Taxing Choices: International Competition, Domestic Institutions, and the. Transformation of Corporate Tax Policy, Journal of European Public Policy.

Similar documents
Taxing Choices: International Competition, Domestic Institutions, and the Transformation of Corporate Tax Policy

Market Institutions and Income Inequality *

Tax competition and inequality

The Impact of Tax Policies on Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Economies

Income inequality and the growth of redistributive spending in the U.S. states: Is there a link?

The Spread of Neoliberalism: U.S. Economic Power and the Diffusion of Market-Oriented Tax Policy

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade

FISCAL CONSOLIDATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CASE STUDY OF PAKISTAN. Ahmed Waqar Qasim Muhammad Ali Kemal Omer Siddique

Online appendix to Mark My Words: Information and the Fear of Declaring an Exchange Rate Regime

Input Tariffs, Speed of Contract Enforcement, and the Productivity of Firms in India

Online Appendices for

Inequality and GDP per capita: The Role of Initial Income

Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality. June 19, 2017

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Globalization and International Tax Competition: Empirical Evidence Based on Effective Tax Rates

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations

Motivation and questions to be addressed

GDP per Head and Labour Productivity

The effect of globalization on capital taxation: What have we learned after 20 years of empirical studies?

Globalization and International Tax Competition: Empirical Evidence Based on Effective Tax Rates

Greenfield Investments, Cross-border M&As, and Economic Growth in Emerging Countries

The Impact of U.S. Trade Agreements on Growth in Output and Labor Productivity of FTA Partner Countries

Redistribution Effects of Electricity Pricing in Korea

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

International Journal of Advance Research in Computer Science and Management Studies

Taxation, Corruption, and Growth. William Kerr

The relation between financial development and economic growth in Romania


Company Stock Price Reactions to the 2016 Election Shock: Trump, Taxes, and Trade INTERNET APPENDIX. August 11, 2017

Internet Appendix for Does Banking Competition Affect Innovation? 1. Additional robustness checks

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV

INTERMEDIATE PUBLIC ECONOMICS. second edition. Jean Hindriks and Gareth D. Myles. The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England

URL:

Deep Determinants. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () Deep Determinants 1 / 65

Institutional Investor Cliques and Governance: Internet Appendix

Military Expenditures, External Threats and Economic Growth. Abstract

Julio Videras Department of Economics Hamilton College

From Communism to Capitalism: Private vs. Public Property and Rising. Inequality in China and Russia

Online Appendix Results using Quarterly Earnings and Long-Term Growth Forecasts

The Relative Income Hypothesis: A comparison of methods.

Does the Equity Market affect Economic Growth?

Online Appendix (Not For Publication)

THE EFFECTIVENESS OF COMPETITION LAW IN PROMOTING ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT

Research Philosophy. David R. Agrawal University of Michigan. 1 Themes

Lottery Revenue and Cross-Border Shopping: A Nation-Wide Analysis. Brandli Stitzel West Texas A&M University. Under the supervision of:

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

6 Private Social Security and International Economic Integration

With CIS celebrating its 40th

Macroeconomic Policy: Evidence from Growth Laffer Curve for Sri Lanka. Sujith P. Jayasooriya, Ch.E. (USA) Innovation4Development Consultants

The Impact of Taxation and Public Expenditure on Income Distribution in Indonesia

There is poverty convergence

Using Land Values to Predict Future Farm Income

Public Good Provision Rules and Income Distribution: Some General Equilibrium Calculations

Does External Debt Lead to Growth in the Presence of Quality Institutions?

Internet Appendix to Does Policy Uncertainty Affect Mergers and Acquisitions?

The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment on the Export Performance: Empirical Evidence for Western Balkan Countries

Online Appendix to Do Tax Changes Affect Credit Markets and Financial Frictions? Evidence from Credit Spreads

Capital Mobility and Tax Competition: Empirical Evidence from South Asia

URBAN INFRASTRUCTURE FINANCING AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE IN CHINA

The Plato Index of tax justice: what it is, where we are and where we are going. Valpy FitzGerald Oxford University

Equality and Fertility: Evidence from China

Centre for Economic Policy Research

The median voter hypothesis, income inequality and income redistribution: An empirical test with the required data.

Income Inequality, Redistributional Spending & Director s Law An Empirical Investigation

For Online Publication Additional results

Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1

REDISTRIBUTION, INEQUALITY, AND GROWTH

How would an expansion of IDA reduce poverty and further other development goals?

Commodity Price Changes and Economic Growth in Developing Countries

Easy and Hard Redistribution: The Political Economy of Welfare States in Latin America

Has Indonesia s Growth Between Been Pro-Poor? Evidence from the Indonesia Family Life Survey

Do Redistributive State Taxes Reduce Inequality?

THE WILLIAM DAVIDSON INSTITUTE AT THE UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN BUSINESS SCHOOL

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

MAKING FINANCIAL GLOBALIZATION MORE INCLUSIVE

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Rate Cutting Tax Reforms and Corporate Tax Competition in Europe

Economic Importance of Keynesian and Neoclassical Economic Theories to Development

Poverty and Poverty Reduction: Relationship between alternative measures of social spending and poverty rates across countries.

Foreign Direct Investment, International Trade and Economic Growth in Pakistan s Economic Perspective

The Impacts of State Tax Structure: A Panel Analysis

Local Government Spending and Economic Growth in Guangdong: The Key Role of Financial Development. Chi-Chuan LEE

Inequality and Economic Growth

1) The Effect of Recent Tax Changes on Taxable Income

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

The Aggregate and Distributional Effects of Financial Globalization: Evidence from Macro and Sectoral Data

working paper Fiscal Policy, Government Institutions, and Sovereign Creditworthiness By Bernardin Akitoby and Thomas Stratmann No.

Composition of Foreign Capital Inflows and Growth in India: An Empirical Analysis.

AUTHOR ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT

This paper examines the effects of tax

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

The Impact of Retrenchment and Reemployment Project on the Returns to Education of Laid-off Workers

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Influence the Balancing Item in Japan? An Empirical Note. Tuck Cheong Tang

1.3 Prices, Supply, and Demand Compare how supply, demand, price, equilibrium, elasticity, and incentives affect the workings of a market.

Supplementary Appendix. July 22, 2016

CROATIA S EU CONVERGENCE REPORT: REACHING AND SUSTAINING HIGHER RATES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH, Document of the World Bank, June 2009, pp.

Economics 448: Lecture 14 Measures of Inequality

The Impact of FTAs on FDI in Korea

Conditional Convergence: Evidence from the Solow Growth Model

Why Do Firms Evade Taxes? The Role of Information Sharing and Financial Sector Outreach The Journal of Finance. Thorsten Beck Chen Lin Yue Ma

Transcription:

Taxing Choices: International Competition, Domestic Institutions, and the Transformation of Corporate Tax Policy, Journal of European Public Policy. Duane Swank, Department of Political Science, Marquette University PO Box 1881 Milwaukee, WI 53201-1881; Phone: 1 414 466-9459 Email: duane.swank@marquette.edu Online Appendix An Overview of Supplementary Estimations The first column of the Online Appendix table displays the results of estimation of the final model of corporate tax rates. As suggested in the text (see the discussion of Table 2 results), the varieties of coordination model (in which the impacts of U.S. rate change are mediated by coordination) is arguably the most robust and theoretically encompassing model among relevant alternatives. It is displayed in the first column to establish a baseline for comparison across alternative specifications and estimations. In the second column of the table, I report the results of estimation without fixed effects; as noted in the text, there are pluses and minuses of the fixed effects specification. As the table reveals, other than an occasional shift in the substantive magnitude of a coefficient, there is little difference between estimations with and without fixed effects. The third column of the table estimates a standard weighted spatial lag model. The underlying assumption is that nations simultaneously see each others policies and competitively respond. As the model entails substantial risk of endogeneity, I follow suggestions in Franzese

and Hays (2007) and use a spatial-two-stage least squares estimator where the instrument for rates in competitors is predicted by exogenous variables in competitors. Weights for degree of competition among nations are the same as those discussed in the text for signals of tax reform in competitors in the Nash model. As Online Appendix Table 1 suggests, net of U.S. tax reforms and their median by coordination as well as direct impacts of international and domestic factors, rate change in competitors does not significantly shape statutory corporate tax rates. The fourth column displays analysis of the effects of dramatic tax reforms in the postcommunist East European nations. A highly plausible argument is that the integration of postcommunist political economies with advanced capitalist democracies of Western Europe intensifies tax competition in Europe (Genschel, Kemmerling, and Seils 2011). Generally, one would expect that rich European nations, especially those with extensive economic ties with the East (i.e., border nations), will be particularly sensitive to the widespread adoption of the flat tax in Eastern Europe. I test that hypothesis in the model of column four. In that estimation, I interact the proportion of post-communist East European nations that have adopted the flat tax with European nations that border the East; I also use broader measures of rich EU and total European nations for these interactions. In the table s model as well as these alternatives, there was no evidence of significantly greater pressure on rich European nations to cut rates as the East adopted a radical neoliberal model. In many of these specifications, the flat-tax adoption variable has a marginally significant, negative effect on corporate tax rates in all nations. The model of the fifth column estimates the independent effects of country size on corporate tax rates. In the classic formulation, small countries gain an advantage by cutting corporate rates when capital is liberalized. The relative gains of large inflows of capital (relative

to the small nation s limited capital tax base) offset the losses in revenues from lower rates. Large nations, with big domestic capital tax bases and other attractions for internationally mobile capital (e.g., big domestic markets, agglomeration effects), do not face the incentives for comparable cuts in corporate rates (see Haufler and Wooton1999 for an overview of the literature on size and tax competition). As the results displayed in column five suggest, size independent of the other factors in the model plays no particular role in either the short or longterm trajectories of corporate tax rates. The sixth and seventh columns of the table display results for the substitution of actual capital flows for capital market liberalization; the sixth column presents results for re-estimation of the Hays model (2003; 2009) with capital flows, and column seven presents findings for the final model where actual capital flows is substituted for capital liberalization. As discussed in the text, substitution of flows for liberalization produces some support for Hays argument that consensus democracies should feel little pressure to lower corporate rates in the face of rising capital mobility. In column seven, we see that the results of basic model are not altered when one substitutes flows for liberalization of capital flows; the flows measure is marginally significant in the estimation of the final model of corporate rates. Finally, recent research has used alternative measures of egalitarian orientations among the electorate, or potential constituency costs of neoliberal reforms (Plümper, Troeger, and Winner 2009). Drawing on data from the International Social Survey Program, we can compute the support for redistribution for the median voter from the mid-1980s to 2008 in a sub-sample of 14 nations. This measure, as a proxy for fairness norms that create constituency costs for neoliberal reforms, was substituted for the Kim-Fording estimate of the ideological position of

the median voter. Results for this new estimation are shown in the final column of the Appendix table. The impact of support for redistribution by the median voter is correctly signed (lower values indicate higher support of redistribution) but insignificant at conventional levels. (Similar results were obtained for additional alternative measures such as the change between pre- and post-fisc GINI indices of inequality and the level of pre-fisc inequality). References Used in the Online Appendix Franzese, R. and Hays, J. (2007) Spatial econometric models of cross-sectional interdependence in political science panel and time-series-cross-section data, Political Analysis 15 (2): 140-164. Genschel, P., Kemmerling, A., and Seils, E. (2011) Accelerating downhill: how the EU shapes corporate tax competition in the single market, Journal of Common Market Studies 49 (3): 585-606. Haufler, A. and Wooton, I. (1999) Country size and tax competition for foreign direct investment, Journal of Public Economics 71 (1): 121-139. Hays, J. (2003) Globalization and capital taxation in consensus and majoritarian democracies, World Politics 56 (1): 79-113. Hays, J. (2009) Globalization and the New Politics of Embedded Liberalism, New York: Oxford University Press. Plümper, T., Troeger, V. and Winner, H. (2009) Why is there no race to the bottom in capital taxation?, International Studies Quarterly 53 (3): 761-86.

Online Appendix Table 1. Alternative Models and Estimators: Domestic Institutions and International Competition in Corporate Income Tax Rates, 1982-2008. International Competition and Institutions Final Model - No Fixed Effects Instrumented Spatial Lag Flat Tax Adoption in Esat. Europe With Size Control Hays Model Median Voter Redistribution US Statutory/Effective Corporate Tax Rate t-2.2608** (.0482).2200** (.0446).2514** (.0533).2495** (.0468).2472** (.0489).3525** (.0567).3320** (.0573).2624** (.0525) US Statutory/Effective Corporate Tax Rate t-1.4121** (.0887).3287** (.0913).4188** (.0921).4088** (.0832).4041** (.0891).4005** (.0981).4396** (.0948).4063** (.0879) US Statutory/Effective Rate Coordination t-2.1152** (.0442).1072** (.0332).1258** (.0447).1210** (.0449).1239** (.0432).1216** (.0464).1210** (.0443) US Statutory/Effective Rate Coordination t-2 -.3119** (.0909) -.2957** (.0996) -.3048** (.0898) -.3162** (.0884) -.3130** (.0884) -.3363** (.0914) -.3047** (.0925) Competitors Statutory Corporate Tax Rate t-1.0545 (.0753) Competitors Statutory Corporate Tax Rate t.0254 (.1689) Eastern Europe Flat Tax Adoption t-2 -.0189* (.0137) Eastern Europe Flat Tax Adoption t-1 Flat Tax Adoption East Europe Border t-2 Flat Tax Adoption East Europe Border t-2.0108 (.0174) -.0057 (.0188).0007 (.0336) Population Size t-2-2.5459 (3.4461)

Final Model - No Fixed Effects Instrumented Spatial Lag Flat Tax Adoption in Esat. Europe With Size Control Hays Model Median Voter Redistribution Population Size t-1.0586 (.0402) Capital t-2 -.0176** (.0074) Capital t-1 -.0150 (.0209) -.0102* (.0074) -.0103 (.0213) Capital t-2 Consensus Demo t-2 Capital t-1 Consensus Demo t-2.0306** (.0172).0030 (.0466) Median Voter Support for -1.4907 Redistribution t-2 (1.6410) Median Voter Support -1.0450 for Redistribution t-1 (1.8049) International Openness Trade Openness t-2 -.0884** (.0180) -.0224** (.0065) -.0887** (.0199) -.0701** (.0198) -.0827** (.0196) -.0774** (.0201) -.0882** (.0199) -.0866** (.0176) Trade Openness t-1 -.0493** (.0317) -.0264 (.0312) -.0487* (.0346) -.0329 (.0327) -.0482* (.0316) -.0504* (.0366) -.0621** (.0355) -.0517** (.0311) Liberalization of Capital Markets t-2 -.0493** (.0186) -.0138 (.0116) -.0520* (.0187) -.0514** (.0189) -.0513** (.0189) -.0456** (.0197) Liberalization of Capital Markets t-1 -.0144 (.0291) -.0052 (.0304) -.0149 (.0300) -.0171 (.0296) -.0175 (.0296) -.0138 (.0291) Institutions and Politics

Final Model - No Fixed Effects Instrumented Spatial Lag Flat Tax Adoption in Esat. Europe With Size Control Hays Model Median Voter Redistribution Coordination t-2-4.9352* (2.7929) -4.8247** (1.5912) -5.5704** (2.8202) -5.6222** (2.8292) -5.3718 (2.7487) 3.2204** (1.0890) -4.4203 (3.0636) -5.0521* (2.7572) Coordination t-1-1.3828 (1.5784) -1.5478 (1.5359) -1.2217 (1.6152) -1.6927 (1.5879) -1.4576 (1.5779).8479 (1.7218) -.6754 (1.6701) -1.2110 (1.5748) Consensus Demo t-2.3751 (.5376).1249 (.2756).4402 (.5596).6322 (.5430).5017 (.5424) -.0558 (.3683).0174 (.5575).4149 (.5880) Consensus Demo t-1.8946 (.8075).9669 (.8086).9592 (.8072) 1.0226 (.8109).9624 (.8005) 2.1932 (2.2131).8725 (.8964) 1.0120 (.8141) Institutional Veto Points t-2 2.4663** (1.1712).7033** (.2581) 2.6032** (1.2043) 2.5944** (1.1591) 2.4490** (1.1623) 2.1932** (2.2131) -.2192 (1.9891) 2.3211** (1.1822) Institutional Veto Points t-1 2.5848* (1.8947) 1.9542 (1.8683) 2.7343* (1.9096) 2.6729* (1.8610) 2.2601* (1.8926) 2.1932* (2.2131) 2.1602 (2.4269) 2.2739* (1.9118) Ideology -Median Voter t-2.0238* (.0170).0338** (.0578).0238* (.0182).0219* (.0176).0228* (.0171).0389** (.0191).0201 (.0177) Ideology -Median Voter t-2.0413 (.0374).0244 (.0381).0426 (.0382).0438 (.0377).0383 (.0376).0467 (.0404).0404 (.0387) Right Government t-4 to t-2.0031 (.0039).0006 (.0032).0028 (.0038).0027 (.0039).0025 (.0039).0013 (.0041).0031 (.0040).0036 (.0040) Right Government t-4 to t-2.0112 (.0094).0094 (.0096).0089 (.0095).0113 (.0095).0100 (.0094).0096 (.0097).0091 (.0097).0104 (.0097) General Model Structural Unemployment t-2 -.0118 (.0194).0095 (.0085) -.0228 (.0206) -.0175 (.0201) -.0107 (.0197) -.0140 (.0223) -.0117 (.0218) -.0187 (.0200) Structural Unemployment t-1 -.0420 (.0331) -.0298 (.0334) -.0464* (.0338) -.0429 (.0330) -.0340 (.0337) -.0439 (.0361) -.0456* (.0353) -.0477* (.0323)

Final Model - No Fixed Effects Instrumented Spatial Lag Flat Tax Adoption in Esat. Europe With Size Control Hays Model Median Voter Redistribution Public Sector Debt t-2.0264** (.0119).0201** (.0050).0300** (.0126).0292** (.0120).0275** (.0119).0258** (.0113).0197** (.0120).0289** (.0117) Public Sector Debt t-1.0489 (.404).0682** (.0337).0395 (.0409).0422 (.0404).0427 (.0402).0542 (.0442).0413 (.0427).0375 (.0396) Percent Change Real Profits t-2.0705 (.0565).0591 (.0572).0777 (.0602).0553 (.0575).0661 (.0506).0685 (.0592).0806* (.0587).0697 (.0566) Percent Change Real Profits t-1.0602* (.0403).0486 (.0405).0674* (.0419).0569* (.0410).0586* (.0402).0595* (.0425).0668* (.0414).0587* (.0401) Domestic Investment t-2.0130 (.0416).0274 (.0421).0123 (.0420).0204 (.0417).0119 (.0416).0154 (.0459).0127 (.0436).0178 (.0414) Domestic Investment t-1 -.0188 (.0279) -.0190 (.0286) -.0153 (.0284) -.0172 (.0281) -.0197 (.0377) -.0205 (.0310) -.0245 (.0290) -.0187 (.0276) Growth Per Capita Real GDP t-2.1271 (.1427).0113 (.1398).1549 (.1479).1324 (.1445).1287 (.1431).1402 (.1457).1104 (.1527).1125 (.1428) Growth Per Capita Real GDP t-1 ( 100) -.0009 (.0033) -.0006 (.0036) -.0008 (.0035) -.0011 (.0034) -.0008 (.0034) -.0068 (.0036) -.0004 (.0036) -.0015 (.0032) Tax Rate t-1 -.2434** (.0324) -.1549** (.0247) -.2619** (.0349) -.2508** (.0355) -.2458** (.0334) -.2488** (.0379) -.2439** (.0362) -.2338 (.0322) Fixed Effects Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Constant 6.1224-5.0894 5.3768 6.5557 34.6799 -.6392-2.8856 10.2654 Observations 469 469 459 469 469 437 437 469 R 2.2566.1960.2655.2620.2587.2237.2571.2540 Statutory corporate tax models are estimated with 1982-2008 data (effective corporate tax rate with 1982-2005 data) by OLS for 18 or 17 nations (full sample with or without U.S.) The table reports OLS unstandardized regression coefficients and panel correct standard errors (Beck and Katz 1996). * indicates significance at the.10 level or below. ** indicates significance at the.05 level or below.