Dynamic Asset Pricing Model

Similar documents
GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

Lecture 1: Lucas Model and Asset Pricing

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

One-Period Valuation Theory

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing

Applying the Basic Model

Empirical Dynamic Asset Pricing

Slides III - Complete Markets

STOCHASTIC CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL: CANONICAL APPLICATIONS SEPTEMBER 13, 2010 BASICS. Introduction

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Basics of Asset Pricing. Ali Nejadmalayeri

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

Intertemporally Dependent Preferences and the Volatility of Consumption and Wealth

The Capital Asset Pricing Model in the 21st Century. Analytical, Empirical, and Behavioral Perspectives

QI SHANG: General Equilibrium Analysis of Portfolio Benchmarking

Foundations of Asset Pricing

Market Survival in the Economies with Heterogeneous Beliefs

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

WITH SKETCH ANSWERS. Postgraduate Certificate in Finance Postgraduate Certificate in Economics and Finance

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Financial Decisions and Markets: A Course in Asset Pricing. John Y. Campbell. Princeton University Press Princeton and Oxford

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 7

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Low Risk Anomalies? Discussion

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Lecture 5 Theory of Finance 1

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Online Appendix: Extensions

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

Equilibrium Asset Returns

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Topic 1: Basic Concepts in Finance. Slides

THE UNIVERSITY OF NEW SOUTH WALES

Methods Examination (Macro Part) Spring Please answer all the four questions below. The exam has 100 points.

Lecture 12. Asset pricing model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: June 15, 2017

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007

Continuous time Asset Pricing

STOCHASTIC CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL: CANONICAL APPLICATIONS FEBRUARY 19, 2013

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 6a

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

A simple wealth model

UPDATED IAA EDUCATION SYLLABUS

A dynamic model with nominal rigidities.

Generalizing to multi-period setting. Forward, Futures and Swaps. Multiple factor pricing models Market efficiency

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

Optimal Option Pricing via Esscher Transforms with the Meixner Process

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Unobserved Heterogeneity Revisited

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Numerical Evaluation of Multivariate Contingent Claims

CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL JANUARY 19, 2018

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

The stochastic discount factor and the CAPM

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

LECTURE 07: MULTI-PERIOD MODEL

1 Introduction The two most important static models of security markets the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), and the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT)

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Lecture notes on risk management, public policy, and the financial system Credit risk models

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

EIEF, Graduate Program Theoretical Asset Pricing

MFE Course Details. Financial Mathematics & Statistics

MFE Course Details. Financial Mathematics & Statistics

ADVANCED ASSET PRICING THEORY

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

INTRODUCTION TO THE ECONOMICS AND MATHEMATICS OF FINANCIAL MARKETS. Jakša Cvitanić and Fernando Zapatero

SDF based asset pricing

Hedge Portfolios, the No Arbitrage Condition & Arbitrage Pricing Theory

Characterization of the Optimum

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Implementing Models in Quantitative Finance: Methods and Cases

Fin 501: Asset Pricing Fin 501:

Entropic Derivative Security Valuation

Notes on Syllabus Section VI: TIME AND UNCERTAINTY, FUTURES MARKETS

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Problem Set (1 p) (1) 1 (100)

THE UNIVERSITY OF NEW SOUTH WALES SCHOOL OF BANKING AND FINANCE

Lecture Notes: November 29, 2012 TIME AND UNCERTAINTY: FUTURES MARKETS

PhD Qualifier Examination

Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and

Transcription:

Econometric specifications University of Pavia March 2, 2007

Outline 1 Introduction 2 3 of Excess Returns

DAPM is refutable empirically if it restricts the joint distribution of the observable asset prices or returns under study.

s The goal is to price a given cash-flow stream based on agent s optimal consumption and investment decisions then a fully articulated specification of agents preferences, technologies and other constraints. If the concern is to derive prices as discounted cash flows, subject only to the constraint that there are no arbitrage opportunities in the economy, then it may be sufficient to specify how the relevant discount factors depend on the underlying risk factors affecting security prices, along with the joint distribution of these factors. Testing the restrictions implied by a particular equilibrium condition arising out of an agent s consumption/investment decision.

s The goal is to price a given cash-flow stream based on agent s optimal consumption and investment decisions then a fully articulated specification of agents preferences, technologies and other constraints. If the concern is to derive prices as discounted cash flows, subject only to the constraint that there are no arbitrage opportunities in the economy, then it may be sufficient to specify how the relevant discount factors depend on the underlying risk factors affecting security prices, along with the joint distribution of these factors. Testing the restrictions implied by a particular equilibrium condition arising out of an agent s consumption/investment decision.

s The goal is to price a given cash-flow stream based on agent s optimal consumption and investment decisions then a fully articulated specification of agents preferences, technologies and other constraints. If the concern is to derive prices as discounted cash flows, subject only to the constraint that there are no arbitrage opportunities in the economy, then it may be sufficient to specify how the relevant discount factors depend on the underlying risk factors affecting security prices, along with the joint distribution of these factors. Testing the restrictions implied by a particular equilibrium condition arising out of an agent s consumption/investment decision.

P s set of payoffs Payoffs at date s > t are to be priced at date t, for s > t by an economic model. Pricing function π t : P s R DAPM mantains the assumption of no arbitrage opportunities q t+1 P t+1 Pr {q t+1 0} = 0 Pr ({π t (q t+1 0)} {q t+1 > 0}) = 0

Non-negative payoffs at t + 1 that are positive with positive probability have positive prices at date t. The absence of arbitrage opportunities on a set of payoffs P s is essentially equivalent to the existence of a special payoff, a pricing kernel q s Pr(q s > 0) = 1 and represents the pricing function π t as π t (q s ) = E[q s q t I t ] q s P s when the uncertainty is generated by discrete random variables.

Overidentifying restrictions are obtained by restricting the functional form of q s or the joint distribution of the pricing environment (P s, q s, I t ).

Classification of DAPM Classification of DAPM according to the types of restrictions they impose on the distributions of the elements of (P s, q s, I t ): Arbitrage-free pricing models Beta representations of excess portfolio returns Linear asset pricing relations.

Classification of DAPM Classification of DAPM according to the types of restrictions they impose on the distributions of the elements of (P s, q s, I t ): Arbitrage-free pricing models Beta representations of excess portfolio returns Linear asset pricing relations.

Classification of DAPM Classification of DAPM according to the types of restrictions they impose on the distributions of the elements of (P s, q s, I t ): Arbitrage-free pricing models Beta representations of excess portfolio returns Linear asset pricing relations.

Classification of DAPM Classification of DAPM according to the types of restrictions they impose on the distributions of the elements of (P s, q s, I t ): Arbitrage-free pricing models Beta representations of excess portfolio returns Linear asset pricing relations.

The preference-based models parameterize agent s intertemporal consumption and investment decision problem. The economy is supposed to be comprised of a finite number of infinitely lived agents with identical endowments, information, and preferences in an uncertain environment. A t agent s information set at time t The agent ranks consumption sequences using a von Neumann-Morgestern utility functional [ ] E β t U(c t ) A 0 t=0 the preferences are assumed to be time separable with period utility function U and the subjective discount factor β (0, 1).

If the representative agent can trade the assets with payoffs P s and their asset holdings are interior to the set of admissible portfolios, the prices of these payoffs in equilibrium are given by where π t (q s ) = E[m s t s q s A t ] m s t s = β U (c s ) U (c t ) is the intertemporal marginal rate of substitution of consumption between t and s. For a given utility parameterization a preference-based DAPM allows the association of the pricing kernel q s with m s t s.

To determine the prices π t (q s ) requires a parametric assumption about the agent s utility function U(c t ) and sufficient economic structure to determine the joint, conditional distribution of ms s t and q s. Prices are part of the determination of an equilibrium in goods and securities markets. The modeler must specify a variety of features of an economy outside of securities markets in order to undertake preference-based pricing. Data limitations: some of the theoretical constructs appearing in utility functions or budget constraints do not have readily available, observable counterparts.

For these reasons the preference-based DAPM have attempted to evaluate whether, for a particular choice of utility function U(c t ) the pricing function π t (q s ) does in fact price the payoffs in P s. Given observations on a candidate ms s t and data on asset returns The condition R s {q s P s : π t (q s ) = 1} π t (q s ) = E[m s t s q s A t ] implies testable restrictions on the joint distribution of R s, π t (q s ) and elements of A t.

For each s-period return r s E[m s t s r s 1 A t ] = 0 r s R s An immediate implication of this moment restriction is that E[(m s t s r s 1)x t ] = 0 x t A t These unconditional moment restrictions can be used to construct method-of-moments estimators of the parameters governing ms s t and to test whether or not ms s t prices the securities with payoffs in P s. There will be no arbitrage opportunities in equilibrium.

Alternative pricing based on the presumption that asset prices are such that no arbitrage opportunities can arise. No equilibrium behavior is needed to determine asset prices. No arbitrage principle used by Black and Scholes (1973), Merton (1973), Ross (1978), Harrison and Kreps (1979). Under weak regularity conditions pricing can proceed as if agents are risk neutral. Continuous-time, trade of default-free bond that matures an instant in the future and pays the (continuously compounded) rate of return r t, discounting for risk-neutral pricing is done by the default-free roll-over return e ( R s t rudu)

If uncertainty about future prices and yields is generated by a continuous-time Markov process Y t (so the conditioning information set I t is generated by Y t ), then the price of the payoff q s is given equivalently by π t (q s ) = E[q s q s Y t ] = E Q [e R s t rudu q s Y t ] E Q is the expectation with regard to the risk-neutral conditional distribution of Y. The risk attitudes of investors are implicit in the exogenous specification of q as a function of the state Y t and hence in the change of probability measure under the risk-neutral representation.

The direct parameterization of the distribution of q facilitates the computation of security prices. The parameterization of (P s, q, Y t ) is chosen so that the expectation can be solved either analytically or numerically for This is facilitated by π t (q s ) = P(Y t ) the adoption of continuous time (continuous trading) special structure on the conditional distribution of Y constraints on the dependence of q on Y so that the expectation E Q is easily computed.

The knowledge of the risk-neutral distribution of Y t is sufficient for pricing, but this knowledge is typically not sufficient for econometric estimation. For the purpose of estimation using historical price or return information associated with the payoffs P s, we also need information about the distribution of Y under its DGP. The difference between actual and risk-neutral distributions of Y are adjustments for the market price of risk. If the conditional distribution of Y t Y t 1 is known (derivable form the continuous-time specification of Y ) then so is the conditional distribution of the observed market prices π t (q s ).

The completeness of the specification of the pricing relations (the distribution of Y and the functional form of P(Y t )) in this case implies that one can use ML to estimate the unknown parameters. This is possible using market price alone even though the risk factors Y may be latent. Key to this strategy is the presumption that the burden of computing π t (q s ) = P(Y t ) is low. For many specifications of the distribution of the state Y t, the pricing relation P(Y t ) must be determined by numerical methods.

The computational burden of solving for P(Y t ) while simultaneously estimating the parameters can be formidable, especially as the dimension of Y gets large. Alternative methods: GMM estimation Simulated ML estimation.

of Excess Returns CAPM static model: expected returns in terms of a security s beta with a benchmark portfolio. The key insights of the CAPM carry over to richer stochastic environments in which agents optimize over multiple periods. Intertemporal CAPM: s = t + 1, benchmark return from the pricing condition r t+1 = q t+1 π t (q t+1 ) π t (q t+1 ) = E[q t+1 q t+1 I t ] = E[q t+1 r t+1π t (q t+1) I t ]

of Excess Returns 1 π t (q t+1 ) = E[r t+1r t+1 I t ] π t (q t+1) = E[q 2 t+1 I t ] For all r t+1 R t+1 E[q 2 t+1 I t ] 1 = E[r t+1 r t+1 I t ] since r is one such term the benchmark return satisfies E[q 2 t+1 I t ] 1 = E[r 2 t+1 I t ] E[r t+1(r t+1 r t+1) I t ] = 0 r t+1 R t+1

of Excess Returns Several implications for the role of rt+1. One is that r t+1 is a benchmark return for a single-beta representation of excess returns ) E[r j,t+1 I t ] rt f = β jt (E[r t+1 I t ] rt f where β jt = E[r j,t+1, r t+1 I t] Var[r t+1 I t] and rt f is the interest rate on one-period riskless loans issued at date t.

of Excess Returns It turns out that the beta representation, together with r f t = 1 E[q t+1 I t] constitute exactly the same information as the basic pricing relation.

Much econometric analysis of DAPMs has focused on linear pricing relations. An important example of a linear DAPM is the version of the ICAPM obtained by assuming that β jt = β j Under this additional assumption, β j is the familiar β, where the CAPM is extended to allow both expected returns on stocks and the riskless interest rate to change over time. The mean of u j,t+1 (r j,t+1 r f t ) β j (r β t+1 r f t ) for all admissible r j. E[u j,t+1 I t ] = 0

The moment conditions: E[u j,t+1 x t ] = 0, x t I t can be used to construct estimators of the β j and tests of ICAPM.