Carmen M. Reinhart b. Received 9 February 1998; accepted 7 May 1998

Similar documents
The Distortionary Effects of Inflation: An Empirical Investigation

Aggregate Consumption and the Risk Free Rates in Turkey: An Empirical Analysis. Türkiye de Toplam Tüketim ve Risksiz Faiz Oranları: Ampirik bir Analiz

14.471: Fall 2012: Recitation 12: Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution (EIS)

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

Government expenditure and Economic Growth in MENA Region

COINTEGRATION AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: AN APPLICATION TO THE CANADIAN TREASURY BILL MARKET. Soo-Bin Park* Carleton University, Ottawa, Canada K1S 5B6

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

STOCK MARKET RETURNS, RISK AVERSION AND CONSUMPTION GROWTH: EVIDENCE FROM THE NIGERIAN ECONOMY

Limited Asset Market Participation and the Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution

Sensitivity, Moment Conditions, and the Risk-free Rate in Yogo (2006)

Asset Pricing with Left-Skewed Long-Run Risk in. Durable Consumption

Ricardian Equivalence: Further Evidence

HABIT PERSISTENCE AND DURABILITY IN AGGREGATE CONSUMPTION: EMPIRICAL TESTS. Wayne E. Ferson. Working Paper No. 3631

Working Paper No. 2032

Why the saving rate has been falling in Japan

Institute of Economic Research Working Papers. No. 63/2017. Short-Run Elasticity of Substitution Error Correction Model

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHAT DO AGGREGATE CONSUMPTION EULER EQUATIONS SAY ABOUT THE CAPITAL INCOME TAX BURDEN? Casey B. Mulligan

A numerical analysis of the monetary aspects of the Japanese economy: the cash-in-advance approach

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Spending for Growth: An Empirical Evidence of Thailand

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Cross-Country Heterogeneity in Intertemporal Substitution

Volume 37, Issue 2. Handling Endogeneity in Stochastic Frontier Analysis

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Do Closer Economic Ties Imply Convergence in Income - The Case of the U.S., Canada, and Mexico

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman

Structural Change in the External Balances Response to Macroeconomic Policies: Perspective from a Two-Sector New Open Economy Macroeconomic Model*

Department of Economics Working Paper

Long-Run Stockholder Consumption Risk and Asset Returns. Malloy, Moskowitz and Vissing-Jørgensen

A Note on the Solow Growth Model with a CES Production Function and Declining Population

INTERNATIONAL REAL ESTATE REVIEW 2002 Vol. 5 No. 1: pp Housing Demand with Random Group Effects

Replacement versus Historical Cost Profit Rates: What is the difference? When does it matter?

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility

Conditional Convergence Revisited: Taking Solow Very Seriously

Is the real effective exchange rate biased against the PPP hypothesis?

Dynamic Asset Pricing Model

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS. No 449. Pursuing the Wrong Options? Adjustment Costs and the Relationship between Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation

SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN *

The Return to Wealth, Asset Pricing, and the Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution

Money Demand in an Open-Economy Shopping-Time Model: An Out-of-Sample- Prediction Application to Canada

Determinants of Cyclical Aggregate Dividend Behavior

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Jacek Prokop a, *, Ewa Baranowska-Prokop b

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Estimating term structure of interest rates: neural network vs one factor parametric models

The purpose of this paper is to examine the determinants of U.S. foreign

Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data

Dynamic Scoring of Tax Reform in the Open Economy *

IN THIS LECTURE, YOU WILL LEARN:

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Asset Pricing with Durable Goods and Non-Homothetic Preferences

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Appendix: Net Exports, Consumption Volatility and International Business Cycle Models.

Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle?

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Macroeconomics and finance

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Asian Journal of Economic Modelling MEASUREMENT OF THE COST-OF-LIVING INDEX IN THE EASI MODEL: EVIDENCE FROM THE JAPANESE EXPENDITURE DATA

Threshold cointegration and nonlinear adjustment between stock prices and dividends

Estimating the Current Value of Time-Varying Beta

Dividend, investment and the direction of causality

Capital-goods imports, investment-specific technological change and U.S. growth

ARE EXPORTS AND IMPORTS COINTEGRATED? EVIDENCE FROM NINE MENA COUNTRIES* HUSEIN, Jamal ** Abstract

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Macroeconometric Modeling: 2018

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

The early 1970s witnessed dramatic change in per-capita output and

THE EFFECT OF SOCIAL SECURITY ON PRIVATE SAVING: THE TIME SERIES EVIDENCE

Lottery Purchases and Taxable Spending: Is There a Substitution Effect?

Impact of Fed s Credit Easing on the Value of U.S. Dollar

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ARE GOVERNMENT SPENDING MULTIPLIERS GREATER DURING PERIODS OF SLACK? EVIDENCE FROM 20TH CENTURY HISTORICAL DATA

Problem Set 5. Graduate Macro II, Spring 2014 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact

STOCHASTIC CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL: CANONICAL APPLICATIONS SEPTEMBER 13, 2010 BASICS. Introduction

Fixed Effects Maximum Likelihood Estimation of a Flexibly Parametric Proportional Hazard Model with an Application to Job Exits

Social Security and Saving: A Comment

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction

Testing the Permanent Income Hypothesis in the Developing and Developed Countries: A Comparison between Fiji and Australia

CAN MONEY SUPPLY PREDICT STOCK PRICES?

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

(F6' The. ,,42, ancy of the. U.S. Wheat Acreage Supply Elasticity. Special Report 546 May 1979

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus)

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Redistribution Effects of Electricity Pricing in Korea

The Effect of the Internet on Economic Growth: Evidence from Cross-Country Panel Data

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power?

Lecture 3, Part 1 (Bubbles, Portfolio Balance Models)

Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences

Trade Openness and Disaggregated Import Demand in East African Countries

competition for a country s exports at the global scene. Thus, in this situation, a successful real devaluation 2 can improve and enhance export earni

Transcription:

economics letters Intertemporal substitution and durable goods: long-run data Masao Ogaki a,*, Carmen M. Reinhart b "Ohio State University, Department of Economics 1945 N. High St., Columbus OH 43210, USA buniversity of Maryland, Baltimore, USA Received 9 February 1998; accepted 7 May 1998 In this paper, we use long-run annual data to estimate the intertempora] elasticity of substitution while accounting for the intra-temporal substitution between nondurable consumption goods and durable consumption goods. We apply a two-step procedure that combines a cointegration approach to preference parameter estimation with Generalized Method of Moments. 1998 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. As Hall (1988) points out, intertemporal substitution by consumers is a central element of many modern macroeconomic and international models, The quantitative importance of effects of changes in various policies implied by these models depend on the magnitude of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution (IES). However, when time aggregation is taken into account, point estimates of the IES tend to be small or even negative. Hall (1988) finds that when time aggregation is taken into account, his point estimates are small and not significantly different from zero. He concludes that the elasticity is unlikely to be much above 0.1 and may well be zero. Thus, his results suggest that intertemporal substitution by consumers is not empirically important. Working with a similar economic model, Hansen and Singleton (1996) improved on Hall's inference methods with a technique that is scale invariant and asymptotically efficient. While they find that there is considerably less precision in the estimation and evidence against small positive values of the IES, their point estimates are negative. In the companion paper, Ogaki and Reinhart (1998), we argue that the model used by these authors is misspecified because the intra-temporal substitution between nondurable consumption goods and durable consumption goods is ignored. Both Hall (1988) and Hansen and Singleton (1996) assume that preferences are additively separable in nondurable and durable goods, but there is empirical evidence against this assumption (see, e.g., Eichenbaum and Hansen (1990». In principle, when two 0165-1765/98/$ - see front matter 1998 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. PH: SOI65-1765(98)00136-0

goods are not additively separable, ignoring one good in estimating the IES of the other good does not necessarily induce a bias that increases the probability of finding either small and positive point estimates or estimates with the wrong sign. In the case of nondurable and durable goods, however, ignoring durable goods in estimating the IES, as in Hall (1988) and Hansen and Singleton (1996), likely introduces a bias in this direction. Hall assumes that preferences are additively separable in nondurable and durable goods, but there is empirical evidence against this assumption (see, e.g., Eichenbaum and Hansen (1990)). When two goods are not additively separable, ignoring one good does not necessarily induce a downward bias in an estimator of the IES for the other good. In the case of nondurable durable goods, however, when the durable good is ignored, the estimators for the IES of the nondurable good are likely to be biased downward. The reason for this is twofold. First, consumption of durable goods is more volatile than nondurable good consumption. In Section 3, we will show that the service flow from the durable good purchase is more volatile than nondurable consumption in the U.S. data. Second, real interest rates affect the user cost for the service flow from the durable good. For example, suppose that the real interest rate rises this year. Other things being equal, this results in a higher user cost for the durable good this year and, thus, consumers will substitute away from the durable good and increase today's consumption of the nondurable good. As long as the user cost in the next year does not fall to offset this effect, the growth rate of nondurable consumption decreases compared with the case of no change in user cost. Hence, the estimator of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution which is based only on the growth rate of nondurable consumption growth will be biased downward. In order to see if this downward bias is important, we use Cooley and Ogaki (1996) Cointegration- Euler Equation approach, and allow for nonseparable preferences in nondurable and durable goods. We assume that the Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) utility function represents intra-temporal preferences. The CES utility function is estimated by Ogaki and Park (1998) cointegration approach to estimating preference parameters in the first step. In the second step, Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) is applied to the Euler equation with the estimated CES utility function. In Ogaki and Reinhart (1998), we apply this two step approach to post war U.S. quarterly data and find that our estimates for the IES are positive and significantly different from zero, even when time aggregation is taken into account. In this paper, we apply the approach to long-run U.S. annual data. It is important to confirm our findings from post war data with long run data because the long-run data are more appropriate for the cointegration approach. In this section, we introduce our model of nonseparable preferences between nondurable and durable consumption. Suppose that a representative consumer maximizes the lifetime utility function in a complete market at time 0, where E r (') denotes expectations conditional on the information available at time t. The intra-period utility function is assumed to be of the CES form for the nondurable good (good I) and the durable good (good 2);

where S2(t) is the service flow from the purchases of good 2. Purchases of the durable consumption good and the service flow are related by where C 2 (t) is the real consumption expenditure for good 2 at time t. Let P/t) be the purchase price of consumption good i. We take good I as a numeraire for each period: P J (t) == I. Let R(t + 1) be the (gross) return on any asset in terms of good 1, which is realized at t + I. Then, the Euler equation is: In order to derive the restrictions that imply cointegration, it is useful to observe another first order condition which states that the purchase price relative to the price of the nondurable good, P 2 (t), is equated with the marginal rate of substitution based on purchases of goods: where mu 2 (t) = S2(t)-J/C(aC J (t)j-i/c + S2(t)J-l/c/u-c)/[u(C-I)] This first order condition forms the basis of the cointegration approach and summarizes the information from the demand side: Ogaki and Reinhart (1998) show that under certain conditions, the first order condition (7) implies that P 2 (t)[c2(t)/ci (t)] 11c is stationary. This section explains the data and reports the empirical results of the two step approach. The data are annual and cover 1929 to 1990. For good 1, we use either nondurables (ND) or nondurables plus services (NDS) from the National Income and Product Account (NIPA). For good 2, we use real durables from the NIPA for the annual data and for the quarterly data either real durables in the NIPA. We use the implicit deflators as the purchase prices. In constructing the service flow series for durables, (3) is used with the initial condition on Set) from Musgrave (1979). In Musgrave's data, the depreciation rate is about 18 percent. Wykoff (1970) estimates a depreciation of about 20 percent per year using resale values of automobiles. For our base results, we use 8 = 0.8 for the annual data and 8 = 0.94 for the quarterly data. In order to obtain per capita real consumption, we use resident population.

Nominal interest rate data, together with Barro's average marginal tax rate series, are used to construct nominal after tax rates. These are converted into real rates by the implicit deflator for good 1. We use the six-month commercial paper rate, which is compounded to calculate the one-year rate of return. In Step 1, we apply a cointegrating regression to the intratemporal first order condition (9) in order to estimate the intratemporal elasticity of substitution, 6. In Step 2, GMM is applied to the Euler Eg. (4). For details of the econometric method, see Ogaki and Reinhart (1998). Table 1 reports the co integrating regression results based on Park (1992) Canonical Cointegrating Regression (CCR) for ND and NDS with and without the dummy variable for 1940-45 for World War II (WWII). For ND, the dummy variable is significant at the five percent level. For NDS, the dummy variable is not significant at the five percent level, but is significant at the ten percent level. In addition, the R(p, q) tests are more favorable for the specification with the dummy variable. Among the four R(p, q) test statistics reported for ND with the dummy variable, only one is significant at the ten percent level and none of them is significant at the one percent level. Among the four R(p, q) test statistics for NDS with the dummy variable, one is marginally significant at the one percent level and another is significant at the five percent level. Overall, the evidence against cointegration is not strong because the R(p, q) tests often overreject according to Han and Ogaki (1997). For all cases, the intratemporal elasticity of substitution, 6, is estimated with the theoretically correct positive sign. For ND, the intratemporal elasticity of substitution is also estimated to be significantly larger than one at the five percent level, so that the Cobb-Douglas utility function is rejected. For NDS, our point estimates for 6 are not significantly different from either zero or one. Table 2 presents the GMM results. The instrumental variables are a constant, the realized real interest rate, the growth rate of the real consumption ratio of good 1 and good 2, and the real defense expenditure growth rate. All instruments are lagged two periods rather than one. Including the growth rate of consumption of good 1, which is often used as an instrument, led to convergence problems after one or two iterations. This fact and Hall (1988) finding that consumption growth has, at most, Table I Canonical cointegrating regression results Nondurable E: d H(O, I) H(I, 2) H(I,3) H(I,4) Good (I) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) ND 3.951 1.531 0.208 0.298 2.719 ( 1.329) (0.216) (0.648) (0.862) (0.437) ND 2.861 0.711 5.918 1.119 1.128 2.518 (0.807) (0.269) (0.015) (0.290) (0.569) (0.472) NDS 0.964 3.205 6.271 6.366 8.232 (0.628) (0.073) (0.012) (0.041) (0.041 ) NDS 0.980 0.404 1.407 6.641 6.664 6.924 (0.535) (0.225) (0.236) (0.010) (0.036) (0.074) NOTE: In cols. 2 and 3, standard errors are in parentheses. Co!. 3 gives a coefficient of the dummy variable for the WWII when it is included in the regression. Co!. 4 is a X 2 test statistic for the deterministic cointegration restriction. Asymptotic P-values are in parentheses. Cols. 5, 6 and 7 are X 2 test statistics for stochastic cointegration. Asymptotic P-va1ues are in parentheses.

M. Ogaki. C.M. Reinhart / Economics Letters 6/ (/998) 85-90 89 Table 2 Generalized method of moments results Nondurable e (T f3 it Good Data (I) (3) (4) (5) (6) The Two-Good Model ND 2.861 0.766 1.032 1.778 (0.340) (0.016) (0.411 ) NDS 0.980 0.414 1.065 1.493 (0.186) (0.032) (0.474) The One-Good Model ND 0.588 0.979 2.378 (0.381 ) (0.019) (0.304) NDS 0.270 0.934 3.319 (0.183) (0.050) (0.190) NOTE: In cols. 3 and 4, standard errors are in parentheses. Co!. 5 reports Hansen's i test with two degrees of freedom, and asymptotic P-values in parentheses. only weak serial correlation suggest that the growth rate of consumption of good 1 is not a good instrument. The first panel presents our results for the two-good model described in Section 2. The second panel presents our results for the one-good model, which can be obtained by assuming u = 6 (which is the separability case). For the one-good model, a is normalized to one. While the one-good model is similar to Hall (1988) model, we include the results because the econometric method and sample period are somewhat different. Unlike Hall, we do not linearize the Euler Eq. (4) due to the difficulty in doing so for the two-good model. We use exactly the same econometric method and data for both the one-good and two-good models, so that we can directly compare the results. In all cases, Hansen's J test of the overidentifying restrictions does not reject the model at the conventional levels. For both ND and NDS, our point estimates of u are positive and significantly different from zero at the five percent level for the two-good model. In contrast, the one-good model yields smaller point estimates of u for both ND and NDS with similar standard errors. It should be noted that the separability assumption (u= 6) is rejected in the two-good model for both ND and NDS. In this paper, we have used long-run annual data to confirm Ogaki and Reinhart (1998) findings from postwar quarterly data. This task is important because we estimate the intratemporal elasticity of substitution from a cointegrating regression in our two step procedure. Because cointegration is a long-run relationship, it is desirable to use long-run data. Our results from the long-run data are similar to those from postwar data. The IES is estimated to be positive and significant when the role of durable good consumption is taken into account.

All data and programs used for this paper are available from the first author upon request. Portions of this paper were written while the first author was a visiting scholar at the Research Department of the International Monetary Fund. He thanks the Commodities and Special Issues Division staff for a stimulative research environment, and gratefully acknowledges financial support by National Science Foundation grant no. SES-9213930. Cooley, T.F., Ogaki, M.A., 1996. Time series analysis of real wages, consumption, and asset returns. Journal of Applied Econometrics I I, I 19- I34. Eichenbaum, M., Hansen, L.P., 1990. Estimating models with intertemporal substitution using aggregate time series data. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 8, 53-69. Hall, R.E., 1988. Intertemporal substitution in consumption. Journal of Political Economy 96, 330-357. Han, H.-L., Ogaki, M., 1997. Consumption, income, and cointegration: further analysis. International Review of Economics and Finance 6, 107-1 17. Hansen, L.P., Singleton, K.J., 1996. Efficient estimation of linear asset-pricing models with moving average errors. Journal of Business and Economics Statistics 14, 53-68. Musgrave, J.e., 1979. Durable goods owned by consumers in the United States, 1925-77. Survey of Current Business, March, 17-25. Ogaki, M., Park, J.Y., 1998. A cointegration approach to estimating preference parameters. Journal of Econometrics, January, 107-134. Ogaki, M., Reinhart, e.m., 1998. Measuring intertemporal substitution: the role of durables. Journal of Political Economy, in press. Park, J.Y., 1992. Canonical cointegrating regressions. Econometrica 60, 119-143. Wykoff, F.e., 1970. Capital depreciation in the postwar period: automobiles. Review of Economics and Statistics 52, 168-172.