Blame the Discount Factor No Matter What the Fundamentals Are

Similar documents
Are Bitcoin Prices Rational Bubbles *

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

Indian Institute of Management Calcutta. Working Paper Series. WPS No. 797 March Implied Volatility and Predictability of GARCH Models

TESTING THE EXPECTATIONS HYPOTHESIS ON CORPORATE BOND YIELDS. Samih Antoine Azar *

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

Unemployment and Labor Force Participation in Turkey

Chapter 4 Level of Volatility in the Indian Stock Market

Volume 29, Issue 2. Measuring the external risk in the United Kingdom. Estela Sáenz University of Zaragoza

The Balassa-Samuelson Effect and The MEVA G10 FX Model

Exchange Rate Forecasting

Does the Unemployment Invariance Hypothesis Hold for Canada?

Unemployment and Labour Force Participation in Italy

Government Tax Revenue, Expenditure, and Debt in Sri Lanka : A Vector Autoregressive Model Analysis

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

Discussion Paper Series No.196. An Empirical Test of the Efficiency Hypothesis on the Renminbi NDF in Hong Kong Market.

Available online at ScienceDirect. Procedia Economics and Finance 32 ( 2015 ) Andreea Ro oiu a, *

1 A Simple Model of the Term Structure

Exchange Rate Market Efficiency: Across and Within Countries

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis

Regional Business Cycles In the United States

Sectoral Analysis of the Demand for Real Money Balances in Pakistan

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

The German unemployment since the Hartz reforms: Permanent or transitory fall?

Survey Based Expectations and Uncovered Interest Rate Parity

Savings Investment Correlation in Developing Countries: A Challenge to the Coakley-Rocha Findings

Efficiency in the Australian Stock Market, : A Note on Extreme Long-Run Random Walk Behaviour

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

The Economic and Social BOOTSTRAPPING Review, Vol. 31, No. THE 4, R/S October, STATISTIC 2000, pp

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward. Discount Puzzle 1

Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in Ireland

INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE

Dynamic Linkages between Newly Developed Islamic Equity Style Indices

Pricing Currency Options with Intra-Daily Implied Volatility

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension

Research Article The Volatility of the Index of Shanghai Stock Market Research Based on ARCH and Its Extended Forms

RE-EXAMINE THE INTER-LINKAGE BETWEEN ECONOMIC GROWTH AND INFLATION:EVIDENCE FROM INDIA

STRESS TEST MODELLING OF PD RISK PARAMETER UNDER ADVANCED IRB

TESTING THE WEAK-FORM EFFICIENCY OF THE ROMANIAN CAPITAL MARKET BY ASSESSING THE RANDOM WALK-LIKE BEHAVIOUR OF STOCK PRICES

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India

Oesterreichische Nationalbank. Eurosystem. Workshops. Proceedings of OeNB Workshops. Macroeconomic Models and Forecasts for Austria

CAN MONEY SUPPLY PREDICT STOCK PRICES?

Determinants of Cyclical Aggregate Dividend Behavior

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

A market risk model for asymmetric distributed series of return

An Analysis of Spain s Sovereign Debt Risk Premium

Most recent studies of long-term interest rates have emphasized term

Testing for efficient markets

LONG MEMORY IN VOLATILITY

Predictability in finance

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note*

US HFCS Price Forecasting Using Seasonal ARIMA Model

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1

MAGNT Research Report (ISSN ) Vol.6(1). PP , 2019

The Asset Pricing Model of Exchange Rate and its Test on Survey Data

Behavioural Equilibrium Exchange Rate (BEER)

Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using Stochastic Volatility Model

Real Exchange Rates, Efficient Markets and Uncovered Interest Parity: A Review

Is the real effective exchange rate biased against the PPP hypothesis?

The Causal Relationship between Government Expenditure & Tax Revenue in Barbados. Authors:Tracy Maynard & Kester Guy

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University

British Journal of Economics, Finance and Management Sciences 29 July 2017, Vol. 14 (1)

Currency Substitution, Capital Mobility and Functional Forms of Money Demand in Pakistan

How do stock prices respond to fundamental shocks?

The Economic Consequences of Dollar Appreciation for US Manufacturing Investment: A Time-Series Analysis

Institute of Economic Research Working Papers. No. 63/2017. Short-Run Elasticity of Substitution Error Correction Model

Financial Econometrics Series SWP 2011/13. Did the US Macroeconomic Conditions Affect Asian Stock Markets? S. Narayan and P.K.

Estimating Demand Uncertainty Over Multi-Period Lead Times

Applied Econometrics and International Development. AEID.Vol. 5-3 (2005)

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities

Why the saving rate has been falling in Japan

An Empirical Study on the Determinants of Dollarization in Cambodia *

The Effects of Public Debt on Economic Growth and Gross Investment in India: An Empirical Evidence

Examining Capital Market Integration in Korea and Japan Using a Threshold Cointegration Model

Department of Economics Working Paper

FORECASTING EXCHANGE RATE RETURN BASED ON ECONOMIC VARIABLES

Uncertainty and the Transmission of Fiscal Policy

Thi-Thanh Phan, Int. Eco. Res, 2016, v7i6, 39 48

Real exchange rate forecasting: a calibrated half-life PPP model can beat the random walk

Asian Economic and Financial Review A REGRESSION BASED APPROACH TO CAPTURING THE LEVEL DEPENDENCE IN THE VOLATILITY OF STOCK RETURNS

The Efficient Market Hypothesis Testing on the Prague Stock Exchange

UK Industry Beta Risk

Modelling Returns: the CER and the CAPM

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

Inflation and inflation uncertainty in Argentina,

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( )

THE IMPACT OF FINANCIAL LEVERAGE ON AGENCY COST OF FREE CASH FLOWS IN LISTED MANUFACTURING FIRMS OF TEHRAN STOCK EXCHANGE

Volume. 3, No. 2 July - December 2016 sijmb.iba-suk.edu.pk. Financing the Fiscal Deficit in Pakistan: Evidence on Ricardian Equivalence

Indonesian Capital Market Review 8 (2016) 83-93

A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS OF REAL AND PREDICTED INFLATION CONVERGENCE IN CEE COUNTRIES DURING THE ECONOMIC CRISIS

Country Fixed Effects and Unit Roots: A Comment on Poverty and Civil War: Revisiting the Evidence

BESSH-16. FULL PAPER PROCEEDING Multidisciplinary Studies Available online at

International Journal of Business and Administration Research Review. Vol.3, Issue.22, April-June Page 1

Foreign Direct Investment & Economic Growth in BRICS Economies: A Panel Data Analysis

Comparing neural networks with other predictive models in artificial stock market

The Relationship between Inflation, Inflation Uncertainty and Output Growth in India

DATABASE AND RESEARCH METHODOLOGY

Inflation and Stock Market Returns in US: An Empirical Study

Transcription:

Blame the Discount Factor No Matter What the Fundamentals Are Anna Naszodi 1 Engel and West (2005) argue that the discount factor, provided it is high enough, can be blamed for the failure of the empirical literature to find significant relationship between the economic fundamentals and the exchange rate. In this paper I test whether the discount factor is of that magnitude. In order to obtain an estimates of the discount factor which is robust to the definition of the fundamental, I apply the following method. I treat the fundamental as being unobserved and filter it out by the Kalman-filter from survey data on exchange rate forecasts with multiple forecast horizons. The estimates for the discount factor is obtained by maximizing the filtering likelihood. The empirical results support the explanation of Engel and West for the disconnect puzzle. JEL: E44, F31, G10 Keywords: asset-pricing exchange rate model, disconnect puzzle, survey forecasts, Kalman-filter. 1 Introduction If the discount factor is in a certain interval then it can be blamed for the failure of the empirical literature to find significant relationship between the fundamentals and the nominal exchange rate, given that the process of the fundamentals is integrated of order one (I(1)). This result is obtained by Engel and West (2005). Sarno and Sojli (2009) estimate the discount factor and find that its magnitude can account for the feeble link between the exchange rate and the fundamentals along the arguments of Engel and West. The empirical method applied by Sarno and Sojli (2009) identifies the discount factor not only from the time series of the exchange rate and the survey data on the one-month-ahead exchange rate forecasts, but also from a set of macro 1 Magyar Nemzeti Bank (the Central Bank of Hungary), Budapest, Hungary email: naszodia@mnb.hu, anna.naszodi@gmail.com 1

fundamentals. 2 In this respect their estimates depends on how exactly the fundamental is defined. This paper proposes an alternative empirical strategy to estimate the discount factor with the same stylized asset-pricing exchange rate model used by Engel and West (2005) and Sarno and Sojli (2009). This alternative approach distinguishes itself from that of Sarno and Sojli by being robust to the definition of the fundamentals. The importance of this feature is supported by the following facts. First, there is no consensus among economists over what the macro fundamentals are. Second, some components of the commonly used fundamentals like the risk premium are unobservable. The main idea of the proposed approach is to use a richer data set on exchange rate forecasts which can take over the role of the fundamentals at identifying the discount factor. These richer data consist of survey forecasts with not only one forecast horizon, but more. I apply this approach to estimate the discount factors of four major exchange rates. Thereby, I test whether the magnitude of the estimates is consistent with the Engel and West explanation for the disconnect puzzle. 2 Exchange rate model I work with a conventional class of asset-pricing models in which the exchange rate is the discounted sum of the current and expected future fundamentals. 3 s t = (1 b) b j E t (f t+j ) with 0 < b < 1, (1) j=0 wheres t denotesthelogexchangerateattimet,whilef t+j isthefundamental at time t + j. E t (.) is the expectation operator, where the expectation is conditional on all the information available at time t. Parameter b is the discount factor, whose magnitude we are interested in. The reduced form of (1) can be rationalized by a number of structural models. For instance, Engel and West (2005) review some commonly used models, where b is either the semi-elasticity of money demand with respect 1 b 2 Sarno and Sojli (2009) define the fundamentals as being the weighted average of the foreign and domestic money supplies and outputs. As a robustness check, they use different weighting schemes. 3 See for instance Mark (2001), page 68. 2

b to the interest rate, or is the inverse of the relative weight of the exchange 1 b rate in the Taylor rule. Along these lines, estimates of the money demand or the Taylor rule can also be used to learn the magnitude of the discount factor b. While Engel and West (2005) chose the above approach, this paper provides estimates of the discount factor that is independent from any of the structural models and uses only the reduced form model of (1) which is common across a large set of structural models. The cost of generality, i.e., the cost of being independent from structural models, is that one has to make an assumption on the process of the fundamental. Here, the assumed process is f t = ρf t 1 +α(1 ρ)+ǫ f,t, where 0 < ρ 1, and ǫ f,t i.i.d N(0,σ 2 f). (2) Iftheautoregressiveparameter0 < ρ < 1thentheprocessofthefundamental isstationary, whileincaseofρ = 1itisintegratedoforderone. Inadditionto the magnitude of the discount factor, we are also interested in the estimates of the autoregressive parameter of the fundamental. The reason for our interestisthattheexplanationofengelandwest(2005)fortherandomwalk behavior of the exchange rate relies not only on the near unity of the discount factor, but also on the assumption that the process of the fundamental is integrated of order one. They show that all autocorrelations of ds will be very close to zero for b very close to one and ρ = 1. From the practical point of view of predicting the future exchange rate, a highly persistent stationary process of the fundamental also makes an interesting case. As it is argued by Engel and West (2005), there is continuity in the autocorrelations in the following sense: for b near one, the autocorrelations of ds will be near zero if the previous paragraph s condition that certain variables are I(1) is replaced with the condition that those variables are I(0) but with an autoregressive root very near one. For a given autoregressive root less than one, the autocorrelations will not converge to zero as b approaches one. But they will be very small for b very near one. It can be derived from Equations (1) and (2) that the expected k periodahead exchange rate is the following function of the fundamental f t and the discount factor b. 4 E t (s t+k ) = α (1 b)α ρk 1 ρb +(1 b) ρ k 1 ρb f t for all k > 0. (3) 4 See the derivation in the Appendix. 3

3 Empirical Implementation Our primary aim is to estimate the discount factor without using data on the fundamental, and without knowing the structural macro model. This Section shows one way of doing it. The basic idea is that survey forecasts with various forecast horizons can identify the discount factor together with the fundamental. A consistent estimator is the Kalman-filter that treats the fundamental as being unobserved. I assume that the survey forecasts are unbiased estimates of the expected future log exchange rates. z t,t+k = E t (s t+k )+ǫ t,k with ǫ t,k i.i.d N(0,σ 2 z,k), (4) where z t,t+k is the survey forecasts with the forecast horizon k. By substituting Equation (3) into (4), we obtain some of the observation equations with different forecast horizons k. z t,t+k = α (1 b)α ρk 1 ρb +(1 b) ρ k 1 ρb f t +ǫ t,k. (5) If we had forecasts for h number of different forecast horizons, then the number of observation equations would be h as well. However, in addition to the survey forecasts, we have data also on the spot exchange rate making the number of observation equations h + 1. Although the spot rate can be thought of as a special forecast with zero forecast horizon s t = z t,t, it is worth to treat it separately from the forecasts. In contrast to the expected future log exchange rate E t (s t+k ), the expected current log exchange rate E t (s t ), i.e., the log spot rate s t is observed without error. By using the identities s t = z t,t and ǫ t,0 = 0, Equation (5) gives s t = α (1 b)α 1 1 ρb +(1 b) 1 1 ρb f t. (6) Finally, Equation(2) corresponds to the transition equation in the state space model. In the filtering exercise, the initial value of the state variable f 0 is set to the log spot exchange rate of the beginning of the sample s 0. The initial state variance is set to 0.3, which reflects a high degree of uncertainty. The estimates of the discount factor and all the other parameters are obtained by maximizing the filtering likelihood. 4

The explanation of Engel and West (2005) for the disconnect puzzle relies on two conditions. First, the discount factor is high. Second, the process of the fundamental is I(1). Whether the discount factor is equal to unity, can be tested by the likelihood ratio test. LR = 2(logl r logl u ). (7) where logl r and logl u are the log likelihoods of the restricted and the unrestricted models respectively. Under the null hypothesis, H 0 : b = 1, the LR-statistics has a chi-square distribution with 1 degrees of freedom. The second condition is tested in three different ways. First, I apply the likelihood ratio test in order to see how likely the restriction of ρ = 1 is. Second, I test whether the time series of the filtered fundamentals have unit roots. For this purpose I use the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test, and the Kwiatkowski-Phillips-Schmidt-Shin (KPSS) test. 4 Survey Data and Empirical Results I use the survey data of the Consensus Economics on the forecasted 3-monthsahead, 1-year-ahead and 2-year-ahead exchange rates. 5 These forecasts are for the exchange rates of the euro(eur), the United Kingdom pound(gbp), the Japanese yen (JPY) against the US dollar (USD), and the Swiss franc (CHF) against the euro. The survey data are the mean of the forecasts of the individual survey participants presumably mirroring the consensus view of the professional forecasters. The frequency of the survey data is monthly. The sample is spanned by January 1999 and September 2008. The beginning of the sample is determined by the availability of the data, while the end of the sample is the last survey date preceding September 15, 2008, when Lehman Brothers has been filed for Chapter 11 bankruptcy protection. In September 2008, there was a salient structural break in different measures of uncertainty, like the implied volatilities of currency option prices and the cross-sectional standard deviation of the individual forecasts. As the jump in uncertainty would invalidate our assumption of having unchanged variance in the observation equations in a sample covering the period even after the 5 The reported forecasts are not the expected log exchange rates, but the expected exchange rates. I proxy the expected log exchange rates by the log of the reported expected exchange rates. An even more precise approximation would be based on adjusting by half of the variance. However, the difference between the two approximations is negligible. 5

structural break, I have decided to exclude observations after September 2008. In addition to the survey forecasts, I use the spot exchange rates on the days of the surveys. These data are from the European Central Bank. 6 The Kalman-filter is used for each of the 4 exchange rates separately. The length of the time series of all variables, i.e., the exchange rate and the forecasts with 3 different forecast horizons, is 116. Therefore, 116 times 4 observations help filter one single time series of the unobserved factor and to estimate 7 parameters in case of each of the exchange rate. Table 1 shows the estimates of the discount factor, the AR parameter of the fundamental together with the rest of the parameters. In economic sense, the point estimates of the discount factors are close to one for all the four exchange rates. However, the likelihood ratio test makes us to reject the null of b = 1. The same can be said about the AR parameters of the fundamentals: the estimates of ρ s are very close to unity for all the four currency pairs, but statistically they are significantly smaller than one. Table 2 presents some further statistics about the processes of the fundamentals. The null hypothesis of the ADF-test that the filtered fundamentals have unit roots cannot be rejected for any of the exchange rates. In accordance with this result, stationarity can be rejected based on the KPSS-test for three exchange rates out of the four. The only exception is the yen, where the KPSS test-statistics is not significant. Although the unit root tests of the filtered fundamentals contradict to the likelihood tests most of the times, the processes of the fundamentals are proved to be highly persistent by both of the approaches. To sum up the results, both the discount factors and the autoregressive parameters of the fundamentals are very close to unity, but certain statistical tests suggests that they are smaller than unity for the four exchange rates examined. 5 Conclusion The near random walk behavior of the exchange rate, and also the weak link between the nominal exchange rate and some economic fundamentals are well documented by the empirical literature. These disappointing findings have questioned the relevance of the conventional exchange rate models for a long time until the breakthrough work of Engel and West (2005). They reconciled 6 http://www.ecb.int/stats/exchange/eurofxref/html/index.en.html 6

the empirics with the theory by demonstrating that under certain conditions the findings are consistent with the models. These conditions are (i) at least one of the factors driving the exchange rate follows an I(1) process, and (ii) the discount factor is relatively large, e.g., close to unity. The primary aim of this paper is to test the second condition by providing estimates of the discount factor. I use an estimator that is robust to the underlying macro model specifying the fundamentals. The motivation for developing such an estimator is twofold. First, the menu of the theoretically appealing fundamentals is large. Second, some components of the fundamentals are unobservable. The main finding is that no matter what the fundamentals are, the discount factor is high. Thereby, the test gives robust support to the resolution of the exchange rate disconnect puzzle proposed by Engel and West. 7

Literature Cited Engel, Charles, and Kenneth D. West. (2005). Exchange Rates and Fundamentals. Journal of Political Economy 113, 485 517. Mark, Nelson C. (2001). International Macroeconomics and Finance: Theory and Econometric Methods. Oxford: Blackwell. Sarno, Lucio, and Elvira Sojli. (2009). The Feeble Link between Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: Can We Blame the Discount Factor? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 41, 437 442. 8

Tables Table 1: The Estimates of the Parameters b ρ α σ 2 f σ 2 z,k=3m σ2 z,k=1y σ 2 z,k=2y CHF/EUR 0.9056 0.8723 0.4321 0.0005 0.0001 0.0002 0.0003 LR 241.8542 253.9174 EUR/USD 0.9878 0.9377 0.2398 0.0441 0.0004 0.0009 0.0016 LR 584.5102 390.9662 GBP/USD 0.9988 0.9570 0.5095 0.9944 0.0002 0.0003 0.0005 LR 184.1991 255.4929 JPY/USD 0.9908 0.9784 4.4971 0.0132 0.0008 0.0019 0.0023 LR 78.6371 91.3387 Notes: *** indicate that we can reject the hypothesis at 1% significance level. The hypothesis of column b is H 0 :b = 1. The hypothesis of column ρ is H 0 :ρ = 1. 9

Table 2: Unit Root Tests of the Filtered Fundamentals ADF-test KPSS-test p-value CHF/EUR 0.4722 0.4168 EUR/USD 0.8565 1.0219 GBP/USD 0.6537 1.0011 JPY/USD 0.2374 0.1533 Notes:,, indicate significance at 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. At the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test the hypothesis is that there is unit root in the process of the fundamental, while at the Kwiatkowski-Phillips-Schmidt-Shin (KPSS) test the hypothesis is that the process of the fundamental is stationary. 10

Appendix In this Appendix I show that under the assumed process of the fundamental f t of (2), the k period-ahead expected log exchange rate E t (s t+k ) is given by Equation (3) in the reduced form asset-pricing model of (1). First, E t (f t+k ) is expressed as a function of f t from Equation (2). Second, by substituting (8) into (1), we obtain E t (f t+k ) = α(1 ρ k )+ρ k f t. (8) s t = (1 b) b j[ ] α(1 ρ j )+ρ j f t. (9) By using j=0 bj = 1 (0 < b < 1) and 1 b j=0 bj ρ j = 1 1 bρ Equation (9) simplifies to j=0 (0 < ρ 1), s t = α b(1 ρ) 1 bρ + 1 b 1 bρ f t. (10) From (10), we get [ E t (s t+k ) = E t α b(1 ρ) 1 bρ + 1 b ] 1 bρ f t+k. (11) Finally, we obtain Equation (3) by substituting Equation (8) into (11). 11