Ross Recovery with Recurrent and Transient Processes

Similar documents
Sensitivity Analysis on Long-term Cash flows

Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Ross Recovery theorem and its extension

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Introduction to Affine Processes. Applications to Mathematical Finance

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 2014

Risk Neutral Measures

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

13.3 A Stochastic Production Planning Model

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

American Foreign Exchange Options and some Continuity Estimates of the Optimal Exercise Boundary with respect to Volatility

Interest rate models in continuous time

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

On the pricing equations in local / stochastic volatility models

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Weak Reflection Principle and Static Hedging of Barrier Options

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

Hedging under Arbitrage

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria web: July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Stochastic Volatility

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

Steven Heston: Recovering the Variance Premium. Discussion by Jaroslav Borovička November 2017

Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard

Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Numerical schemes for SDEs

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers

Prospect Theory, Partial Liquidation and the Disposition Effect

1 The continuous time limit

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

Sample Path Large Deviations and Optimal Importance Sampling for Stochastic Volatility Models

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

Drawdowns Preceding Rallies in the Brownian Motion Model

Barrier Options Pricing in Uncertain Financial Market

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

A discretionary stopping problem with applications to the optimal timing of investment decisions.

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

Enlargement of filtration

Generalized Recovery

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Path Dependent British Options

Logarithmic derivatives of densities for jump processes

L 2 -theoretical study of the relation between the LIBOR market model and the HJM model Takashi Yasuoka

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Barrier Option Pricing Formulae for Uncertain Currency Model

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

PDE Methods for the Maximum Drawdown

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

On Using Shadow Prices in Portfolio optimization with Transaction Costs

Law of the Minimal Price

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Advanced topics in continuous time finance

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

On the White Noise of the Price of Stocks related to the Option Prices from the Black-Scholes Equation

MARGIN CALL STOCK LOANS

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

SHORT-TERM RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN VOLATILITY-STABILIZED MARKETS

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model

Conditional Full Support and No Arbitrage

A Note on the No Arbitrage Condition for International Financial Markets

Transcription:

Ross Recovery with Recurrent and Transient Processes Hyungbin Park Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences, New York University, New York, NY, USA arxiv:4.2282v5 [q-fin.mf] 7 Oct 25 23 September 25 Abstract Recently, Ross [2] argued that it is possible to recover an objective measure from a riskneutral measure. His model assumes that there is a finite-state Markov process X t that drives the economy in discrete time t N. Many authors extended his model to a continuous-time setting with a Markov diffusion process X t with state space R. Unfortunately, the continuoustime model fails to recover an objective measure from a risk-neutral measure in general. We determine under which information recovery is possible in the continuous-time model. It was proven that if X t is recurrent under the objective measure, then recovery is possible. In this article, when X t is transient under the objective measure, we investigate what information is sufficient to recover. Keywords: Ross recovery, Markovian pricing operators, recurrence, transience Introduction Quantitative finance theory involves two related probability measures: a risk-neutral measure and an objective measure. The risk-neutral measure determines the prices of assets and options in a financial market. The risk-neutral measure is distinct from the objective measure, which describes the actual stochastic dynamics of markets. The conventional belief is that one cannot determine an objective measure by observing a risk-neutral measure. The best known example capturing this belief is the Black-Scholes model, which says that the drift of a stock under a risk-neutral measure is independent of the drift of the stock under an objective measure. Recently, Ross [2] questioned this belief and argued that it is possible to recover an objective measure from a risk-neutral measure under some circumstances. His model assumes that there is an underlying process X t that drives the entire economy with a finite number of states on discrete time t N. This result can be of great interest to finance researchers and investors, and thus it The author is grateful to Jonathan Goodman and Srinivasa Varadhan for technical insights. The author also appreciates two unknown referees for their constructive feedback. First version: 9 September 24 hyungbin@cims.nyu.edu, hyungbin25@gmail.com

is highly valuable to extend the Ross model to a continuous-time setting, which is practical and useful in finance. In this paper, we investigate the possibility of recovering in a continuous-time setting t R with a time-homogeneous Markov diffusion process X t with state space R. In this setting, the risk-neutral measure contains some information about an objective measure. In general, however, the model unfortunately fails to recover an objective measure from a risk-neutral measure. A key idea of recovery theory is that the reciprocal of the pricing kernel is expressed in the form e βt φx t ) for some constant β and positive function φ ). For example, in the consumption-based capital asset model in [4] and [3], the pricing kernel is expressed in the above form. The basis of recovery theory is finding β and φ ). Thus, we obtain the pricing kernel and the relationship between the objective measure and the risk-neutral measure. We will see that β and φ ) satisfy the second-order differential equation 2 σ2 x)φ x) + kx)φ x) rx)φx) = β φx)..) Thus, recovery theory is transformed into a problem of finding a particular solution pair β, φ) of this particular differential equation with φ ) >. If such a solution pair were unique, then we could successfully recover the objective measure. Unfortunately, this approach categorically fails to achieve recovery because such a solution pair is never unique. Many authors have extended the Ross model to a continuous-time setting and have also confronted the non-uniqueness problem. To overcome the non-uniqueness problem, all authors assumed more conditions onto their models so that the differential equation.) has a unique solution pair satisfying the conditions. Carr and Yu [5] introduced the notion of Long s discovery of the numeraire portfolio to extend the Ross model to a continuous-time setting. They assumed Long s portfolio depends on time t and the underlying process X t, and then they derived the above differential equation.). Carr and Yu also assumed that the process X t is a time-homogeneous Markov diffusion on a bounded interval with regular boundaries at both endpoints. They also implicitly assumed that φ ) is in L 2 w) for some measure w to apply the regular Sturm-Liouville theory, thereby obtaining a unique solution pair satisfying these conditions. Dubynskiy and Goldstein [7] explored Markov diffusion models with reflecting boundary conditions. Walden [2] extended the results of Carr and Yu to the case that X t is an unbounded process. Walden proved that recovery is possible if the process X t is recurrent under the objective measure. In addition, he showed that when recovery is possible in the unbounded case, approximate recovery is possible from observing option prices on a bounded subinterval. Qin and Linetsky [7] proved that recovery is possible if X t is recurrent and the pricing kernel admits a Hansen-Scheinkman decomposition. They also showed that the Ross recovery has a close connection with Roger s potential approach to the pricing kernel. Borovicka, Hansen and Scheinkman [2] showed that the recovery is possible if the process X t is stochastically stable under the objective measure. They also discussed applications of the recovery theory to finance and economics. The papers of Borovicka, Hansen and Scheinkman [2], Qin and Linetsky [7] and Walden [2] assumed a common condition on X t. Specifically, X t is recurrent under the objective measure. The mathematical rationale for this condition is to overcome the non-uniqueness problem of the differential equation.). Indeed, if existent, there is a unique solution pair β, φ) of the equation.) satisfying this condition and we will review this condition in Section 5.. 2

In this article, we investigate the possibility of recovery when the process X t is transient under the objective measure. We explore in this case what information is sufficient to recover. One of the main contributions is that if β is known and if X t is non-attracted to the left or right) boundary under the objective measure, then recovery is possible. To achieve this, we establish a graphical understanding of recovery theory. This topic is discussed in Section 4 and 5. In Section 6, two examples of recovery theory are explored: the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross CIR) interest rate model and the Black-Scholes stock model. Section 7 summarizes this article. 2 Markovian pricing operators A financial market is defined as a probability space Ω, F, P) having a one-dimensional Brownian motion B t with the filtration F = F t ) t= generated by B t. All the processes in this article are assumed to be adapted to the filtration F. P is the objective measure of this market. We assume that there are a state variable X t and a positive numeraire G t in the market. Let Q be an equivalent measure on the market Ω, F, P) such that each risky asset discounted by the numeraire G t is a martingale under measure Q. It is customary that this measure Q is referred to as a risk-neutral measure when G t is a money market account. In this article, however, for any given positive numeraire G t, we say Q is a risk-neutral measure with respect to G t. Set the Radon- Nikodym derivative by Σ t = dq dp Ft, which is known to be a martingale process on Ω, F, P) for < t < T. Using the martingale representation theorem, we can write in the stochastic differential equation form dσ t = ρ t Σ t db t for some ρ t. It is well-known that W t defined by dw t := ρ t dt + db t 2.) is a Brownian motion under Q. We define the reciprocal of the pricing kernel by L t = G t /Σ t. Assumption. The state variable X t is a time-homogeneous Markov diffusion process satisfying dx t = bx t ) dt + σx t ) dw t, X = ξ. The range of X t is an open interval I = c, d) with c < d. b ) and σ ) are continuously differentiable on I and that σx) > for x c, d). It is implicitly assumed that both endpoints are unattainable because the range of the process is an open interval. Assumption 2. The dynamics of the numeraire G t is determined by X t. More precisely, G t follows dg t G t = rx t ) + v 2 X t )) dt + vx t ) dw t, G =. Assume that r and v are continuously differentiable on I and exp t t ) v 2 X s ) ds vx s ) dw s 2 is a martingale. We assume that we can extract theses four functions b ), σ ), r ) and v ) from market prices data, thus they are assumed to be known ex ante. The above martingale assumption is to define a new measure by using the Girsanov theorem, for example, in the proof of Theorem E.. It is noteworthy that if there is a money market account with interest rate, denoted by r t, in the market, then r t is equal to rx t ) because e t rs ds G t is a martingale under Q. 3

Assumption 3. Assume that the reciprocal of) the pricing kernel L t is transition independent in the sense that there are a positive function φ C 2 I) and a real number β such that In this case, we say β, φ) is a principal pair of the market. L t = e βt φx t ) φ ξ). 2.2) The basis of recovery theory is finding the principal pair β, φ) and then obtaining the objective measure P by setting the Radon-Nikodym derivative dp dq = Σ t = e βt φx t ) φ ξ) G t. Ft One important aspect in implementing the recovery approach is to decide how to choose state variables X t. Many processes can serve as a state variable and the choice of a state variable depends on the purpose of use. One way is the short interest rate r t. Investors interested in the price of bonds want to find the dynamics of r t under an objective measure. Plenty of examples with interest rate state variables can be found in [8]. Another way is a stock market index process such as the Dow Jones Industrial Average and Standard & Poor s S&P) 5. Refer to [] for an empirical analysis of recovery theory with the state variable S&P 5. 3 Transformed measures We investigate how recovery theory is transformed into a problem of a differential equation. Applying the Ito formula to the definition of L t, we know dl t = rx t ) + v 2 X t ) + vx t )ρ t ) L t dt + vx t ) + ρ t )L t dw t. From 2.2), we also have dl t = β + ) 2 σ2 φ φ )X t ) + bφ φ )X t ) L t dt + σφ φ )X t ) L t dw t. By comparing these two equations, we obtain 2 σ2 φ + b vσ)φ rφ = β φ, ρ t = σφ φ v)x t ). 3.) For convenience, set kx) := b vσ)x). Using notation L defined by Lφx) = 2 σ2 x)φ x) + kx)φ x) rx)φx), we have the following theorem. Theorem 3.. Let β, φ) be the principal pair of the market. Then β, φ) satisfies Lφ = βφ. In other words, if λ, h) is a solution pair of Lh = λh with h >, then λ, h) is a candidate pair for the principal pair of X t. We are interested in a solution pair λ, h) of Lh = λh with positive function h. There are two possibilities. i) there is no positive solution h for any λ R, or 4

ii) there exists a number β such that it has two linearly independent positive solutions for λ < β, has no positive solution for λ > β and has one or two linearly independent solutions for λ = β. Refer to page 46 and 49 in [6]. Assumption 3. It is easily checked that In this article, we implicitly assumed the second case by e λt hx t ) h ξ) G t is a local martingale under Q. When this is a martingale, one can attempt to recover the objective measure P by setting this as a Radon-Nikodym derivative. Definition. Let λ, h) be a solution pair of Lh = λh with positive function h. Suppose that e λt hx t ) h ξ) G t is a martingale. A measure obtained from the risk-neutral measure Q by the Radon-Nikodym derivative d dq = e λt hx t ) h ξ) G t Ft is called the transformed measure with respect to the pair λ, h). Clearly, the transformed measure with respect to the principal pair is the objective measure P. We have the following proposition by 2.) and 3.). Proposition 3.2. A process B h t defined by db h t = σh h v)x t ) dt + dw t is a Brownian motion under the transformed measure with respect to λ, h). Furthermore, X t follows dx t = b vσ + h h )X t ) dt + σx t ) db h t = k + h h )X t ) dt + σx t ) db h t. 3.2) Occasionally, we use the notation B t instead of Bt h without ambiguity. Even when e λt hx t ) h ξ) G t is not a martingale, we can consider the diffusion process corresponding to 3.2). Definition 2. The diffusion process X t defined by is called the diffusion process induced by λ, h). dx t = k + h h )X t ) dt + σx t ) db t 4 Recurrence and transience 4. Mathematical preliminaries We establish the mathematical preliminaries for recurrent and transient processes. The contents of this section are indebted to [8], [2] and [4]. Consider the diffusion process induced by λ, h) : dx t = µx t ) dt + σx t ) db t, X = ξ, where µ ) = k + h h ) ). A measure S defined by dsx) := e x ξ 2µy) dy y) dx = h2 ξ) x h 2 x) e ξ 2ky) y) dy dx is called the scale measure of the process with respect to the pair λ, h). 5

Definition 3. The left boundary c is attracting if Sc, ξ]) < and non-attracting otherwise. Similarly, we say the right boundary d is attracting if S[ξ, d)) < and non-attracting otherwise. Define a stopping time τ by the following way. Let c n ) n=, d n ) n= be strictly monotone sequences with limits c and d, respectively. Set τ n := inf { t > X t / c n, d n ) } and τ := lim n τ n. Proposition 4.. The left boundary c is non-attracting if and only if ) Prob lim X t = c =. t τ It is similar to the right boundary d. Proposition 4.2. X t is recurrent if and only if both boundary points c and d are non-attracting. 4.2 Graphical understanding We establish a graphical understanding of recovery theory. Recall that X = ξ in Assumption. The purpose of this section is to understand the graphs shown in Figure and 2. A solution h of a second-order differential equation is uniquely determined by the initial value and the initial velocity. By normalizing, we may assume hξ) = such that a solution is determined by h ξ). In this section, we describe the relationship between h ξ) and the recovery of X t with respect to h. Occasionally, we use the terminology without ambiguity: the transformed measure with respect to tuple λ, h ξ)) means the transformed measure with respect to pair λ, h). The two terms tuple and pair will be used to distinguish between these meanings. Definition 4. We say λ, h ξ)) R 2 is a candidate tuple or we say λ, h) is a candidate pair if λ, h) is a solution pair of Lh = λh with h ) > and hξ) =. Denote the set of the candidate tuples by C. C := { λ, h ξ)) R 2 Lh = λh, h >, hξ) = }. We investigate graphical properties of C. Let β be the maximum value of the first coordinate of elements of C, that is, β := max{ λ λ, z) C }. The maximum β is achieved as we discussed in Section 3. For any λ with λ β, we set M λ := sup z, m λ := inf z. λ,z) C λ,z) C Proposition 4.3. Let λ β. For any z with m λ z M λ, the tuple λ, z) is in C. Therefore, the supremum and infimum are, in fact, the maximum and minimum, respectively. Furthermore, the λ-slide of C is a connected and compact set. See Appendix A for proof. Theorem 4.4. The diffusion process induced by tuple λ, M λ ) is non-attracted to the left boundary. For z with m λ z < M λ, the diffusion process induced by tuple λ, z), is attracted to the left boundary. Similarly, the diffusion process induced by tuple λ, m λ ) is non-attracted to the right boundary. For z with m λ < z M λ, the diffusion process induced by tuple λ, z) is attracted to the right boundary. Therefore, for z with m λ < z < M λ, the diffusion process induced by tuple λ, z) is attracted to both boundaries. For proof, see Appendix B. 6

Proposition 4.5. M λ is a strictly decreasing function of λ and m λ is a strictly increasing function of λ for λ β. See Appendix C for proof. Corollary 4.6. For β, there are two possibilities: i) there is a unique number z such that β, z) is in C. In this case, the tuple β, z) is the unique tuple in C such that the induced diffusion process is recurrent. ii) there is an infinite number of z s such that β, z) is in C. In this case, for any such tuple β, z) in C, the induced diffusion process X t is transient. Refer to Section 6 for examples of i) and also see Appendix F for an example of ii). In Figure, the left graph is the case of i) and the right graph is the case of ii). Figure : Candidate sets We now explore a particular subset of C. In general, for a candidate pair λ, h), e λt hx t ) G t is a local martingale. We are interested in pairs that induce martingales. Definition 5. Let λ, h) be a candidate pair. We say λ, h ξ)) is an admissible tuple or we say λ, h) is an admissible pair if e λt hx t ) G t is a martingale. Denote the set of the admissible tuples by A. A := { λ, h ξ)) R 2 λ, h) is a candidate pair and e λt hx t ) G t is a martingale }. One of the main purposes of this section is to investigate the graphical properties of A with the notion of recurrence and transience. It is noteworthy that C and A depend on ξ. Proposition 4.7. Let λ β and let m λ < z < M λ. If two tuples λ, m λ ) and λ, M λ ) are in A, then λ, z) is in A. If at least one of λ, m λ ) and λ, M λ ) is not in A, then λ, z) is not in A. See Appendix D for proof. Proposition 4.8. Let δ < λ β. If δ, M δ ) is in A, then λ, M λ ) is also in A. Similarly, if δ, m δ ) is in A, then λ, m λ ) is also in A. 7

Refer to Appendix E for proof. Proposition 4.9. Consider the case of i) in Corollary 4.6. For β, suppose that there is a unique number z such that β, z) is in C. Then β, z) is in A. For proof, see [6]. Figure 2 displays two examples of admissible set and summarizes this section. Figure 2: Admissible sets 5 Recurrent and transient recovery 5. Recurrent recovery We review recovery theory with the assumption that X t is recurrent under the objective measure. With this assumption, we can successfully recover the objective measure from the risk-neutral measure. This theory is especially useful when the state variable X t is an interest rate process because the actual dynamics of an interest rate is usually recurrent or mean-reverting in the actual real-world measure. Proposition 5.. If it exists, there is a unique admissible pair β, φ) of Lφ = β φ with φ > such that X t is recurrent under the transformed measure with respect to the pair β, φ). In this case, we have β = max{ λ λ, z) A }. This proposition is easily obtained from Section 4.2 and gives the following theorem. Theorem 5.2. Recurrent recovery) Suppose X t is recurrent under the objective measure P. We can then recover the objective measure P from the risk-neutral measure Q. 5.2 Transient recovery We encounter several conditions under which we can recover the objective measure when X t is transient under the objective measure. The state variable X t is always transient under the transformed measure with respect to an admissible pair λ, h) for any λ < β. Therefore, without further information, recovery is impossible when the process X t is transient under the objective measure. 8

We assume that we know the value β. Despite knowing this value β, we cannot achieve recovery in general. However, the following theorem says that recovery is possible under some circumstances. The proof is direct from Proposition 4.7. Theorem 5.3. Transient recovery) Suppose we know the value β. If only one of β, m β ) and β, M β ) is an admissible tuple, then we can recover the objective measure P from the risk-neutral measure Q. When both of β, m β ) and β, M β ) are admissible tuples, we cannot uniquely determine the objective measure P because there is an infinite number of admissible pairs. We investigate another way for recovery. We will see that there is only one way to recover the objective measure such that X t is non-attracted to the left or right) boundary. Proposition 5.4. For any fixed λ with λ β, if it exists, there is a unique admissible pair λ, h) such that X t is non-attracted to the left boundary under the corresponding transformed measure. In this case, h ξ) = M λ. Similarly, if it exists, there is a unique admissible pair λ, h) such that X t is non-attracted to the right boundary under the corresponding transformed measure. In this case, h ξ) = m λ. This proposition is easily obtained from Section 4.2 and gives the following theorem. Theorem 5.5. Transient recovery) Suppose we know the value β. If X t is non-attracted to the left or right) boundary under the objective measure P, then we can recover the objective measure P from the risk-neutral measure Q. If X t is attracted to both boundaries under the objective measure P, then both β, m β ) and β, M β ) are admissible tuples. Thus there is an infinite number of admissible tuples such that X t is attracted to both boundaries under the corresponding transformed measure. We now shift our attention to the choice of β. When X t is non-attracted to the left right) boundary, to recover the objective measure, we confront a problem of determining the value β. How can we choose the value? One way is to use the long-term yield of bonds, which is defined by See [5] and [8] as a reference. 6 Applications 6. Interest rates lim t t log EQ [ G t We investigate the recovery theorem when the state variable X t is an interest rate process r t and the numeraire is the money market account: ] ). X t = r t, G t = e t rs ds. Assume that r t follows dr t = kr t ) dt + σr t ) dw t. Then 2 σ2 r)h r) + kr)h r) rhr) = λh. is the corresponding second-order differential equation. 9

Example 6.. We explore the CIR model: with the Feller condition 2aθ. Consider dr t = aθ r t ) dt + σ r t dw t 2 σ2 rh r) + aθ r)h r) rhr) = λh with hr ) =. Set k := a 2 +2 a. It can be shown that the maximum value β is equal to kaθ. For any fixed λ with λ kaθ, denote the functions corresponding to tuples λ, M λ ) and λ, m λ ) by h λ ) and g λ ), respectively. Then we have h λ x) = ψ λ x)/ψ λ r ) where ψ λ x) := e kx λ kaθ K a2 + 2σ, 2aθ 2 σ, 2x ) a2 + 2. 2 Here, K,, ) is the Kummer confluent hypergeometric function. Refer to [7] for more details about g λ. It can be shown that λ, M λ ) is an admissible tuple, but λ, m λ ) is not. Thus, the admissible set A is described by A = { λ, h λr )) R 2 λ kaθ }. See [7] for more details. Interest rates are usually recurrent in the real world; therefore, we assume that r t is recurrent under the objective measure. kaθ, e kr r) ) is the only admissible pair that induces the recurrent X t under the corresponding transformed measure and under which the X t is expressed by dr t = ) aθ a 2 + 2 a2 + 2σ r 2 t dt + σ r t db t. 6.2 Stock prices We investigate the recovery theorem when the state variable X t is a stock price S t and the dividends of the stock are paid out continuously with rate δs t ) dt. Here δ ) is a deterministic function and the case of δ ) = is not excluded. Let the numeraire G t be the wealth process defined by Assume that the dynamics of S t is given by G t = S t e t δsu) du. ds t = rs t ) δs t ) + S t ))S t dt + σs t )S t dw t. Then it follows that dg t = rs t ) + S t )) dt + σs t ) dw t. G t The corresponding second-order differential equation is 2 σ2 s)s 2 h s) + rs) δs))sh s) rs)hs) = λhs). It is noteworthy that that if there is a money market account with a constant interest rate r in the market, then rs t ) = r.

Example 6.2. Assume that the state variable is a stock price S t and the dividends of the stock are paid out continuously with rate δ dt. Suppose S t follows a geometric Brownian motion and the numeraire is G t = S t e δt. Consider ds t = r δ + )S t dt + σs t dw t, S = 2 σ2 s 2 h s) + r δ)sh s) rhs) = λhs). We want to find the candidate set and the admissible set. For λ < 2 are given by hs) = c s l + c) s l 2 for c where l = 2 r δ 2 r δ ) 2 + l 2 = 2 r δ + 2 r δ ) 2 + σ ) r δ 2 2 σ +r, these solutions 2r λ), 2r λ), thus we have m λ = l, M λ = l 2. For λ = σ ) r δ 2 2 2 σ + r, the only positive solution h with h) = is hx) = x 2 r δ and m λ = M λ = r δ. For λ > σ ) r δ 2 2 2 2 σ +r, there are no positive solutions. Thus, the candidate set is obtained. It can be easily shown that the admissible set is equal to the candidate set. If S t is recurrent under the objective measure, then the transformed measure with respect to tuple σ ) ) r δ 2 2 2 σ + r, r δ is the objective measure. We used Theorem 5.2. Under this 2 measure, S t follows ds t = 2 σ2 S t dt + σs t db t. We now assume that S t is non-attracted to and the value β 2 Then, by Theorem 5.5, the transformed measure with respect to tuple β, M β ) = β, 2 r δ + 2 r δ ) 2 + σ ) ) r δ 2 2 σ + r is known. 2r β) is the objective measure, under which S t follows σ ) ds t = σ2 2 + 2 2 r δ) + 2σ 2 2 r β) S t dt + σs t db t. As a particular case, if β is equal to the long-term yield of bonds t log [ ] ) EQ G t = r, lim t then S t follows ) σ 2 ds t = 2 + r δ σ2 2 S t dt + σs t db t

under the objective measure. The numeraire G t satisfies dg t = µg t dt + σg t db t with µ := σ2 2 + δ + r δ σ2 2. Thus, the Sharpe ratio of G t is µ r σ σ + = 2δ r) σ if r < δ + σ2 2 if r δ + σ2 2. 7 Conclusion This article extended the Ross model to a continuous-time setting model. In a continuous-time setting, the risk-neutral measure contains some information about the objective measure. Unfortunately, the model fails to recover an objective measure from a risk-neutral measure. We discussed several conditions under which the recovery of the objective measure from the risk-neutral measure is possible in a continuous-time model. When the state variable X t is recurrent under the objective measure, recovery is possible. We also determined the type of information that is sufficient for recovery when X t is transient. It was shown that when X t is transient, recovery is possible if the value β is known and only one of β, m β ) and β, M β ) is an admissible tuple. We can also recover the objective measure if the value β is known and X t is non-attracted to the left or right) boundary. The following extensions for future research are suggested. First, it would be interesting to find sufficient conditions under which recovery is possible when X t is attracted to both boundaries. We could not offer such conditions in this article. Second, it would be valuable to find financially and economically reasonable ways to determine β. Finally, much work remains to be conducted on the implementation and empirical testing of recovery theory in future research. A Proof of Proposition 4.3 Proposition A.. A solution h of Lh = λh can be expressed by h = uq, where qx) = e x ky) dy y) and u is a solution of u x) + d ) kx) dx x) ) k2 x) 2 rx) + λ) + ux) =. σ 4 x) x) This can be shown by direct calculation. For more details, refer to [2], page 36. We now prove Proposition 4.3. Proof. For convenience, we may assume that ξ =, the left boundary is and the right boundary is. Let h be a positive solution of Lh = λh with h) =. Another solution, which is independent of h, is x hx) y h 2 y) e 2 2kz) z) dz dy.

It can be obtained by direct calculation). Let S be the scale measure with respect to the pair λ, h), then x y 2kz) hx) h 2 y) e dz z) dy = hx) S[, x)). The general solutions of Lh = λh are expressed by hx) c + c 2 S[, x))). Assume that at least one of S, ]) and S[, )) is finite. Otherwise, h is the unique positive solution of Lh = λh, so m β = z = M β, in which case we have nothing to prove). We may assume S, ]) <. Set B := S, ]). The general normalized to h c ) = ) solution is expressed by h c x) := hx) c) + c ) B S, x]), which is a positive function for and only for c if S[, )) = B D c if D := S[, )) < Using h c) = h ) + c, we have that B M λ = h ) + B, m λ = h ) if S[, )) = M λ = h ) + B, m λ = h ) D if D = S[, )) < Furthermore, h c) can be any value in [m λ, M λ ]. Hence, for any z with m λ z M λ, the tuple λ, z) is in A. This completes the proof. B Proof of Theorem 4.4 Proof. For convenience, we may assume that ξ =, the left boundary is and the right boundary is. Suppose that the diffusion process induced by tuple λ, M λ ) is attracted to the left boundary. Denote the scale measure with respect to tuple λ, M λ ) by S. We have B := S, ]) <. By the proof of Proposition 4.3, we know that λ, h ) + ) = λ, M B λ + ) is B in C. This is a contradiction. We now show that for z with m λ z < M λ, the diffusion process induced by tuple λ, z) is attracted to the left boundary. Let h and g be the functions corresponding to tuple λ, M λ ) and λ, z), respectively. Recall qx) = e x ky) dy y) in Proposition A.. Write h = uq and g = vq. It can be easily checked that u) = v) = and u ) > v ). Set Γ := u. By direct calculation, we have Γ = Γ 2 2v v Γx) for all x. By differentiating Γx) e x Thus, Γx) e x Γy)+ 2v y) vy) v u v Γ. Because Γ) > and Γ = is an equilibrium point, we know that ) Γy)+ 2v y) vy) ) Γ x) + Γ 2 x) + 2v x) vx) Γx) ) dy = Γ), which yields v 2 x) = e x 2v v e x dy, we have Γy)+ 2v y) vy) dy = Γx) Γ) e x Γy) dy. 3 ) dy =.

We obtain that y g 2 y) e 2kz) dz z) dy = v 2 y) dy = Γ) = Γ) Γy) e y Γz) dz dy e Γy) dy ) Γ) <. Therefore, the diffusion process induced by λ, z) is attracted to. C Proof of Proposition 4.5 Proof. Let δ < λ. Let g be a positive function of Lg = δg with g) = and g ) = M δ. We show that there does not exist a positive function h of Lh = λh with h) = and h ) = M δ. This implies that M δ > M λ. Suppose h is a positive solution of Lh = λh with h) = and h ) = M δ. Recall qx) = e x ky) Γ = u v. Then u v Γ = Γ 2 2v v y) dy in Proposition A.. Write h = uq and g = vq. Define 2λ δ) Γ. From Γ) =, we have that Γx) > for x < because if Γ ever gets close to, then term 2β λ) have dominates the right hand side of the equation. Choose x with x <. For x < x, we Integrating from x to x, 2 ln v x ) vx ) 2v x) vx) = Γ x) 2λ δ) + Γx) + Γx) x) Γx). Γ x ) x x = ln Γx ) + 2λ δ) Γy) dy + x x y) Γy) dy which leads to for x < x. Thus, v 2 x ) v 2 x ) Γ x ) Γx ) e x x Γy) dy x y g 2 y) e 2kz) x dz z) dy = v 2 y) dy x y x constant) Γy) e Γw)dw dy = constant) e x ) Γw)dw constant) <. This implies that the diffusion process induced by the tuple δ, M δ ) is attracted to the left boundary, which is a contradiction. 4

D Proof of Proposition 4.7 Suppose that two tuples λ, m λ ) and λ, M λ ) are in A. Let h m and h M be the functions corresponding to λ, m λ ) and λ, M λ ), respectively. Then e λt h m X t ) G t and e λt h M X t ) G t are martingales. For z with m λ z M λ, let h be the function corresponding to λ, z). Because h can be expressed as a linear combination of h m and h M, e λt hx t ) G t is also a martingale. Thus, λ, z) is in A. We now show that e λt hx t ) G t is not a martingale if at least one of λ, m λ ) and λ, M λ ) is not in A. Write h = c h m + c)h M for some constant c. Because e λt h m X t ) G t and e λt h M X t ) G t are positive local martingales, they are supermartingales. We have hξ) = c h m ξ) + c)h M ξ) c E[e λt h m X t ) G t ] + c) E[e λt h M X t ) G t ] = E[e λt hx t ) G t ]. If at least one of λ, m λ ) and λ, M λ ) is not in A, the above inequality is strict. This completes the proof. E Proof of Proposition 4.8 Theorem E.. Let β, φ) be a solution pair of Lφ = βφ with positive function φ. Then e βt φx t ) φ ξ) G t is a martingale if and only if the diffusion induced by β, φ) does not explode. Proof. Set dx t = k + φ φ )X t ) dt + σx t ) db t H t := exp 2 t v 2 X s ) ds t ) vx s ) dw s. Define a new measure L by setting the Radon-Nikodym derivative dl = H t dq. By the Girsanov theorem, we know that a process Z t defined by is a Brownian motion under L. It follows that dz t = vx t ) dt + dw t dx t = b vσ)x t ) dt + σx t ) dz t = kx t ) dt + σx t ) dz t. We used that that kx) = b vσ)x). We show that e βt φx t ) G t only if e βt t rxs) ds φx t ) is a martingale under L. It is because is a martingale under Q if and E L [e βt t rxs) ds φx t )] = E Q [e βt t rxs) ds φx t ) H t ] = E Q [e βt φx t ) G t ]. 5

Since both are supermatingales, this computation gives the desired result. From the contents of [6] on page 22 and 25, we know that e βt t rxs) ds φx t ) is a martingale under L if and only if dx t = k + φ φ )X t ) dt + σx t ) dz t does not explode. This completes the proof. Lemma E.2. Assume δ < λ β. Let g and h be the functions corresponding to tuple δ, M δ ) and λ, M λ ), respectively. Then we have g g > h h. Proof. For convenience, we may assume that ξ =, the left boundary is and the right boundary is. Recall qx) = e x ky) dy y) in Proposition A.. Write h = uq and g = vq. Define Γ = h g = u v. Then h g u v Γ = Γ 2 2v v 2λ δ) Γ. It suffices to show that Γx) < for all x. First, we show this for x >. We know Γ) = M λ M δ <. We have that Γx) < for all x > because Γ ever gets close to, then the term 2λ δ) dominates the right hand side of the equation above. We now show that Γx) < for all x <. Suppose there exists x < such that Γx ). Then for all z < x, it is obtained that Γz) > since if Γ ever gets close to, then term 2β λ) dominates the right hand side of the equation. Fix a point x such that x < x, thus Γx ) >. For z < x, we have 2v z) vz) = Γ z) 2β λ) + Γz) + Γz) z) By the same argument in Appendix B, we have x v 2 y) dy <. Γz). This implies that the diffusion process induced by tuple δ, M δ ) is attracted to the left boundary, which is a contradiction. We now prove Proposition 4.8. Proof. Assume δ < λ β. Let g and h be the functions corresponding to tuple δ, M δ ) and λ, M λ ), respectively. Suppose that e δt gx t ) G t is a martingale. Then by Proposition 3.2 and Theorem E., we know that the process X t under the transformed measure with respect to δ, M δ ) satisfies dx t = k + g g )X t ) dt + σx t ) db t and does not explode to. The above lemma says g g > h h. By the comparison theorem, we know that a process Y t with dy t = k + h h )Y t ) dt + σy t ) db t satisfies Y t X t almost everywhere, thus Y t does not explode to. On the other hand, it is clear that Y t does not explode to because it is non-attracted to the left boundary. By Theorem E., we conclude that e λt hx t ) G t is a martingale. 6

F An example for Corollary 4.6 Consider the equation Lh = λh. Recall that β := max{ λ λ, z) A }. That is, β is the maximum value among all the λ s of the solution pair λ, h) with hξ) = and h ) >. In this section, we explore an example such that Lh = βh has two linearly independent positive solutions. Let L be such that Lhx) := h x x) + + x 2 ) 3/4 h x) for x R. First, Lhx) = has two linearly independent positive solutions: h x) and h 2 x) = x y e uz) dz z dy where uz) =. +z 2 ) 3/4 It is enough to show that β =. That is, for any fixed λ >, the equation Lh = λh has no positive solutions. Suppose there exists such a positive solution h. Define a sequence of functions by g n x) := hx+n) for n N. By direct calculation, g hn) n satisfies the following equation: g nx) x + n + + x + n) 2 ) 3/4 g nx) = λg n x). F.) By the Harnack inequality stated below, we have that g n ) n= is equicontinuous on each compact set on R; thus we can obtain a subsequence g nk ) k= such that the subsequence converges on R, say the limit function g. Since g n is positive, the limit function g is nonnegative and g is a nonzero function because g) = lim k g nk ) =. On the other hand, it can be easily shown that the limit function g satisfies g x) = λgx) by taking limit n in equation F.. Clearly there does not exist a nonzero nonnegative solution of this equation when λ >. This is a contradiction. The author appreciates Srinivasa Varadhan for this example. Theorem F.. Harnack inequality) Let h : R R be a positive solution of ax)h x) + bx)h x) + cx)hx) =. Assume that ax) is bounded away from zero; that is, there is a positive number l such that ax) l >. Suppose that ax), bx) and cx) are bounded by a constant K. Then for any z >, there exists a positive number M = Mz, K) depending on z and K, but on neither a ), b ), c ) nor h )) such that hx) M whenever x y z. hy) G Reference Functions In this section, we focus on the function φ rather than the value β. We assume that we roughly know the behavior of φ; for example, we know a function f such that φ f is bounded below and above or such that E P ξ [φ f)x t )] converges to a nonzero constant. Knowing f means that we have information about φ near the area where the process X t lies with high probability under the objective measure. Such a function f is called a reference function of φ. More generally and more formally, we define a reference function in the following way. Definition 6. A positive function f is called a reference function of φ if lim t t log [ EP ξ φ f)x t ) ] =. 7

Proposition G.. Knowing a reference function is equivalent to knowing the value β. Proof. Suppose we know a reference function f of φ. From [ E Q ξ [G t fx t )] = E P ξ φ f)x t ) ] φξ) e βt, and by the definition of the reference function, we have that lim t t log EQ ξ [G t fx t )] = β. Hence, we know the value β. Conversely, suppose we know the value β. We show that for any admissible pair β, f) of Lf = βf, f is a reference function. We have and thus This completes the proof. References E Q ξ [G t fx t )] = e βt fξ) E P ξ [φ f)x t )] = E Q ξ [G t fx t )] e βt φ ξ) = φ f)ξ). [] Audrino, F., R. Huitema and M. Ludwig. An Empirical Analysis of the Ross Recovery Theorem. 24) Working paper. [2] Borovicka, J., L.P. Hansen and J.A. Scheinkman. Misspecified Recovery. 24) Working Paper. [3] Borovicka, J., L.P. Hansen, M. Hendricks and J.A. Scheinkman. Risk Price Dynamics. 2) Journal of Financial Econometrics, vol 9, 3-65. [4] Breeden, D.T. An Intertemporal Asset Pricing Model with Stochastic Consumption and Investment Opportunities 979) Journal of Financial Economics, vol 73), 265-296. [5] Carr, P. and J. Yu. Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery. 22) The Journal of Derivatives, vol. 2, no., 38-59. [6] Davydov, D. and V. Linetsky. Pricing Options on Scalar Diffusions: An Eigenfunction Expansion Approach. 23) Operations Research, 85-29. [7] Dubynskiy, S and R. Goldstein Recovering Drifts and Preference Parameters from Financial Derivatives 23) [8] Durrett, R. Stochastic Calculus: A Practical Introduction. 996) CRC Press. [9] Goodman, J. and H. Park Do Prices Determine Objective Measures? 24) Working Paper. [] Hansen, L.P. and J.A. Scheinkman. Long Term Risk: An Operator Approach. 29) Econometrica, vol 77, 77-234. [] Hull, J.C. Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives. 997) Pearson Prentice Hall. 8

[2] Karatzas, I. and S.E. Shreve. Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus. 99) Springer- Verlag. New York. [3] Karatzas, I. and S.E. Shreve. Methods of Mathematical Finance. 998) Springer-Verlag. New York. [4] Karlin, S. and H. Taylor. A Second Course in Stochastic Process. 98) Academic Press. [5] Martin, I. and S. Ross. The Long Bond. 23) Working paper. [6] Pinsky, R.G. Positive Harmonic Fuinction and Diffusion. 995) Cambridge University Press. New York [7] Qin, L. and V. Linetsky. Long Term Risk: A Martingale Approach. 24a) Working paper. [8] Qin, L. and V. Linetsky. Positive Eigenfunctions of Markovian Pricing Operators: Hansen- Scheinkman Factorization and Ross Recovery. 24b) Working paper. [9] Romer, D. Advanced Macroeconomics. 22) McGraw-Hill. [2] Ross, S.A. The Recovery Theorem. 25) Journal of Finance, vol 7, no 2, 65 648. [2] Walden, J. Recovery with Unbounded Diffusion Processes. 23) Working paper. [22] Zettl, A. Sturm-Liouville Theory. 25) American Mathematical Society, vol 2. 9