Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Similar documents
DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data

Labour market frictions in a small open economy model of the Czech Republic

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Inflation Target and its Impact on Macroeconomy in the Zero Lower Bound Environment: the case of the Czech economy

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Transmission of fiscal policy shocks into Romania's economy

Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Effi cient monetary policy frontier for Iceland

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

Sebastian Sienknecht. Inflation persistence amplification in the Rotemberg model

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks: Comment

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence

DISCUSSION OF NON-INFLATIONARY DEMAND DRIVEN BUSINESS CYCLES, BY BEAUDRY AND PORTIER. 1. Introduction

Monetary Policy and Inflation Dynamics in Asset Price Bubbles

On the Merits of Conventional vs Unconventional Fiscal Policy

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

1 Business-Cycle Facts Around the World 1

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy

Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy in A Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Phillips Curve

Romania s accession to the Eurozone a simulation using a simple DSGE model

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

WORKING PAPER SERIES 15. Juraj Antal and František Brázdik: The Effects of Anticipated Future Change in the Monetary Policy Regime

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

Does natural rate variation matter? Evidence from New Zealand. Michael Kirker. December JEL classification: C51, E52, F41

Nominal rigidities and wage-price dynamics in DSGE model of open economy: application for the Czech Republic

On the new Keynesian model

Endogenous Money or Sticky Wages: A Bayesian Approach

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Satya P. Das NIPFP) Open Economy Keynesian Macro: CGG (2001, 2002), Obstfeld-Rogoff Redux Model 1 / 18

Fiscal Consolidations in Currency Unions: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes

UNIVERSITY OF TOKYO 1 st Finance Junior Workshop Program. Monetary Policy and Welfare Issues in the Economy with Shifting Trend Inflation

The Real Business Cycle Model

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Financial intermediaries in an estimated DSGE model for the UK

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions

Groupe de Recherche en Économie et Développement International. Cahier de recherche / Working Paper 09-02

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

Discussion of Limitations on the Effectiveness of Forward Guidance at the Zero Lower Bound

Do Nominal Rigidities Matter for the Transmission of Technology Shocks?

Introduction to DSGE Models

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions

The New Keynesian Model

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

The Eurozone Debt Crisis: A New-Keynesian DSGE model with default risk

Dynamic Macroeconomics

The Welfare Consequences of Nominal GDP Targeting

The Zero Lower Bound

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model

Volume 35, Issue 4. Real-Exchange-Rate-Adjusted Inflation Targeting in an Open Economy: Some Analytical Results

Samba: Stochastic Analytical Model with a Bayesian Approach. DSGE Model Project for Brazil s economy

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

The Great Recession in the Non-EMU Visegrád Countries: A Nonlinear DSGE Model with Time-Varying Parameters *

State-Dependent Pricing and the Paradox of Flexibility

Taking Multi-Sector Dynamic General Equilibrium Models to the Data

Gali Chapter 6 Sticky wages and prices

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

Evolving Macroeconomic dynamics in a small open economy: An estimated Markov Switching DSGE model for the UK

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 11. The Smets-Wouters Model

Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy 1

The new Kenesian model

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Do Central Banks respond to exchange rate movements? A Markov-Switching structural investigation

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility

Inflation s Role in Optimal Monetary-Fiscal Policy

Output Gaps and Robust Monetary Policy Rules

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools

Inflation and Output Dynamics in a Model with Labor Market Search and Capital Accumulation

Optimal Monetary Policy Instrument in Setting Monetary Policy Reaction Function in Nigeria

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont)

Macroprudential Policy Implementation in a Heterogeneous Monetary Union

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

A New Keynesian Phillips Curve for Japan

Fiscal Consolidation in a Currency Union: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes

How Robust are Popular Models of Nominal Frictions?

Lorant Kaszab (MNB) Roman Horvath (IES)

Monetary Economics. Lecture 11: monetary/fiscal interactions in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

Nobel Symposium Money and Banking

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Do Central Banks Respond to Exchange Rate Movements? Some New Evidence from Structural Estimation

Fiscal Policy in an Estimated DSGE Model of the Japanese Economy

Transcription:

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach Pavel Herber 1 and Daniel Němec 2 1 Masaryk University, Faculty of Economics and Administrations Department of Economics Lipová 41a, 602 00 Brno, Czech Republic pherber@seznam.cz 2 Masaryk University, Faculty of Economics and Administrations Department of Economics Lipová 41a, 602 00 Brno, Czech Republic nemecd@econ.muni.cz Abstract. In our contribution, we estimate the output gap that is consistent with a fully specified DSGE model. The output gap is defined in this framework as a deviation of actual output from its flexible-price equilibrium level. The flexible-price equilibrium corresponds to the state of the economy with more efficient allocation. These estimates are thus useful indicators for monetary policy. Our output gap illustrates Czech business cycles which are rather different to other estimates (e.g. HP filter). This result may be typical for economies in transition. Moreover, our results for the Czech economy show that the turning points in the gaps are accompanied by government changes. 1 Introduction There are various methods and models to estimate the potential output and output gap. One way is to use pure statistical estimates (e.g. HP filter). Such an approach lacks of economic content. Production function method estimates an aggregate production function with equilibrium inputs. More economic approaches estimate potential output within the framework of the Phillips curve. These models exploit reduced-form equations and the resulting output gaps are non-accelerating inflation measure. In our contribution, we estimate the output gap (using Bayesian techniques) that is consistent with a fully specified DSGE model. The output gap is defined in this framework as a deviation of actual output from its flexible-price equilibrium level. The flexible-price equilibrium corresponds to the state of the economy with more efficient allocation. These estimates are thus useful indicators for monetary policy. Our contribution is structured as follows. The next section provides a brief description of the basic New Keynesian DSGE model which is used for our analysis. Section 3 explains used data and estimation techniques. In Section 4, our baseline estimation results are presented and robustness of our analysis is checked. Section 5 concludes this contribution.

2 The model The model is a simple variant of the standard New Keynesian (NK) DSGE model used by Hirose and Naganuma [5]. The model consists of optimizing households and monopolistic firms facing price stickiness. Monetary policy follows an interest-rate feedback rule. All real variables are detrended by a non-stationary trend component of the productivity process Āt with the constant growth rate γ. This assumption guarantees stationarity of the model. We will present only the log-linearized version of the model in this contribution. Basic equations, derivation of first-order conditions and details to the log-linearization of corresponding equations are provided by Herber [3] and Herber and Němec [4]. For further references and extensions of basic NK DSGE model see Galí [2]. Our system consists from following log-linearized equations: u C,t y t = E t u C,t+1 E ty t+1 + r t E t π t+1 (1) w t p t = d t + ηn t u C,t + y t (2) [ ) u 1 C,t = (1 τ) ((1 + βh 2 )y t hy t 1 βhe t y t+1 1 βh ] + d t βhe t d t+1 (3) (1 βω)(1 ω) π t = βe t π t+1 + ϕ t + 1 ω ω ω (z t βωe t z t+1 ) (4) y f t = a t + 1 1 + η u f c,t 1 1 + η d t (5) [ ( ) u f C,t = 1 (1 τ) (1 + βh 2 )y f t 1 βh hyf t 1 βhe ty f t+1 ] + d t βhe t d t+1 (6) ] r t = ρ r r t 1 + (1 ρ r ) [ψ π π t + ψ y (y t y ft ) + ǫ r,t (7) d t = ρ d d t 1 + ǫ d,t (8) z t = ρ z z t 1 + ǫ z,t (9) a t = ρ a a t 1 + ǫ a,t (10) Lower case letters are logarithms of the corresponding upper cases. The notation is very intuitive but all the details may be found in Herber [3] or Herber and Němec [4]. We have seven equations for endogenous variables and three equations which describe exogenous processes. The system includes four shocks ǫ r,t, ǫ d,t, ǫ z,t a ǫ a,t. Previous equations may be read as follows: Equation (1) is a New Keynesian IS curve (Euler equation for the consumption). Equation (2) represents labor supply curve of the households. Equation (3) express marginal utility of consumption. Equation (4) is a New Keynesian Phillips curve. Equation (5) defines potential output. Equation (6) reflects marginal utility of consumption in the case of flexible-price framework. Equation (7) is a modified Taylor

rule. Equation (8) is the AR(1) process of demand shock. Equation (9) is the AR(1) process of cost shock. Equation (10) is the AR(1) process of productivity shock. We will use the log-linearized versions of both production function and real marginal costs: y t = a t + n t, (11) ϕ t = w t p t a t. (12) We estimate 15 parameters. These parameters are described in the Table 1. Parameter Description Table 1. Parameters Range Density τ 1 Intertemporal elasticity in consumption IR + Gamma β Discount factor (0, 1) Beta h Habit persistence (0, 1) Beta η 1 Elasticity of substitution between labor and consumption IR + Gamma ω The share of non-optimizing firms [0, 1] Beta ψ π Elasticity of the interest rate with respect to inflation IR + Gamma ψ y Elasticity of the interest rate with respect to output gap IR + Gamma ρ r Interest rate smoothness [0,1) Beta ρ d Persistence in the demand shock [0,1) Beta ρ z Persistence in the supply shock [0,1) Beta ρ a Persistence in the productivity shock [0,1) Beta σ r Standard deviation of the monetary shock IR + Inv. Gam. σ d Standard deviation of the demand shock IR + Inv. Gam. σ z Standard deviation of the supply shock IR + Inv. Gam. σ a Standard deviation of the productivity shock IR + Inv. Gam. 3 Estimation We use Bayesian techniques (Random-Walk metropolis Hasting algorithm) and Kalman filter algorithm in order to estimate both the parameters and unobserved potential output. The model is thus identified by using the Dynare toolbox for Matlab [6]. We use quarterly seasonally adjusted macroeconomic data of the Czech Republic from the second quarter 1996 to the fourth quarter 2008. Observable variables are quarter-on-quarter productivity growth, inflation and nominal interest rate. Productivity is obtained from the output growth of real GDP divided by the labor force. The inflation rate is based on CPI and interest rate is the 3M PRIBOR. Inflation and nominal interest rate are annualized. One of the alternative models uses data of the inflation target. The variables in the model are expressed as deviation from their steady-states. We have added measurement equations that relate the model variables to the data (instead of

prefiltering the observed data): Yt obs = γ ss + y t y t 1, (13) Πt obs = π ss + 4π t, (14) Rt obs = rr ss + π ss + 4r t, (15) where γ ss is equilibrium growth rate of a non stationary technology shock, π ss is annualized inflation at the steady-state and rr ss is real interest rate at the steady-state. Priors are presented in the Table 2. They are mostly in line with Table 2. Estimates - parameters and shocks Parameter Prior mean Prior s.d. Post. mean 90% HPDI τ 1.10 0.50 2.3128 1.5128 3.0692 h 0.80 0.10 0.9661 0.9317 0.9982 η 1.50 0.30 1.5442 1.0440 2.0247 ω 0.60 0.20 0.7944 0.7163 0.8774 ψ π 1.50 0.30 1.3157 0.9985 1.5823 ψ y 0.30 0.15 0.2706 0.0627 0.4794 ρ r 0.65 0.25 0.7290 0.6603 0.7990 ρ d 0.50 0.25 0.8308 0.7253 0.9414 ρ z 0.50 0.25 0.5724 0.2029 0.9779 ρ a 0.70 0.25 0.9336 0.8790 0.9953 γ ss 0.50 0.30 0.6725 0.5067 0.8467 π ss 3.50 0.50 3.6368 2.8588 4.3909 rr ss 1.80 0.30 1.7559 1.2991 2.1924 σ r 0.30 0.3355 0.2771 0.3946 σ d 0.50 1.0901 0.4321 1.7915 σ z 0.50 0.4230 0.1050 0.9410 σ a 0.80 1.4366 0.8301 2.0816 the estimates of similar estimates for the Czech Republic (see Musil and Vašíček [7] or Remo and Vašíček [8]). Prior hyperparameters of π ss and rr ss are obtained from the historical averages of inflation and real interest rate. 4 Results Table 2 reports posterior distributions of the structural parameters. The posterior mean of the parameter τ is 2.31, intertemporal elasticity of substitution τ 1 is thus 0.43. Households prefer actual consumption to future consumption. The parameter h is 0.97, i.e.past consumption plays crucial role in current decisions. The parameter η is 1.54. Elasticity for labor supply is therefore 0.65. This low elasticity is typical for the Czech labor market because of low flexibility of the labor force. Price rigidity is related to the parameter ω. The mean value 0.8 means that only 20% of firms change their price every quarter. The mean contract duration is thus five quarters.

The reaction function of the Czech National Bank is based on the parameters ρ r, ψ π a ψ y. Interest rate rule may be written as r t = 0.73r t 1 + 0.36π t + 0.07gap t + ǫ r,t. (16) The smoothing parameter is relative high and plays the most important role in monetary decisions. Central bank places five times less weight on the output gap relative to inflation variations. The autoregressive coefficients for the shocks represent persistency of the shocks. Figure 1 plots the posterior mean of smoothed estimate of the output gap and its 90% confidence intervals. This trajectory may be compared with the gap obtained using Hodrick-Prescott filter. Using U.S. data we were able to replicate the original results presented by Hirose and Naganuma [5] which are similar compared with other commonly used estimates. Our output gap, on the other hand, illustrates Czech business cycles which are rather different to the estimate using HP filter. 3 Outpu gap 90% confidence interval Output gap HP filter 2 1 [%] 0 1 2 3 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 Fig.1. Output gap and confidence intervals Our approach shows the potential of the economy with flexible-prices that would prevail in the absence of cost shocks. We may present alternative estimates which measures output gap as the deviation of the actual output from its equilibrium (trend) level. In this case, the dynamics of the gap should be in accordance with HP filter estimates. This may be shown on the Figure 2. Resulting trajectories differ in levels because our data are detrended by steady-state growth rate of a technology shock (parameter γ ss ). As argued by Woodford [9], an optimal monetary policy replicates flexibleprice equilibrium, which can be the best outcome of the economy where gov-

ernment offsets monopolistics distortions by appropriate transfers. The output gap that is defined here should be a useful measure for monetary policy makers (from a welfare perspective). Monetary policy is able to stabilize inflation and welfare of the households (approximated by the output gap). These goals are conformable with each other. New Keynesian approach to the output gap offers relevant economic background compared to the traditional estimates. Output gap is linked to real marginal costs which influence inflation within the Phillips curve framework. There is a strong relationship between output gap and inflation which may be used by monetary authority. 6 4 2 0 [%] 2 4 6 Output gap HP filter Gap actual output Gap potential output 8 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 Fig.2. Actual output gap and potential output gap What says our output gap in the Figure 1? Its trajectory indicates the existence of rigid prices in the Czech economy. On the one hand, these rigidities have damped impact of recession in the period since 1997 and 2001 (positive output gap). On the other hand they restrain economic growth in the periods of the booms (negative output gap since 2005). Our results for the Czech economy show that the turning points in the gaps are accompanied by government changes (1998, 2002 and 2006). 4.1 Prior sensitivity and model alternatives Our results may be influenced by the choice of prior hyperparameters. We have specified two alternative prior sets based on tight and loose prior. Our choice concerns following parameters: τ, h, η, ω, ψ π, ψ y, γ ss, π ss and rr ss. In the case of tight prior the prior standard deviation equals a half of the base one. In

the case of loose prior the standard deviations has been doubled. As expected, for most of the parameters, deviations of the posterior estimates from the prior means were remarkable under the loose prior. The tight prior leads the posterior estimates close to the prior. The output gap is similar to the gap under the loose prior at the beginning of the period and to the gap under loose prior in the second half of the period. The output gap under the tight prior exhibits smaller volatility due to the smaller values of h and ω. The dynamic of all trajectories is almost the same within the whole period. Our baseline estimate may be taken as a relevant compromise estimate. We have made three alternative specifications of the model which may be more appropriate to describe the Czech economy. The first model (Model 1) assumes time-varying steady-state growth rate of technology shocks γt ss. The second model (Model 2) assumes time-varying steady-state inflation πt ss. The last model (Model 3) takes into account inflation targeting. In our case, inflation gap will be defined as the difference between actual inflation and its target level. The results are not sensitive to the changes in measurement equations. Obtained output gaps have similar dynamics in comparison with the basic model. They differ only in levels of the gaps and in the confidence intervals which are larger. Interesting results are offered by Model 3 which takes into account inflation targeting. Central bank was not able to achieve its inflation target at the beginning of the period of inflation targeting. This fact leads to higher volatility of the inflation gap in our model. The Phillips curve and the dynamics of the real marginal costs are the mechanisms through which the volatility of the output gap increases. For more detailed discussion about our alternative models and sensitivity analysis (including the trajectories of time-varying steady-state values) see Herber [3] or Herber and Němec [4]. 5 Conclusion In our contribution, we estimated the output gap which is consistent with the fully specified DSGE model. This gap is a useful measure for welfare of the economy. The output gap is a plausible indicator for monetary policy. Structural parameters may provide an economic interpretation for movements of the estimated output gap. Using U.S. data we were able to replicate the original results presented by Hirose and Naganuma [5] which are similar compared with other commonly used estimates. Our output gap, on the other hand, illustrates Czech business cycles which are rather different to other estimates (e.g. HP filter). This result may be typical for economies in transition. Rigidities in the Czech economy have damped the fall of economy in the periods of recession but they have hindered the potential growth in the periods of booms. Moreover, our results for the Czech economy show that the turning points in the gaps are accompanied by government changes. Acknowledgement This work was supported by MŠMT project Research centers 1M0524, and funding of specific research at ESF MU.

References 1. Calvo, G. A.: Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework. Journal of Monetary Economics, 12(3), 383-398 (1983) 2. Galí, J.: Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business Cycle. Princeton University Press (2008) 3. Herber, P.: Odhady potenciálního produktu - DSGE přístup. Master Thesis, Masaryk University, Brno (2009) 4. Herber, P, Němec, D.: Estimating output gap - DSGE approach. Working papers CVKS ESF MU, forthcoming 5. Hirose, Y., Naganuma, S.: Structural Estimation of the Output Gap: A Bayesian DSGE Approach for the U.S. Economy. Bank of Japan Working Paper Series, no. 7 (2007) 6. Juillard, M.: DYNARE Toolbox for Matlab. ver. 3.65. www.cepremap.cnrs.fr/dynare/ 7. Musil, K., Vašíček, O.: The Czech Economy with Inflation Targeting Represented by DSGE Model: Analysis of Behaviour. Working papers CVKS ESF MU, no. 7. (2005) 8. Remo, A., Vašíček, O.: Monetary policy and stability of Czech economy: optimal commitment policy in NOEM DSGE framework. In Tomeš, Z., Žídek, L.: Determinanty hospodářského rŭstu v zemích východní Evropy. Brno, CVKS ESF MU, 409-460 (2008) 9. Woodford, M.: Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey (2003)