Leverage Dynamics over the Business Cycle

Similar documents
The Debt-Equity Choice of Japanese Firms

The Debt-Equity Choice of Japanese Firms

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Session 2: What is Firm Value and its use as State Variable in the Models?

Investigating the Intertemporal Risk-Return Relation in International. Stock Markets with the Component GARCH Model

Determinants of Capital Structure: A Long Term Perspective

Growth Rate of Domestic Credit and Output: Evidence of the Asymmetric Relationship between Japan and the United States

How Effectively Can Debt Covenants Alleviate Financial Agency Problems?

Dynamic Capital Structure Choice

Ownership Concentration and Capital Structure Adjustments

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW. Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set

Business cycle effect on leverage: A study of Indian non-financial firms

Debt Capacity and Tests of Capital Structure Theories

Does the Equity Market affect Economic Growth?

Working Paper Series

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

Firms Histories and Their Capital Structures *

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Capital Structure and Financial Performance: Analysis of Selected Business Companies in Bombay Stock Exchange

CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE 2003 TAX CUTS Richard H. Fosberg

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Business cycle fluctuations Part II

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

UNOBSERVABLE EFFECTS AND SPEED OF ADJUSTMENT TO TARGET CAPITAL STRUCTURE

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Financial Crisis Effects on the Firms Debt Level: Evidence from G-7 Countries

How much is too much? Debt Capacity and Financial Flexibility

REIT and Commercial Real Estate Returns: A Postmortem of the Financial Crisis

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MOTIVATIONS FOR PUBLIC EQUITY OFFERS: AN INTERNATIONAL PERSPECTIVE. Woojin Kim Michael S. Weisbach

Discussion of Banks Equity Capital Frictions, Capital Ratios, and Interest Rates: Evidence from Spanish Banks

Debt and Taxes: Evidence from a Bank based system

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market?

A Macroeconomic Approach to a Firm's Capital Structure

CAN AGENCY COSTS OF DEBT BE REDUCED WITHOUT EXPLICIT PROTECTIVE COVENANTS? THE CASE OF RESTRICTION ON THE SALE AND LEASE-BACK ARRANGEMENT

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance.

The Impact of Uncertainty on Investment: Empirical Evidence from Manufacturing Firms in Korea

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

Equity Financing Regulation and Corporate Capital Structure A Model and the Simulation

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for?

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan;

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS

: Monetary Economics and the European Union. Lecture 5. Instructor: Prof Robert Hill. Inflation Targeting

Do firms have leverage targets? Evidence from acquisitions

How Do Firms Finance Large Cash Flow Requirements? Zhangkai Huang Department of Finance Guanghua School of Management Peking University

Business fluctuations in an evolving network economy

Corporate Liquidity Management and Financial Constraints

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Determinants of Target Capital Structure: The Case of Dual Debt and Equity Issues

Determinants of Credit Rating and Optimal Capital Structure among Pakistani Banks

Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen. Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n.

What do we know about Capital Structure? Some Evidence from International Data

Family Control and Leverage: Australian Evidence

Key Influences on Loan Pricing at Credit Unions and Banks

MONETARY POLICY EXPECTATIONS AND BOOM-BUST CYCLES IN THE HOUSING MARKET*

The Determinants of Capital Structure: Analysis of Non Financial Firms Listed in Karachi Stock Exchange in Pakistan

The (out)performance of zeroleverage firms in recessions

THE SPEED OF ADJUSTMENT TO CAPITAL STRUCTURE TARGET BEFORE AND AFTER FINANCIAL CRISIS: EVIDENCE FROM INDONESIAN STATE OWNED ENTERPRISES

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Relationship Between Capital Structure and Firm Performance, Evidence From Growth Enterprise Market in China

Bubbles, Liquidity and the Macroeconomy

Commodity price movements and monetary policy in Asia

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno

Capturing Heterogeneity in Leverage

DO TARGET PRICES PREDICT RATING CHANGES? Ombretta Pettinato

Online Appendix for Offshore Activities and Financial vs Operational Hedging

Investment and Financing Constraints

The relation between bank losses & loan supply an analysis using panel data

The leverage dynamics of companies: comparison across firm types

International Journal of Asian Social Science OVERINVESTMENT, UNDERINVESTMENT, EFFICIENT INVESTMENT DECREASE, AND EFFICIENT INVESTMENT INCREASE

Working Paper October Book Review of

Dr. Syed Tahir Hijazi 1[1]

The Speed of Adjustment to the Target Market Value Leverage is Slower Than You Think

Effectiveness of macroprudential and capital flow measures in Asia and the Pacific 1

How do business groups evolve? Evidence from new project announcements.

The Decreasing Trend in Cash Effective Tax Rates. Alexander Edwards Rotman School of Management University of Toronto

Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model)

Aggregate Implications of Credit Market Imperfections (II) By Kiminori Matsuyama. Updated on January 25, 2010

Asset Volatility and Financial Policy: Evidence from Corporate Mergers

On the Capital Structure of Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs)

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description

Macroeconomics. Based on the textbook by Karlin and Soskice: Macroeconomics: Institutions, Instability, and the Financial System

ECONOMIC POLICY UNCERTAINTY AND SMALL BUSINESS DECISIONS

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Does Growth make us Happier? A New Look at the Easterlin Paradox

Investment, Alternative Measures of Fundamentals, and Revenue Indicators

ASSESSING THE DETERMINANTS OF FINANCIAL DISTRESS IN FRENCH, ITALIAN AND SPANISH FIRMS 1

Box 1.3. How Does Uncertainty Affect Economic Performance?

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Macroeconomic Factors in Private Bank Debt Renegotiation

This short article examines the

Transaction Costs and Capital-Structure Decisions: Evidence from International Comparisons

Can Tax Drive Capital Investment?

How Does Access to the Public Capital Market Affect. Firms Capital Structure?

Transcription:

Leverage Dynamics over the Business Cycle Michael Halling Jin Yu Josef Zechner February, 2011 Abstract There remains broad disagreement about what the important drivers of capital structure dynamics are. This paper sheds new light on this question by studying the business cycle dynamics of leverage ratios, using a comprehensive sample of firms from 19 countries. Our main finding is that book leverage evolves pro-cyclically but market leverage counter-cyclically. This empirical pattern is difficult to reconcile with any single theoretical capital structure model. We also find that leverage dynamics are dramatically different for financially constrained and unconstrained firms and that the origin of law, as a proxy for the development of public markets, matters. Finally, we find that leverage adjusts more slowly to target levels during recessions and that this effect is amplified for firms from civil law countries. JEL Classifications: G32, G15. Keywords: Empirical corporate finance, capital structure dynamics, business cycle variation. Acknowledgment: Preliminary and incomplete. We welcome comments, including references to related papers we inadvertently overlooked. We thank Johann Reindl for excellent research assistance. All errors are our responsibility. University of Utah (email: michael.halling@utah.edu) University of New South Wales (email: jin.yu@unsw.edu.au) Vienna University of Economics and Business (CEPR and ECGI) (email: josef.zechner@wu.ac.at)

Leverage Dynamics over the Business Cycle Abstract There remains broad disagreement about what the important drivers of capital structure dynamics are. This paper sheds new light on this question by studying the business cycle dynamics of leverage ratios, using a comprehensive sample of firms from 19 countries. Our main finding is that book leverage evolves pro-cyclically but market leverage counter-cyclically. This empirical pattern is difficult to reconcile with any single theoretical capital structure model. We also find that leverage dynamics are dramatically different for financially constrained and unconstrained firms and that the origin of law, as a proxy for the development of public markets, matters. Finally, we find that leverage adjusts more slowly to target levels during recessions and that this effect is amplified for firms from civil law countries. JEL Classifications: G32, G15. Keywords: Empirical corporate finance, capital structure dynamics, business cycle variation. 1

1 Introduction There is an ongoing intense debate on what the main determinants of capital structure dynamics are. In particular, there is little agreement in the academic literature on the following questions. Are capital structure dynamics driven by changing firm characteristics, and if yes, which ones? Are changing capital market conditions, or changing investor sentiment important? Or are capital structure dynamics largely driven by random events? Empirical examinations of firms dynamic capital structure behavior face significant challenges. For example, existing tests have recently been criticized for ignoring the effects of transactions costs, for selection and survivorship biases or mechanical mean reversion (see, for example, Strebulaev (2007), Leary and Roberts (2005), Chang and Dasgupta (2009), or Shyam-Sunder and Myers (1999) and Chen and Zhao (2007)). One possible remedy for these challenges is to exploit natural experiments (see, e.g. Welch (2011)). Such natural experiments occur in periods in which certain candidate explanatory variables change significantly due to some exogenous event. One can then analyze how such events affect corporate capital structure choices. In this paper we analyze capital structure dynamics by focussing on natural experiments provided by economic recessions. During recessions most of the main theoretical determinants of firms financial structure usually experience significant changes. For example, during recessions corporate cash flows drop for many firms, equity capital of financial intermediaries is reduced, equity valuation levels and the term-structure of interest rates usually change. We first provide an overview of the main theories of dynamic capital structure choice and their implied empirical hypotheses. In this discussion we focus on the influence of business cycle variation on firms target capital structures and choices of debt maturities (long-term vs. short-term). Because of transactions costs or other market frictions, firms will not always be right at their target leverage ratios but might only partially adjust towards their targets. This partial adjustment or, more specifically, the speed of adjustment represents another dimension of our analysis. In our empirical study, we use stock prices and annual firm-level accounting data, combined with business cycle data for 19 countries. From a statistical point of view, the design of the empirical analysis is driven by the goal to include a sufficiently large number of recession year observations. This is achieved by obtaining data for several countries, instead of focus- 2

ing on a single country only. 1 Thus, we also very carefully assign reported balance sheet information to recessions taking into consideration each firm s fiscal year. In addition to analyzing a large number of recessions, our data panel also allows us to identify country characteristics that influence differences in capital structure dynamics. Our empirical results generate several novel and interesting insights. First, we find that market target leverage ratios are generally countercyclical. This contradicts traditional tradeoff models, which predict constant target ratios. It also is at odds with models that focus on time-varying collateral values, capital shocks to financial intermediaries or temporary freezing of debt markets, which predict pro-cyclical market leverage ratios. In contrast, the counter-cyclicality is more in line with dynamic agency models and possibly some market timing models. We also find evidence that firms adjust upwards (downwards) their book debt levels during expansions (recessions). This pro-cyclicality of book values is more in line with tradeoff models but clearly contradicts pure market timing based theories, since they would imply that firms should only issue equity and also should buy back debt during expansions. Finally, we find many highly significant effects of the business cycle on firms dynamic financing behavior for different leverage definitions and different subsets of firms. For example, we find that leverage dynamics differ across countries by their legal origin and the development of their capital markets. Thus, a pure irrelevance view of financing behavior, as proposed by some academics, seems to be clearly rejected by our data. As far as speed of adjustment to target leverage is concerned, we find a strong impact of business cycle variation that is consistent with theory: speed of adjustment is, in general, significantly slower during recessions than during expansions. We document, however, that this decrease in speed of adjustment during recessions is much less pronounced in countries with well developed public markets. This result is consistent with an interpretation that these markets are more robust during recessions and freeze to a lesser extent, thus enabling firms to consistently adjust their leverage to appropriate target levels. There have only been few empirical studies on capital structure and macroeconomic determinants. Korajczyk and Levy (2003) find evidence that book and market target leverage are counter-cyclical for relatively un- 1 If our study focused on the US, we would only end up with 5 recessions after 1975. Three of these recessions are less than 12 months long: 1/1980 to 7/1980, 7/90 to 3/91 and 3/2001 to 11/2001. Thus, the statistical power to discriminate between expansions and recessions using yearly balance sheet information would be very low. 3

constrained firms, but pro-cyclical for relatively constrained firms. 2 Our conclusion about target leverage dynamics of unconstrained firms is quite different: while we also find that market leverage is counter-cyclical, we find strong evidence that book leverage is actually pro-cyclical. This difference is most probably explained by differences in empirical design: most importantly, we employ a more direct definition of business cycle variation. Our results are consistent with Korajczyk and Levy (2003) in the sense that we also find that constrained and unconstrained firms are differently affected by business cycle variation. We also extend their study by including short-term leverage, by analyzing the business cycle dynamics of speed of adjustment estimates and by evaluating the influence of capital market characteristics on these dynamics. Few empirical papers have looked at the relationship between speed of adjustment to target leverage ratios and macroeconomic conditions. Consistent with our results, Cook and Tang (2009) find, using only US data, that the speed of adjustments towards target capital structures is faster in booms than in recessions. Drobetz and Wanzenried (2006) find a similar result for 90 Swiss firms. The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 discusses three strands of theory that have predictions for leverage dynamics and summarizes our hypotheses; Section 3 summarizes the data and our empirical design; Section 4 reports results regarding target leverage ratios and Section 5 presents the results regarding speed of adjustment estimates. Section 6 concludes. 2 Literature and hypotheses The literature on capital structure dynamics can be classified into three broad strands: issuer-driven tradeoff models, capital market-driven models of time-varying supply of financial intermediation and models driven by behavioral biases of investors and/or managers. In this section we summarize these strands of literature and explain which empirical hypotheses regarding firms capital structure dynamics they generate. In our discussion we define leverage as pro-cyclical (counter-cyclical) if it increases (decreases) during economic expansions (contractions). 2 They proxy for business cycle variation using 2-year corporate profit growth, 2-year equity market return and commercial paper spread. 4

2.1 Issuer-driven capital structure dynamics The first strand of literature is by now well developed and focuses on capital structure dynamics determined by time-varying firm characteristics. The first advances were made by Merton (1974) and Black and Cox (1976) and extended by Kane, Marcus, and McDonald (1984) and Kane, Marcus, and McDonald (1985), and Leland (1994) to consider the tradeoff between a tax benefit of debt and costly bankruptcy in continuous-time. These models constitute an important first step towards accounting for dynamic aspects of capital structure choice by introducing a stochastic asset value process, but they do not allow firms to adjust their leverage over time. The next generation of dynamic capital structure models explicitly allows firms to increase or decrease leverage over time. The basic framework developed in Fischer, Heinkel, and Zechner (1989a) and Fischer, Heinkel, and Zechner (1989b) has been extended in several directions. 3 Although firms do not respond instantaneously to changes in their profitability, due to transactions costs, these model predict a constant target capital structure, irrespective of whether the majority of firms experiences increasing or decreasing profitability, i.e. irrespective of the business cycle. Note that, strictly interpreted, the models only make predictions about leverage dynamics expressed in market values, since they do not separately model the evolution of book values of debt, equity, and assets. Obviously asset market values generally fluctuate more than their book values. Thus, if one assumes that firms asset book values move less than their market values over the business cycle, then the above models implicitly predict increasing (decreasing) book target leverage ratios during expansions (contractions). The models also have implications for their propensity to move to the target leverage ratio when their profitability either increases or decreases. While equityholders have an incentive to call existing debt to subsequently issue a higher amount in response to increased profitability, they are generally reluctant to call debt to reduce debt levels after decreasing profitability. This result is driven by the fact that calling debt after adverse changes in a firm s profitability will generally lead to wealth transfers from equity to debt holders. Many dynamic tradeoff models therefore imply that equityholders do not find it optimal to decrease leverage in response to decreasing 3 For example, by modeling firm dynamics via stochastic cash flows rather than stochastic asset values (Goldstein, Ju, and Leland (2001), Dangl and Zechner (2004), and Strebulaev (2007)), and by allowing for investment (Mello and Parsons (1992), Mauer and Triantis (1994), Morellec (2001), Moyen (2004), Childs, Mauer, and Ott (2005),Hennessy and Whited (2005), Hennessy and Whited (2007), Moyen (2007), Titman and Tsyplakov (2007), and Gamba and Triantis (2008)). 5

profitability (see, for example, Dangl and Zechner (2004) and Dangl and Zechner (2007)). Thus, dynamic tradeoff models predict asymmetric adjustments towards the target leverage ratio: Firms respond to increased profitability by increasing leverage but are reluctant to adjust in response to decreasing profitability. 4 Firms reluctance to reduce debt in response to lower profitability can be mitigated in two ways. First, instead of considering only perpetual debt, as most of the models referred to above do, one can consider finite debt maturities. As shown by Dangl and Zechner (2007), firms may then decide not to roll over expiring short term debt in bad times, since this could be too expensive. Thus, short-term debt induces firms to effectively reduce leverage in bad times by not fully rolling over short term debt. Second, instead of calling debt at the call price, firms may be able to renegotiate debt after a drop in profitability. In the presence of bankruptcy costs, it may be rational for bondholders to accept equityholders renegotiation offers, even if this implies partial debt forgiveness. This has been demonstrated, for example, by Mella-Barral and Perraudin (1997), Mella-Barral (1999), and Hege and Mella-Barral (2005). Such renegotiation offers may not be feasible if the debt is public and held by dispersed investors (for a discussion of related issues, see, for example, Gertner and Scharfstein (1991)). Thus, the countercyclicality of leverage during downturns can be mitigated by shorter debt maturities and if large blocks of debt are non-public. Summarizing our discussion so far, the following hypotheses emerge from dynamic tradeoff models: Firms market leverage target ratios are constant, whereas their book leverage ratios are pro-cyclical. Also, the speed of adjustment towards the target ratio is asymmetric: it is higher during expansions and lower during contractions. The latter effect should be mitigated if corporate debt is short-term and if large blocks are non-public. More recently, dynamic capital structure models have been extended to allow for the business cycle to affect either the level or the drift of the state variable. For example, the level of corporate cash flows and/or its drift may decrease (increase) during recessions (expansions). These effects on the model parameters influence firms target leverage ratios. During economic expansions, for example, the expected costs of bankruptcy are lower for a given debt level and the expected tax benefit may be higher. Thus, as shown by Bhamra, Kuehn, and Strebulaev (2009), target leverage ratios during expansions are higher for plausible model parameterizations. 4 The relationship between firm profitability/cash flow and leverage dynamics in the presence of transactions costs is illustrated for simulated economies in Strebulaev (2007). 6

Opposite results are found by Hackbarth, Miao, and Morellec (2006). They argue that the present value of future cash-flows is pro-cyclical and that this effect dominates the pro-cyclical choice of debt, leading overall to countercyclical leverage ratios. Thus, according to this literature, the predicted dynamics of market leverage ratios are ambiguous they can be pro-cyclical or counter-cyclical. Gamba and Triantis (2008) develop a dynamic model that incorporates both, pecking order concepts and the trade-off between tax benefit against financialdistress. 5 Sinceitismorecostlyforafirmtoadjustitsdebtthanits cash holdings, their model predicts that a matured firm, which has already reached its steady state, maintains a constant debt level and adjusts its cash holdings, i.e. net debt level, in response to the time-varying profitability. Therefore, leverage ratios are counter-cyclical but net leverage ratios are more pro-cyclical. As Gamba and Triantis (2008) only discuss the levels of debt and cash, we interpret their predictions to apply to both, book and market, leverage ratios. Yu (2010) presents another dynamic model that incorporates aspects of pecking order and tradeoff theory. He allows firms to simultaneously make dynamic leverage and investment decisions over the business cycle. Again, the business cycle affects the model parameters. In the absence of investment, this model also implies pro-cyclical leverage, as in Bhamra, Kuehn, and Strebulaev (2009). However, the explicit consideration of investment opportunities changes this result, since investments are funded according to a version of the pecking order. I.e. investment is first funded via internally generated cash, then via debt and only in exceptions via equity. In his model, both the trade-off between tax benefit against bankruptcy costs and the pecking order of financing affect a firm s capital structure and investment policies. Financially constrained firms have to follow the pecking order when they are at external financing margin but unconstrained firms have the privilege to trade-off tax benefit against bankruptcy costs. This generates counter-cyclicality of book and market leverage for firms that are financially constrained. These are likely to be small, growth, and/or highly levered firms. The models discussed so far focus largely on the tradeoff between tax benefits of debt versus bankruptcy costs. There are other papers which derive implications for leverage dynamics driven by time-varying collateral values, by time-varying agency costs or by dynamic versions of the pecking 5 Though in their model only risk-less debt contracts are studied, a firm s borrowing capacity is constrained by its assets fire sale discount in financial distress. 7

order theory. Several models explore the effect of borrowers deteriorating balance sheets on their ability to obtain bank loans. In these papers firms access to outside debt is limited by the amount of collateral they have. If a recession leads to a drop in the value of the assets which can be pledged as collateral, this also limits debt financing. Examples for models that explore this are Bernanke and Gertler (1989), Calomiris and Hubbard (1990), Gertler (1992), Greenwald and Stiglitz (1992), Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), and Shleifer and Vishny (1992). These models predict pro-cyclical financial structures, since firms access to external debt markets is limited during contractions due to decreased collateral values. Levy and Hennessy (2007) model time varying agency costs and their effects on leverage dynamics. In this model an entrepreneur must hold a minimum share of the firm s equity and keep the firm s leverage below some critical upper bound to commit not to divert earnings and/or assets. In this setup firms are more highly equity financed during expansions and more levered during contractions. The model predicts that these counter-cyclical swings would be sharper for firms with good governance and for firms which are less financially constrained. 2.2 Capital market-driven capital structure dynamics Another, somewhat less developed strand of literature focuses on capital market driven determinants of firms financial structures. There are at least two potential channels, through which such supplyside effects can arise. First, raising external capital requires the services of intermediaries, either by directly relying on funding via bank loans, private debt placements, private equity, etc. or by relying on intermediaries as underwriters in the primary market for corporate securities or as market makers in the secondary market. Second, liquidity in the secondary markets for corporate securities may change over the business cycle and thus have an effect on firms capital structure choice. If the costs of intermediation and market illiquidity vary with the business cycle, then firms leverage dynamics should reflect such variations. The first supply side channel mentioned above has been explored by analyzing shocks to intermediaries capital. If intermediaries lending capacities are limited by the amount of capital, for example via regulation, then an adverse shock may have a direct effect on the amount of credit banks can supply to businesses. Holmstrom and Tirole (1997) develop a model, where intermediaries are exposed to capital shocks. They show that poorly capital- 8

ized firms that have limited access to the public debt and equity markets are affected most by adverse shocks to intermediaries capital. Other analyses of this potential effect on capital structure are presented by Bernanke and Blinder (1992), Romer, Romer, Goldfeld, and Friedman (1990), or Kashyap, Stein, and Wilcox (1993). 6 To the extent that economic expansions are correlated with higher amounts of capital for financial intermediaries, this implies pro-cyclical leverage dynamics. A young but growing literature explores time varying secondary market liquidity. Several recent papers provide models of secondary markets for corporate debt which are characterized by search costs. Examples are Ericsson and Renault (2006) and Duffie, Garleanu, and Pedersen (2007). In these models, search costs may increase during recessions. If the expected costs of trading in the secondary market is discounted in the issue price, then these models are consistent with lower leverage during contractions, i.e. procyclicality. Note that this only applies to firms borrowing via publicly held bonds, not bank debt. Hennessy and Zechner (2011) show that secondary debt markets become particularly fragile during contractions. In such situations multiple equilibria arise where secondary debt markets may freeze. Hennessy and Zechner (2011) show that this leads tofinancing cycles, where firms use lessdebt during contractions. 7 Again this predicts pro-cyclical leverage for firms which rely on public debt. 2.3 Market-timing driven capital structure dynamics Deviations from fundamental valuations may also influence capital structure choices. For example, Graham and Harvey (2001) find in a survey that the majority of CFOs state that the amount by which their stock is over- or undervalued plays an important role when deciding whether to issue equity or not. The effect of investors with limited rationality on financial markets has been analyzed theoretically, for example, by Fischer and Merton (1984), De Long, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann (1990), Morck, Shleifer, and Vishny(1990), and Blanchard, Rhee, and Summers(1993), and Stein(1996). According to this literature, firms can actively exploit misvaluations by timing their equity and debt issues. Specifically, firms time IPOs and seasoned stock offerings to take advantage of high market valuation levels and/orarun-upintheirstockprice(forsomeempiricalevidenceonsuchtim- 6 For an interesting empirical study of this channel, see Leary (2009). 7 Bhamra, Kuehn, and Strebulaev (2009) also model exogenously varying debt market illiquidity during contractions. This leads to pro-cyclical leverage dynamics. 9

ing, see, for example, Pagano, Panetta, and Zingales (1998)). Furthermore, according to this literature, corporate debt is issued when equity valuation levels are low and/or interest rates are low (see, for example, Baker and Wurgler (2002) for empirical evidence on the market timing view of capital structure dynamics). According to this literature, firms should exhibit strongly counter-cyclical leverage ratios, both in terms of market values and in terms of book values. According to the market timing hypothesis firms should issue equity at the peak of an expansion, when equity valuation levels reach their highest levels, thereby reducing their leverage. At the trough of a contraction, equity valuations and interest rates are usually low, and firms would therefore prefer to issue debt, thus increasing their leverage further. 8 2.4 Hypotheses We now summarize the main hypotheses generated by the three strands of literature discussed above. The discussion of the previous chapter illustrates that there is considerable heterogeneity among the predictions of the mentioned models. In general, we distinguish hypotheses regarding business cycle dynamics of target leverage ratios and business cycle differences of speed of adjustment estimates towards these target ratios. An important complication arises because many theory models don t explicitly distinguish between book and market leverage ratios or focus on either one and are silent on what should happen to the other one. According to our interpretation, in many cases models predict the same dynamics for book and market leverage ratios. 9 Standard tradeoff theory is an exception, as it predicts constant market leverage ratios that imply pro-cyclical book leverage ratios. Wherever possible we will try to carefully disentangle our predictions and results according to this dimension. As far as the dynamics of target leverage are concerned, we evaluate the following specific hypotheses: 8 There is potentially another, behaviorally based channel of demand driven capital structure dynamics. This occurs when managers go through sentiment waves. I.e. sometimes they are overconfident, and issue debt. At other times they issue equity. One could even think of sun spot equilibria, where managers want to behave in a way that is similar to their peers. I.e. if some firms issue debt, other firms follow to imitate them. 9 In the case of pro-cyclical dynamics this argument is easy to see, as market leverage can only be pro-cyclical if book leverage is even more pro-cyclical. In the case of counter-cyclical market leverage, the implied prediction about book leverage is ambiguous. Nevertheless, as long as the theory does not explicitly suggest procyclical book leverage, we also assume the prediction of counter-cyclical book leverage. 10

H-TL 1a: Book and Market leverage ratios are pro-cyclical over the business cycle according to (i) dynamic tradeoff models without 10 and, partly, with explicit business cycle state variables 11, (ii) models of time-varying collateral values and (iii) capital market driven capital structure models. H-TL 1b: In contrast, market and book leverage ratios are counter-cyclical over the business cycle in (i) (some) dynamic tradeoff models with explicit business cycle state variables, (ii) hybrid dynamic capital structure models that include pecking order and tradeoff concepts, (iii) in dynamic agency cost models, and (iv) in market timing driven capital structure models. These general hypotheses can be refined along the following dimensions. H-TL 2: Net book and market leverage ratios are pro-cyclical according to hybrid dynamic capital structure models that include pecking order and tradeoff concepts. H-TL 3a: Book and market leverage ratios are more pro-cyclical for financially constrained firms than for unconstrained firms according to (i) models of time-varying collateral values and (ii) capital constraints in the banking sector. H-TL 3b: Book and market leverage ratios (especially short-term) are more counter-cyclical for constrained firms according to (i) dynamic tradeoff models with BC variables, investment and pecking order components and (ii) time-varying agency costs. H-TL 4a: Long-term book and market debt ratios should be more pro-cyclical (less counter-cyclical) than short-term leverage ratios if information asymmetries increase during recessions. H-TL 4b: Long-term book and market debt ratios should be less pro-cyclical (more counter-cyclical) than short-term leverage ratios if transactions costs of rolling over short-term debt are higher during recessions, and 10 To be precise, standard dynamic tradeoff models predict constant market leverage ratios. We included the predictions from this model class in this hypothesis in order to keep the number of hypotheses manageable. 11 This class of dynamic capital structure models has ambiguous predictions: Bhamra, Kuehn, and Strebulaev (2009), for example, support pro-cyclicality, while Hackbarth, Miao, and Morellec (2006) suggest opposite dynamics. The latter paper, thus, belongs to Hypothesis H-TL 1b. 11

debt maturity is largely a tradeoff between some benefits of short-term debt, such as a commitment to debt reductions or the signaling effect. H-TL 5a: Firms in common law (civil law) countries exhibit more procyclical (counter-cyclical) leverage dynamics for book and market values in dynamic tradeoff models without investment. H-TL 5b: Firms in countries with higher proportions of public debt exhibit more counter-cyclical book and market leverage dynamics according to the debt renegotiation literature. In addition to target leverage ratios we also analyze the speed of adjustment (SOA) of leverage ratios towards these target leverage ratios. Here are the hypotheses regarding the speed of adjustment. H-SOA 1: The speed of adjustment towards the target ratio is higher during expansions and lower during contractions according to dynamic tradeoff models without explicit business cycle state variables. H-SOA 2: The difference between the speed of adjustment towards the target leverage ratio in expansions and in contractions is lower for firms with large proportions of public debt according to the debt renegotiation literature. 3 Data and Empirical Design 3.1 Data and Sample Our source of business cycle data is Economic Cycle Research Institute (ECRI) s international cycle dates. We use the business cycle chronologies file, which includes countries from America, Europe, Asia Pacific, Africa, and Middle East regions. In order to have information on both business cycle dates and firm-level variables, we end up with 19 countries, ranging from developing to developed economies and from common-law to civillaw countries. Specifically, these countries are: Australia, Austria, Brazil, Canada, China, France, Germany, India, Italy, Japan, Korea, Mexico, New Zealand, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Taiwan, UK, and USA. We use Worldscope to obtain annual firm-level accounting data. Our sample period is from 1983 to 2009 12. In our subsequent analysis, we remove 12 In our sample some countries have shorter period of data available than others. We don t have firms from all countries for all years between 1983 and 2009. However, our first observations are in 1983 and last observations are in 2009. 12

China from our database because there are no recessions during the sample period. Variable definitions are given in Appendix A and summarized in Table 1. Financial firms are usually regulated and hence their leverage choices ought to be quite different from other industrial firms. For this reason and following the literature, we remove all financial firms, i.e. all firms with WSIC between 4300 and 4400 are deleted from our sample. We also drop firm-year observations such that either of the following conditions are met: (i) zero total assets value, (ii) zero market capitalization, (iii) total debt greater than total asset, (iv) market asset less than cash, (v) total asset less than cash, and (vi) negative cash. Following Korajczyk and Levy (2003), we assume that a firm is financially constrained if the following conditions are fulfilled: (1) the firm does not have a net purchase of debt or equity and does not pay dividends within the event window, and (2) the firms market to book ratio, defined as the sum of the market capitalization of equity and the book value of debt, divided by the book value of assets, at the fiscal year end is greater than one. In our empirical analysis, we consider each of eight leverage ratios (four based on book values and four based on market values) as a dependent variable. Book total leverage ratio (bl) is the total debt to total assets ratio. Book long-term leverage ratio (bl lt) is the long-term debt to total assets ratio. Book short term leverage ratio (bl st) is the short-term debt to total assets ratio. Book net leverage ratio (bl net) is the total debt less cash 13 to total assets less cash ratio. Market value based leverage ratios (Market total leverage ratio (ml), Market long term leverage ratio (ml lt), Market short term leverage ratio (ml st) and Market net leverage ratio (ml net)) are calculated in a similar fashion by only replacing total assets in the above definitions by market value. A recession dummy that is 1 during recessions and 0 otherwise (Rec) is our key independent variable. More precisely, this dummy is equal to 1 if a firm s entire fiscal year overlaps with a recession. 14 We also control for other variables, which have been widely used in the literature, including the logarithm of Net Sales (sales), market to book ratio (market to book), EBITDA to total assets ratio (profitability), PPE to total assets ratio (tangibility), industry median leverage ratio (industry median), dividend payer dummy 13 The cash variable includes cash and short-term investments. 14 This definition is a relatively conservative way of identifying recessions. There are, however, two advantages: (i) the definition is most precise in aligning yearly firm data with recession information, and (ii) the definition requires that recessions last for at least 12 months and, thus, filters out less severe recessions. 13

(dividend payer), which equals 1 if a firm pays out dividend and 0 otherwise. Last but not least, lagged leverage ratios are used to capture the persistence in leverage dynamics. We further drop observations with (i) negative net sales, (ii) book net leverage ratio of less than -1, and (iii) market net leverage ratio of less than -1. We do allow firms, at some point in time, to be cash savers, i.e. carrying a negative net leverage ratio, rather than borrowers. However, we remove firm-year observations with net leverage ratios less than -1 because such firms hold a tremendous amount of cash relative to their other type of assets and hence are unlikely to be normal industrial firms. Table 2 summarizes the descriptive statistics of our key variables of interest. Means and standard deviations of variables for the entire sample are given in Panel A. Panel B shows that leverage ratios, in particular market leverage ratios, tend to be higher in recessions than in expansions. Panel C presents the summary statistics of our variables when the sample is split by financial constraints. Financially unconstrained firms are more levered than constrained firms. Further, constrained firms tend to have higher market to book ratios as well as lower profitability and tangibility than unconstrained companies. As shown in Panel D, firms from developing countries, on average, have higher leverage than firms from developed economies. The intuition is that developing countries tend to have less developed equity capital markets and poorer corporate governance leading to higher cost of equity capital. Panel E lists the summary statistics of our variables when the sample is split by origin of law. In general, leverage ratios of civil-lawcountry firms are higher than leverage ratios of common-law-country firms. Again, this is likely due to the fact that common-law countries, on average, enjoy good corporate governance, which tilts firms external finance choice towards equity finance. 3.2 Empirical Specification In our empirical analysis we follow Flannery and Rangan (2006) and estimate dynamic partial adjustment capital structure models (DPACS-Model) including firm fixed effects. 15 These models contemporaneously estimate time-varying target leverage ratios and estimates of the speed of adjustment with which actual leverage ratios move towards target leverage ratios. In this research we, in particular, examine the effect of business cycles on a firm s target leverage ratio as well as its speed of adjustment towards the 15 See Chang and Dasgupta (2009) and Iliev and Welch (2010) for critical discussions of these models. 14

target. Specifically, our dynamic partial adjustment capital structure model (DPACS-model) is given by, lr j,i,t+1 = ρ rec lr j,i,t Ij,t+1+ρ rec exp lr j,i,t I exp j,t+1 +αrec j,t+1+βx j,i,t +δ j,i +e j,i,t+1, (1) wherelr {bl, bl lt, bl st, bl net, ml, ml lt, ml st, ml net},ij,t+1 rec = 1(Iexp j,t+1 = 1) during recessions (expansions), countries are indexed by subscript j, firms by i, and periods by t, and δ j,i is a firm fixed effect. The speed of adjustment estimate (SOA-estimate) is defined as λ rec = 1 ρ rec (λ exp = 1 ρ exp ) during recessions (expansions). Given the above specification, λ rec (λ exp ) measures the fraction of the difference between a firm s actual and its target leverage ratios, both of which are time-varying, that has been closed during recessions (expansions). As far as time-varying target leverage is concerned, recall that Rec is the recession dummy. X j,i,t is a vector of lagged firm-level characteristics, i.e. X = sales market to book profitability tangibility industry median dividend payer. (2) The coefficient α and the coefficient vector β capture the influence of the business cycle variable and the above explanatory variables on target leverage. 16 4 Empirical Results: Target Leverage Ratios In this section, we present our empirical results concentrating on insights with regard to the relationship between business cycles and firms target leverage ratios. 4.1 Total Debt Several of the hypotheses discussed in subsection 2.4 predict differences between leverage ratios during recessions and during expansions. Table 3 16 The estimates of α and β are also affected by λ (see equation (4) in Flannery and Rangan (2006)). In the results section, we report unadjusted coefficient estimates. Where necessary, we show and discuss the adjustment in the text(i.e., when we compare estimates of α and β across subsamples). 15

shows the results from dynamic partial adjustment capital structure models (DPACS-Models) for book and market leverage ratios. In this subsection, we focus on the coefficients in front of the recession dummy. 17 In DPACS- Models, these coefficients can be interpreted as measures of the impact of recessions on target leverage ratios. Our main hypotheses, H-TL 1a and H-TL 1b, suggest that from a theoretical point of view both pro-cyclical (negative coefficient) and countercyclical (positive coefficient) patterns of book and market leverage can be justified. Standard trade-off models without investment variables even predict no effect of business cycle variation on market leverage ratios. The column labeled All in Table 3 Panel A summarizes our results for book leverage ratios for the entire sample of firms. In this case, we find a statistically significant, negative coefficient. This implies that overall book leverage seems to behave in a pro-cyclical way it shrinks during recessions and increases during expansions. For market leverage (Table 3 Panel B), in contrast, we observe strong counter-cyclicality. This effect seems to be driven by the decrease in market valuation (the denominator in the ratios) during recessions. Overall, our results pro-cyclicality of book leverage and countercyclicality of market leverage are only partly consistent with dynamic capital structure theories. Pro-cyclical book leverage is broadly speaking consistent with dynamic tradeoff models, with models of time-varying collateral values and capital market driven capital structure models. But counter-cyclical market leverage is inconsistent with these kind of models. Some dynamic tradeoff models that explicitly model business cycle state variables and time-varying agency models predict counter-cyclical market leverage ratios. But, then these versions of dynamics tradeoff models are inconsistent with pro-cyclical book leverage. Other models that are consistent with counter-cyclical market leverage dynamics are hybrid dynamic capital structure models that include pecking order and tradeoff concepts, dynamic agency costs models and market timing driven capital structure models. But, again, these models usually also predict counter-cyclical book leverage. Thus, to this end, we are unable to identify a specific dynamic capital structure theory that is entirely consistent with our empirical results. Another set of hypotheses addresses the influence of financial constraints 17 The results with respect to our standard controls and their influence on leverage ratios are broadly consistent with the existing literature. These coefficients and their variation across samples and leverage definitions are, however, not the main interest of our paper. Thus, for reasons of brevity, we don t discuss them in detail in the current version of the paper. 16

on the dynamics of capital structure. As in the case of total debt, theory supports both pro-cyclical(h-tl 3a, models of time-varying collateral values and capital constraints in the banking sector) and counter-cyclical (H-TL 3b, dynamic tradeoff models with BC variables, investment and pecking order components and models with time-varying agency costs) patterns. The columns labeled Unconstrained and Constrained in Table 3 show the appropriate results. Following theoretical predictions and common intuition, our results suggest that business cycle variation affects the capital structure of unconstrained firms differently than the one of financially constrained firms. While we find that book leverage is significantly pro-cyclical for unconstrained firms, we find a positive (counter-cyclicality) but insignificant coefficient for the subset of financially constrained firms. Ignoring for a moment that the coefficient is insignificant, our empirical results support hypothesis H-TL 3b. The more pronounced (but statistically insignificant) counter-cyclicality of financially constrained firms in the case of book leverage implies that these firms seem to be less responsive to issue more debt during expansions than financially unconstrained firms. This finding has several potential explanations. First, financially constrained firms are likely to be more risky, and thus have wider recapitalization bands (i.e., recapitalize less frequently) than less risky unconstrained firms, according to classic dynamic tradeoff theories (e.g. Fischer, Heinkel, and Zechner (1989a)). Second, constrained firms may be forced to issue debt with shorter maturities, which must be rolled over in shorter periods (this aspect will be discussed in more detail later on). However, a high short-term debt ratio creates a particularly significant funding risk if access to debt markets is difficult during recessions. Third, financially constrained firms may experience much sharper freezes of their primary debt markets during recessions than financially unconstrained firms. That is, during recessions debt markets may be characterized by a flight to quality, which affects constrained firms access to debt markets more severely than unconstrained firms. Thus, constrained firms are reluctant to increase their leverage during expansions. In the case of market leverage, we find a related result: unconstrained firms show a strong counter-cyclical pattern but, in the case of financially constrained firms, we find no effect. Thus, again the patterns are quite different but this specific result is somewhat surprising, as we would have expected to find rather more than less counter-cyclicality in the case of financially constrained firms. Note, however, that the sample size in case of financially constrained firms is much smaller than in the case of unconstrained firms. Thus, the results with respect to financially constrained firms 17

must be interpreted cautiously. 18 Our last set of hypotheses with respect to target leverage ratios addresses the influence of a country s legal origin and its degree of development on the leverage dynamics across the business cycle. The idea is that in common-law countries, owners of publicly traded stocks or bonds are better protected, and thus a larger fraction of firms funding comes directly from the capital market rather than from banks. By contrast, in civil law countries and developing countries 19 a smaller fraction of corporate funding is obtained via issues of public equity and public corporate debt, and more funding occurs via bank loans. While standard dynamic tradeoff models suggest that firms in common law (civil law) countries exhibit more pro-cyclical (countercyclical) leverage dynamics (H-TL 5a), models in the debt renegotiation literature argue in the opposite direction (H-TL 5b). Columns 4 to 7 of Table 3 summarize the results. The only sub-sample for which we find statistical significance in the case of book leverage is the sample of firms from developed economies. As before we find pro-cyclical leverage dynamics. If we split the sample by legal origin, we unfortunately lose significance. Nevertheless, point estimates of the coefficients point into opposite directions: they imply pro-cyclical patterns for firms from common law countries and counter-cyclical patterns for firms from civil law countries. This last result, although statistically insignificant, would be consistent with dynamic tradeoff theory (Hypothesis H-TL 5a). In the case of market leverage we find consistently significant and positive coefficients implying counter-cyclical dynamics across all four sub-samples. Comparing the relative magnitudes of the coefficient estimates suggests a stronger influence of recessions on firms from common law countries (and firms from developing countries). This result, in contrast to the one for book leverage, seems to be more in support of the debt renegotiation literature. 4.2 Net Leverage In this section, we interpret cash and marketable securities as negative debt and, accordingly, subtract them from total debt. Thus, the variable of interest in this section is net leverage. In contrast to book leverage, we find a strongly significant and positive coefficient for the recession dummy in the 18 We are in the process of looking into other definitions of financial constraints that would provide is with a larger sample of constrained firms. 19 Note that our current sample of countries shows a very homogenous distribution among common law and civil law countries but covers comparatively few observations from developing countries. 18

caseofnetbookleverage(table4panela).fornetmarketleverage(table4 Panel B) we find the same pattern, namely strong counter-cyclicality. Thus, in contrast to our hypothesis, H-TL 2, net leverage seems to be countercyclical, in general. Considering the results for total book debt, the effect on net book debt must be driven by the level of cash reserves that seem to be strongly reduced during recessions (pushing net book leverage upward). Thus, firms build up financial slack during expansionary times. Then, during recessions, they use slack to partly fund capital expenditures and/or cash distributions to shareholders. One would expect that this effect is particularly pronounced for financially constrained firms. Columns 2 and 3 of Table 4 compare the results for financially constrained and unconstrained firms. In the case of book values, the results confirm our above conjecture: net book debt ratios are more strongly affected by the business cycle (i.e., more counter-cyclical) for financially constrained than unconstrained firms. The coefficient of interest in Table 4 Panel A is nearly four times as large for the sub-sample of financially constrained firms. 20 In the case of market net leverage, we don t find this result: estimated coefficients are very similar. 21 Although we don t have specific hypotheses for the relationship between business cycle variation, net leverage ratios and legal origin/economic development of a firm s home country, we included the empirical results in Table 4. The results don t show a lot of variation across samples: we find consistently significant counter-cyclical dynamics. The only exception are firms from developing countries and book net leverage where the estimated coefficient is negative but insignificant. 4.3 Short-Term Debt vs. Long-Term Debt In this subsection we wish to gain deeper insights into the dynamics of firms financial maturity structures over the business cycle. As discussed in subsection 2.4, informational asymmetries may require firms to choose short maturities. If a recession makes the presence of informational asymmetries more likely, then we should expect debt maturity to become shorter (Hypothesis H-TL 4a). By contrast, if transactions costs of rolling over short-term debt are higher during recessions, and debt maturity is largely 20 For this cross-sample comparison we have to adjust the reported coefficients by dividing them by 1-β (β is an average of the coefficients estimated for recessions and expansions, β rec and β exp). In this case the adjustment has basically no effect on the comparison. 21 And after controlling for the partial adjustment effect, the counter-cyclicality of unconstrained firms becomes even stronger compared to financially constrained firms. 19