Identifying FDI Spillovers Online Appendix

Similar documents
The exporters behaviors : Evidence from the automobiles industry in China

Pure Exporter: Theory and Evidence from China

Measuring Chinese Firms Performance Experiences with Chinese firm level data

Online Appendix Only Funding forms, market conditions and dynamic effects of government R&D subsidies: evidence from China

Exporting Behavior of Foreign A liates: Theory and Evidence

How Do Exporters Respond to Antidumping Investigations?

Identifying FDI Spillovers

Exports, FDI and Productivity

Measuring Firm-level Ine ciencies in the Ghanaian. Manufacturing Sector

Adjustment Costs and the Identi cation of Cobb Douglas Production Functions

Spillovers from FDI: What are the Transmission Channels?

Input Tariffs, Speed of Contract Enforcement, and the Productivity of Firms in India

Intermediaries, Firm Heterogeneity, and Exporting Behavior

Family Financing and Aggregate Manufacturing. Productivity in Ghana

Intermediaries, Firm Heterogeneity, and Exporting Behavior

Services Reform and Manufacturing Performance: Evidence from India

Liquidity Constraints and Firm s Export Activity

Online Appendix. Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: Do Dynamic Incentives Matter? by Aron-Dine, Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen

Markups and Quality Adjustments to Chinese Import Competition: Evidence from India

Foreign Acquisitions in China and Multinationals Global Market Strategy

Working Paper Series / Cahiers de recherche

How Do Exporters Respond to Antidumping Investigations?

NATIONAL BANK OF POLAND WORKING PAPER No. 51

When Foreign Rivals are Coming to Town: Firm Responses to Multinational Investment News

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRODUCTION FUNCTION ESTIMATION WITH MEASUREMENT ERROR IN INPUTS. Allan Collard-Wexler Jan De Loecker

Production Function Estimation with Measurement Error in Inputs

Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and

How Do Exchange Rate Regimes A ect the Corporate Sector s Incentives to Hedge Exchange Rate Risk? Herman Kamil. International Monetary Fund

Does Easing Controls on External Commercial Borrowings boost Exporting Intensity of Indian Firms?

Online Appendices for

"Inequality, Growth and Investment"

Industrial Policy in China: Some Intended or Unintended. Consequences?

The Impact of FTAs on FDI in Korea

Rethinking industrial policy. Philippe Aghion

Growing lemons and cherries?

Do Domestic Chinese Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment?

STOCK RETURNS AND INFLATION: THE IMPACT OF INFLATION TARGETING

On the Reverse Causality between Output and Infrastructure: the Case of China

Financial liberalization and the relationship-specificity of exports *

Benefits of Foreign Ownership: Evidence from Foreign Direct Investment in China

Technological Catch-Up and Productivity Spillovers From FDI: Evidence From Indian Manufacturing

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

research paper series

18/006 Capital-Labor Substitution and the Decline in Labor s Share. Dan Berkowitz, Hong Ma and Shuichiro Nishioka. April, 2018

Former Foreign Affiliates: Cast Out and Outperformed?

Competition and Productivity Growth in South Africa

Estimating Productivity of Public Infrastructure Investment

Technological Catch-up and Geographic Proximity

Advanced Industrial Organization I. Lecture 4: Technology and Cost

On the Reverse Causality between Output and Infrastructure: the Case of China

The impact of credit constraints on foreign direct investment: evidence from firm-level data Preliminary draft Please do not quote

The Economic Impact of Special Economic Zones: Evidence from Chinese Municipalities

Identifying FDI Spillovers

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility

Deregulation and Firm Investment

Local Intermediate Inputs, Foreign Direct Investment and the Performance of Domestic Firms: When Firms Share Common Local Input Suppliers

In Search of Export Spillovers in a Developing Country

The heterogeneous effects of trade facilitation: theory and evidence

Productivity and the internationalization of firms: cross-border acquisitions versus greenfield investments.

Productivity and Foreign Institutional Ownership 1

Outward FDI and Total Factor Productivity: Evidence from Germany

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Redefine Foreign : Implications for FDI spilovers

Cardiff University CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL. Cardiff Economics Working Papers No. 2005/16

Picking Winners or Creating Them? Revisiting the Benefits of FDI in the Czech Republic

Precautionary Corporate Liquidity

ONLINE APPENDIX (NOT FOR PUBLICATION) Appendix A: Appendix Figures and Tables

FDI, domestic sales and export intensity: A case study of China s manufacturing industries

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

Internet Appendix for Collateral Shocks and Corporate Employment

The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment on the Export Performance: Empirical Evidence for Western Balkan Countries

Inward foreign direct investment and industrial restructuring: micro evidence the Slovenian firms growth model *

Reassessing the Productivity Gains from Trade Liberalization

Firm Investment and Exporting: Evidence from China s Value-Added Tax Reform

Input-Trade Liberalization and Markups

Offshoring and skill-upgrading in French manufacturing: a Heckscher-Ohlin-Melitz view

Spillovers Through Backward Linkages from Multinationals: Measurement Matters!

Does Manufacturing Matter for Economic Growth in the Era of Globalization? Online Supplement

Location Decision of Heterogeneous Multinational Firms

Imports and Productivity

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES. No TRADE LIBERALIZATION, INTERMEDIATE INPUTS AND PRODUCTIVITY: EVIDENCE FROM INDONESIA. Mary Amiti and Jozef Konings

Misallocation and Trade Policy

Foreign Rivals are Coming to Town: Responding to the Threat of Foreign Multinational Entry (Job Market Paper)

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FDI SPILLOVERS AND INDUSTRIAL POLICY: THE ROLE OF TARIFFS AND TAX HOLIDAYS. Luosha Du Ann Harrison Gary Jefferson

The Impact of Mutual Recognition Agreements on Foreign Direct Investment and. Export. Yong Joon Jang. Oct. 11, 2010

An Estimated Two-Country DSGE Model for the Euro Area and the US Economy

Determinants of foreign direct investment in Malaysia

Estimating the Incidences of the Recent Pension Reform in China: Evidence from 100,000 Manufacturers

Input-Trade Liberalization and Markups

Are Financial Markets Stable? New Evidence from An Improved Test of Financial Market Stability and the U.S. Subprime Crisis

Patterns of Trade and Tax Interventions and Firm Performance

Trade Liberalization and Markups: Micro Evidence from China

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS. No 449. Pursuing the Wrong Options? Adjustment Costs and the Relationship between Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation

Productivity Differences among Unaffiliated Domestic Firms, Licensees and Foreign Subsidiaries*

Wage Markdowns and FDI Liberalization

Spillovers through backward linkages from multinationals: Measurement matters! 1

Statistical Evidence and Inference

U.S. Job Flows and the China Shock

GROWTH CONTRIBUTING FUTURE PROSPECTS. Summary and Selected Figures and Tables FACTORS TO CHINA ROWTH, AND ITS

Transcription:

Identifying FDI Spillovers Online Appendix Yi Lu Tsinghua University and National University of Singapore, Zhigang Tao University of Hong Kong Lianming Zhu Waseda University This Version: December 2016 1 Appendix A: Determinants of Changes in FDI Regulations To some extent, the changes in FDI regulations upon China s WTO accession in 2002 may not be randomly determined. This presents an identi cation issue that the treatment and control groups were not comparable before the changes in FDI regulations, which may potentially bias our DID estimation. Meanwhile, there is a reverse causality problem in that the productivity of China s domestic rms may a ect the government s decision in modifying the FDI regulations, which may also cause estimation biases. In this appendix, we carefully examine the determinants of the changes in FDI regulations upon China s WTO accession in addressing these issues. There are many reasons why the government decided to modify the Catalogue for the Guidance of Foreign Investment Industries in 2002. It is widely acknowledged that the central government of China was keen on making its domestic rms competitive in the era of globalization. According to the Xinhua News released on March 12, 2002, the government relaxed the FDI regulations for certain industries to promote industry upgrading and exports. Meanwhile, the government may protect infant industries in their early stages and encourage industrial clustering so as to boost development in those industries. Finally, the government also cares about how the relaxation of FDI regulations may impact labor market conditions, such as current employment and wages, which are critical for maintaining social stability in 1

the country. To account for the above possible considerations of China s government in relaxing its FDI regulations, we include seven variables: new product intensity (the ratio of new products in total output), export intensity (the ratio of exports to total output), number of rms, industrial clustering (the Ellison Glaeser index), average age of rms, average employment, and average wage per worker. The regression results are reported in column 1 in Table A2, in which the changes in FDI regulations (a dummy variable taking value 1 if FDI in an industry became more welcome, and 0 otherwise) are regressed on the aforementioned seven potential determinants in 1998, the initial year of the data available in our sample period. It is found that four variables are statistically signi cant: (1) new product intensity is found to have a positive e ect; (2) export intensity is found to have a negative e ect; (3) number of rms is found to have a positive e ect; and (4) average age of rms is found to have a negative e ect. We further add a control of TFP in the regression to account for the potential reverse causality issue that the changes in FDI regulations may be reversely a ected by TFP. As shown in column 2, the coe cient of TFP is not statistically signi cant, with magnitude close to zero. In column 3, we replace TFP level with the growth of TFP in the pre- WTO period (i.e., from 1998 to 2002). The estimated coe cient of the TFP growth rate is also insigni cant. Combined, these result indicate that changes in FDI regulations are not reversely a ected by TFP or the time trajectory of TFP. 2 Appendix B: Estimation of Firm TFP Consider the following Cobb-Douglas production function in logs: y ft = l l ft + k k ft + m m ft +! ft + ft ; (A1) where y ft is the log of rm output, and l ft, k ft, and m ft are the inputs of log employment, log capital, and log materials, respectively.! ft is rm productivity, and ft is measurement error and/or unanticipated shocks to output. To obtain consistent production function estimates = ( l ; k ; m ), we need to control for unobserved productivity shocks potentially leading to simultaneity and selection biases. We use a control function based on a static input demand function to proxy for the unobserved productivity. We follow the control function approach initiated by Olley and Pakes (1996), and extended by Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) and De Loecker and Warzynski (2012), and proxy for 2

the unobserved productivity using the following materials demand function: m = m t (! ft ; k ft ; EXP ft ) : (A2) where EXP ft is rm s export status. Inverting (A2) yields the control function for productivity:! ft = h t (k ft ; m ft ; EXP ft ) : In the rst stage, we purge unanticipated shocks and/or measurement error ft by estimating the following equation: y ft = t (l ft ; k ft ; m ft ; EXP ft ) + ft ; (A3) which yields an estimate of predicted output (^ ft ). We use (A1) and (A3) from the rst-stage estimation to express productivity:! ft () = ^ ft l l it k k it m m it : (A4) To estimate production function coe cients, we follow Ackerberg, Caves, and Frazer (2015) and form moments based on innovation in the productivity shock ft in the law of motion for productivity: 1! ft = g (! ft 1; EXP ft) + ft: We use (A4) and nonparametrically regress! ft () on g (! ft 1 ; EXP ft ) to obtain the innovation ft () =! ft () E (! ft () j! ft 1 () ; EXP ft 1 ). The moment conditions used to estimate the production function coe cients are: E ft () Y ft = 0; where Y ft contains lagged labor and materials, and current capital. 2 Once the production function coe cients ^ = ^l ; ^ k ; ^ m are estimated, we can compute rm productivity as follows: ^! ft = ^ ft ^l l it ^k k it ^m m it : 1 As in De Loecker (2013), we include rm s export status in the law of motion for productivity to account for the potential e ect of exporting on productivity. 2 Following the literature, we treat labor and materials as exible inputs and their lagged values are used to construct moments. As capital is considered as a dynamic input that faces adjustment costs, its current value is used to form moments. 3

References [1] Ackerberg, Daniel A., Kevin Caves, and Garth Frazer, 2015. Identi cation properties of recent production function estimators. Econometrica. 83(6), 2411 2451. [2] De Loecker, Jan, 2013. Detecting learning by exporting. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics. 5(3), 1 21. [3] De Loecker, Jan, and Frederic Warzynski, 2012. Markups and rm-level export status. American Economic Review. 102(6), 2437 2471. [4] Levinsohn, James A., and Amil Petrin, 2003. Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables. Review of Economic Studies. 70(2), 317 341. [5] Olley, Stephen G., and Ariel Pakes, 1996. The dynamics of productivity in the telecommunications equipment industry. Econometrica. 64(6), 1263 1297. 4

Table A1: Changes of FDI regulations (product level) between 1997 and 2002 2002 (1) (2) (3) (4) Supported Permitted Restricted Prohibited (1) Supported No change Less welcome Less welcome Less welcome 1997 (2) (3) Permitted Restricted More welcome No change Less welcome Less welcome More welcome More welcome No Change Less welcome (4) Prohibited More welcome More welcome More welcome No Change

Table A2: Determinants of changes in FDI regulations (industry level) Dependent variable: Changes in FDI regulations (1) (2) (3) New product intensity 1.571*** 1.558*** 1.593*** (0.253) (0.260) (0.256) Export intensity 0.257** 0.255** 0.257** (0.106) (0.106) (0.106) (log) number of firms 0.032* 0.032* 0.031* (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) Ellison-Glaeser index 0.742 0.732 0.749 (0.566) (0.570) (0.568) Average age of firms 0.009** 0.009** 0.008** (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (log) average employment 0.009 0.008 0.011 (0.036) (0.036) (0.036) (log) average wage per worker 0.086 0.087 0.082 (0.078) (0.078) (0.078) (log) TFP 0.010 (0.051) TFP growth rate 0.138 (0.335) Observations 412 412 412 R-squared 0.130 0.130 0.130 Note: Observations are at the four-digit industry level. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Table A3: Privatization of SOEs Dependent variable: Degree of state ownership 0.069 (1) (2) (0.045) Treatment Post02 0.001 (0.007) Firm fixed effects Y Y Year fixed effects Y Y FDI determinants Year dummies Y Y Tariff reductions Year dummies Y Y Time-varying firm controls Y Y Observations 1,153,661 176,941 Note: Determinants of changes in FDI regulations include new product intensity, export intensity, number of firms, and average age of firms at the four-digit industry level in 1998. Tariff reductions include output tariff, input tariff, and export tariff at the four-digit industry level in 2001. Timevarying firm controls include firm output, export status, and capital-labor ratio. Standard errors are clustered at the four-digit industry level in parentheses.

Table A4: Foreign multinationals before and after WTO accession (1) (2) (3) 1998-2001 2002-2007 Diff (2) (1) Percentage of wholly-owned FIEs 0.442 0.659 0.217*** (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) Note: The percentage of wholly-owned multinationals in all foreign firms is reported for the pre-wto 1998-2001 period, post-wto 2002-2007 period, and their differences. *** denotes significance at the 1% level.

Table A5: Expectation effect Dependent variable: Log firm TFP (1) (2) (3) Fake treatment timing in 2001 0.006 (0.004) Fake treatment timing in 2000 0.007 (0.005) Fake treatment timing in 1999 0.007 (0.006) Firm fixed effects Y Y Y Year fixed effects Y Y Y FDI determinants Year dummies Y Y Y Tariff reductions Year dummies Y Y Y SOE privatization Year dummies Y Y Y Time-varying firm controls Y Y Y Observations 402,552 402,552 402,552 Note: Determinants of changes in FDI regulations include new product intensity, export intensity, number of firms, and average age of firms at the four-digit industry level in 1998. Tariff reductions include output tariff, input tariff, and export tariff at the four-digit industry level in 2001. SOE privatization is a ratio of state-owned enterprises in the total number of firms at the four-digit industry level in 2001. Time-varying firm controls include firm output, export status, capital-labor ratio, and SOE dummy. Bootstrapped standard errors are clustered at the four-digit industry level in parentheses.

Table A6: First-stage estimation results (1) (2) (3) Panel A. Horizontal vs. vertical FDI Dependent variable Horizontal FDI Backward FDI Forward FDI Treatment Post02 0.017** 0.002 0.002 (0.007) (0.003) (0.002) α Treatment Post02 0.044** 0.145*** 0.011*** (0.020) (0.015) (0.004) β Treatment Post02 0.030* 0.019 0.052*** (0.016) (0.014) (0.006) Weak instrument test Anderson-Rubin Wald test (32.32)*** Stock-Wright LM S statistic (109.08)*** Panel B. Local vs. non-local FDI Dependent variable (local) (nonlocal) Treatment Post02 Local share 0.043** 0.006 (0.021) (0.021) Treatment Post02 Non-local share 0.831*** 1.770*** (0.193) (0.388) Weak instrument test Anderson-Rubin Wald test (54.87)*** Stock-Wright LM S statistic (34.55)*** Panel C. Developed vs. developing FDI Dependent variable (developed) (developing) Treatment Post02 0.002 0.018*** (0.004) (0.006) Treatment Indicator Post02 0.008 0.014* (0.006) (0.008) Weak instrument test Anderson-Rubin Wald test (6.52)** Stock-Wright LM S statistic (10.69)*** Panel D. TFP growth Dependent variable Treatment Post02 0.013** (0.006) Weak instrument test Anderson-Rubin Wald test (1.19) Stock-Wright LM S statistic (3.28)* Panel E. Interaction with R&D intensity in 2001 Dependent variable R&D intensity in 2001 Treatment Post02 0.012* 0.000036 (0.007) (0.000025) Treatment Post02 R&D intensity in 2001 0.017 0.034*** (0.022) (0.009) Weak instrument test Anderson-Rubin Wald test (7.95)** Stock-Wright LM S statistic (11.54)*** Panel F. Interaction with SOE dummy in 2001 Dependent variable SOE dummy in 2001 Treatment Post02 0.014** 0.003*** (0.007) (0.001) Treatment Post02 SOE dummy in 2001 0.006** 0.015*** (0.003) (0.005) Weak instrument test Anderson-Rubin Wald test (13.20)*** Stock-Wright LM S statistic (26.39)*** Note: First-stage estimation results of the IV estimation are reported in panels A-F. ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Table A7: Dynamic effect Dependent variable TFP growth (t, t-1) TFP growth (t, t+3) Lagged 0.945*** (1) (2) (0.230) 1.440*** (0.203) Firm fixed effects Y Y Year fixed effects Y Y FDI determinants Year dummies Y Y Tariff reductions Year dummies Y Y SOE privatization Year dummies Y Y Time-varying firm controls Y Y Observations 938,305 640,863 Note: Determinants of changes in FDI regulations include new product intensity, export intensity, number of firms, and average age of firms at the four-digit industry level in 1998. Tariff reductions include output tariff, input tariff, and export tariff at the four-digit industry level in 2001. SOE privatization is a ratio of state-owned enterprises in the total number of firms at the four-digit industry level in 2001. Time-varying firm controls include firm output, export status, capitallabor ratio, and SOE dummy. Bootstrapped standard errors are clustered at the fourdigit industry level in parentheses. *** and ** denote significance at the 1% and 5% level, respectively.

Table A8: Different lags of FDI presence Dependent variable: Log firm TFP One-year lagged Two-year lagged 2.602*** (0.370) 1.956* (1.079) 1.111** (0.504) Three-year lagged 1.113 Firm fixed effects Year fixed effects FDI determinants Year dummies Tariff reductions Year dummies SOE privatization Year dummies Time-varying firm controls (1.174) Observations 441,320 Note: Determinants of changes in FDI regulations include new product intensity, export intensity, number of firms, and average age of firms at the four-digit industry level in 1998. Tariff reductions include output tariff, input tariff, and export tariff at the four-digit industry level in 2001. SOE privatization is the ratio of state-owned enterprises in the total number of firms at the four-digit industry level in 2001. Timevarying firm controls include firm output, export status, capital-labor ratio, and SOE dummy. Bootstrapped standard errors are clustered at the four-digit industry level in parentheses. ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively. Y Y Y Y Y Y

Table A9: Ratio of skilled labor Dependent variable: Ratio of skilled labor (1) (2) Indicator for foreign firms 0.022*** 0.037*** (0.001) (0.001) Industry fixed effects N Y City fixed effects N Y Observations 214,723 214,723 Note: Robust standard errors are in parentheses. *** denotes significance at the 1% level.