ON THE FOUR-PARAMETER BOND PRICING MODEL. Man M. Chawla X-027, Regency Park II, DLF City Phase IV Gurgaon , Haryana, INDIA

Similar documents
25. Interest rates models. MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, References for this Lecture:

A THREE-FACTOR CONVERGENCE MODEL OF INTEREST RATES

LIBOR Convexity Adjustments for the Vasiček and Cox-Ingersoll-Ross models

Lecture 18. More on option pricing. Lecture 18 1 / 21

Interest rate models in continuous time

European call option with inflation-linked strike

THE USE OF NUMERAIRES IN MULTI-DIMENSIONAL BLACK- SCHOLES PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Hyong-chol O *, Yong-hwa Ro **, Ning Wan*** 1.

NUMERICAL METHODS OF PARTIAL INTEGRO-DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS FOR OPTION PRICE

SYLLABUS. IEOR E4728 Topics in Quantitative Finance: Inflation Derivatives

Lecture 2 - Calibration of interest rate models and optimization

Market interest-rate models

Lecture 1. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. No tutorials in the first week

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Estimating Maximum Smoothness and Maximum. Flatness Forward Rate Curve

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

MODELLING 1-MONTH EURIBOR INTEREST RATE BY USING DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS WITH UNCERTAINTY

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

Lecture 5: Review of interest rate models

The Riccati Equation in Mathematical Finance

Convexity Theory for the Term Structure Equation

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

The Term Structure of Interest Rates under Regime Shifts and Jumps

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

Fixed Income and Risk Management

Affine term structures for interest rate models

Derivatives Options on Bonds and Interest Rates. Professor André Farber Solvay Business School Université Libre de Bruxelles

The Lognormal Interest Rate Model and Eurodollar Futures

Crashcourse Interest Rate Models

The Yield Envelope: Price Ranges for Fixed Income Products

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Option Valuation with Sinusoidal Heteroskedasticity

Averaged bond prices for Fong-Vasicek and the generalized Vasicek interest rates models

Estimation of dynamic term structure models

Equilibrium Term Structure Models. c 2008 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University Page 854

MARKET VALUATION OF CASH BALANCE PENSION BENEFITS

Introduction to Affine Processes. Applications to Mathematical Finance

Discrete time interest rate models

Option Pricing Model with Stepped Payoff

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Instantaneous Error Term and Yield Curve Estimation

Fixed-Income Options

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

An Equilibrium Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates

The Fixed Income Valuation Course. Sanjay K. Nawalkha Natalia A. Beliaeva Gloria M. Soto

CALIBRATION OF THE HULL-WHITE TWO-FACTOR MODEL ISMAIL LAACHIR. Premia 14

A new Loan Stock Financial Instrument

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation

Foreign Exchange Derivative Pricing with Stochastic Correlation

1 The Hull-White Interest Rate Model

Claudia Dourado Cescato 1* and Eduardo Facó Lemgruber 2

Shape of the Yield Curve Under CIR Single Factor Model: A Note

The Binomial Model. The analytical framework can be nicely illustrated with the binomial model.

Shape of the Yield Curve Under CIR Single Factor Model: A Note

(1) Consider a European call option and a European put option on a nondividend-paying stock. You are given:

APPROXIMATE FORMULAE FOR PRICING ZERO-COUPON BONDS AND THEIR ASYMPTOTIC ANALYSIS

Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation

AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL

Homework Assignments

Barrier Option Pricing Formulae for Uncertain Currency Model

TEACHING NOTE 97-02: OPTION PRICING USING FINITE DIFFERENCE METHODS

TEACHING NOTE 00-03: MODELING ASSET PRICES AS STOCHASTIC PROCESSES II. is non-stochastic and equal to dt. From these results we state the following:

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pr] 23 Feb 2014

Risk of Default in Latin American Brady Bonds

Using of stochastic Ito and Stratonovich integrals derived security pricing

Investigation of Dependency between Short Rate and Transition Rate on Pension Buy-outs. Arık, A. 1 Yolcu-Okur, Y. 2 Uğur Ö. 2

Multi-dimensional Term Structure Models

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

1.1 Implied probability of default and credit yield curves

P2.T5. Tuckman Chapter 9. Bionic Turtle FRM Video Tutorials. By: David Harper CFA, FRM, CIPM

Numerical Solution of BSM Equation Using Some Payoff Functions

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

INSTITUTE OF ACTUARIES OF INDIA

Jaime Frade Dr. Niu Interest rate modeling

Lecture 1: Stochastic Volatility and Local Volatility

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications

ONE NUMERICAL PROCEDURE FOR TWO RISK FACTORS MODELING

A distributed Laplace transform algorithm for European options

3 Department of Mathematics, Imo State University, P. M. B 2000, Owerri, Nigeria.

Polynomial Algorithms for Pricing Path-Dependent Interest Rate Instruments

1 The continuous time limit

Continuous time; continuous variable stochastic process. We assume that stock prices follow Markov processes. That is, the future movements in a

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Dynamic pricing with diffusion models

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Monte Carlo Methods for Uncertainty Quantification

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Mathematics in Finance

THE BLACK-SCHOLES FORMULA AND THE GREEK PARAMETERS FOR A NONLINEAR BLACK-SCHOLES EQUATION

Cash Balance Plans: Valuation and Risk Management Cash Balance Plans: Valuation and Risk Management

MATH 4512 Fundamentals of Mathematical Finance

The stochastic calculus

Calibration of Interest Rates

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 2 Solutions

Valuation of Defaultable Bonds Using Signaling Process An Extension

Transcription:

International Journal of Applied Mathematics Volume 29 No. 1 216, 53-68 ISSN: 1311-1728 printed version); ISSN: 1314-86 on-line version) doi: http://dx.doi.org/1.12732/ijam.v29i1.5 ON THE FOUR-PARAMETER BOND PRICING MODEL Man M. Chawla X-27, Regency Park II, DLF City Phase IV Gurgaon-1222, Haryana, INDIA Abstract: A four-parameter random walk model for the short rate of interest is described in Wilmott et al. [15]. For pricing zero-coupon bonds from the resulting partial differential equation based on this short rate model, a certain form of solution requires the solution of two first-order nonlinear ordinary differential equations. In the present paper we show the interesting result that, for obtaining solutions of the bond pricing equation, neither of these two equations requires any differential equation solving techniques; in fact, both these first-order nonlinear differential equations can be solved simply by elementary integration. We include the corresponding yield curve and its asymptotic behavior. We identify our results obtained here for the general four-parameter model in the two special cases of Vasicek [14] and Cox, Ingersoll and Ross [4] with those given by these authors. AMS Subject Classification: 91B24, 91B28, 91B3 Key Words: four-parameter short rate model, bond pricing equation, general solution, yield curve, Vasicek model, Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model 1. Introduction The first short rate model for the evolution of interest rates was proposed by Vasicek [14], and since then various short rate models have been suggested with various degrees of generalizations. Received: November 9, 215 c 216 Academic Publications

54 M.M. Chawla by Vasicek model [14] is a three constant-parameter short rate model described dr = ab r)dt+σdx, 1.1) where a, b and σ are constants, σ is volatility of interest rate and dx is a Wiener process drawn from a normal distribution with mean zero and variance dt. While the drift term indicates Vasicek model incorporates mean reversion, however under Vasicek model it is possible for interest rates to become negative. To fix this shortcoming of Vasicek model, Cox, Ingersoll and Ross [4] extended Vasicek model and proposed for the short rate the following stochastic differential equation: dr = ab r)dt+σ rdx. 1.2) While, like Vasicek model, Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model has mean reversion, however σ r in volatility term helps prevent interest rates becoming negative or zero. A general treatment is given by Maghsoodi [12] and consistency of the model with an input term structure of interest rates is given by Brigo and Mercurio [2]. Another weakness of the Vasicek model is that while the model produces a term structure as an output but it does not accept today s term structure as input. In the solution of initial-value problems for differential equations, of the many solutions possible, the one that is relevant and useful is the one that also satisfies the initial condition. Likewise in financial mathematics of interest rates and bond pricing, the one solution of the bond pricing equation that is relevant and useful is the one that incorporates today s term structure into the bond pricing model. The first such model was proposed by Ho and Lee [6] with the short rate model: dr = θt)dt+σdx, 1.3) with σ a constant and θt) is a time-dependent parameter which is utilized to fit exactly today s term structure into the Ho-Lee model of pricing zero-coupon bonds. Later, Hull and White [9], by combining the ideas of Vasicek and Ho and Lee, considered an extended Vasicek model with the short rate model: dr = [θt) ar]dt+σdx. 1.4) Again, as in the Ho-Lee model, the time dependent parameter θt) is utilized to fit today s term structure of interest rates in the bond pricing model. For more discussion of interest rate models and pricing of interest rate derivative securities, see Black, Derman and Toy [1]. Duffie and Kan [5], Hughston [7], Hull [8], Klugman [1] and Klugman and Wilmott [11].

ON THE FOUR-PARAMETER BOND PRICING MODEL 55 We consider a four-parameter random walk model for the short rate of interest as described, for example, in Wilmott et al. [15]. For pricing zero-coupon bonds from the resulting partial differential equation based on this short rate model, a certain form of solution requires the solution of two first-order nonlinear ordinary differential equations. In the present paper we show the interesting result that, for obtaining solutions of the bond pricing equation, neither of these two equations requires any differential equation solving techniques; in fact, both these first-order nonlinear differential equations can be solved simply by elementary integration. We include the corresponding yield curve and its asymptotic behavior. We identify our results obtained here for the general four-parameter model in the two special cases of Vasicek [14] and Cox, Ingersoll and Ross [4] with those given by these authors. 2. The Four-Parameter Model We consider the four-parameter random walk model for the short term rate of interest described by the stochastic differential equation: where dr = ur,t)dt+wr,t)dx, 2.1) wr,t) = r β, ur,t) = η γr)+λwr,t). 2.2) We are concerned with the pricing of zero-coupon bonds with this fourparameter short rate model. Let Bt,T) denote the value of a zero-coupon bond at time t with maturity T, t < T, and value on maturity BT,T) = Z. Though interest rates are random, for a known interest rate, Bt,T) = BT,T)e T t rs)ds. 2.3) As a measure of future interest rates, the yield curve is defined by Y t,t) = 1 ) Bt,T) T t ln, 2.4) BT,T) and then the interest rate implied by the yield curve is given by rt,t) = d dt [Y t,t)t t)]. 2.5) The bond pricing equation providing values of zero-coupon bonds Bt, T), at time t < T, is B t + 1 2 r β) 2 B B +η γr) rb =. 2.6) r2 r

56 M.M. Chawla Note that λ does not appear in the bond pricing equation 2.6). It will be helpful to introduce time to expiry τ = T t and set an f t,t) = f T t) = f τ). We seek a solution of the bond pricing equation 2.6) in the form: B t,t) = Ze At,T) rct,t). 2.7) This leads to two first-order nonlinear ordinary differential equations for the determination of the functions Aτ) and Bτ): daτ) dτ = ηcτ) 1 2 βc2 τ), 2.8) and dcτ) = 1 dτ 2 C2 τ) γcτ)+1, 2.9) with now the initial conditions A) = and C) =. We note here that Chawla[3] solved2.9) by first homogenizing the equation and then solving it as a Bernoulli equation with index two. Shreve [13], page 285, first transforms the first-order nonlinear equation 2.9), using an exponential transformation, into a second order linear ordinary differential equation from whose solution is recovered the solution of 2.9). Even though both 2.8) and 2.9) are nonlinear differential equations, no special differential equation solving techniques are needed; in fact, both these equations can be solved simply by elementary integration as we show in the following. 3. Solution of the Bond Pricing Equation We first consider solution of the nonlinear differential equation 2.9). For >, we can write 2.9) as dc C 2 + 2γ C 2 = 1 2 dτ. Factorizing the quadratic expression in the denominator, we get where we have set dc C a)c +b) = 1 2 dτ, ψ = γ 2 +2, a = γ +ψ, b = γ +ψ.

ON THE FOUR-PARAMETER BOND PRICING MODEL 57 Partial fractioning gives 1 C a 1 ) dc = 1 a+b)dτ = ψdτ, C +b 2 since a+b = 2ψ. Integrating we have C a C +b = k 1e, for a constant k 1. Applying the initial condition C) = we have k 1 = a therefore ) C a a C +b = e. b Solving for C we have C b+ae ) = ab 1 e ). Since ab = 2, we obtain the solution of 2.9) as 1 e Cτ) = 2 b+ae. 3.1) We next consider the solution of 2.8). With the initial condition A) =, integrating 2.8) from to τ we have where we have set IC) = Aτ) = ηic) 1 2 βi C 2), 3.2) Cu)du, I C 2) = C 2 u)du. First consider evaluation of IC). With 3.1) this can be written as IC) = 2 = 2 1 e ψu b+ae ψudu e ψu be ψu +a du 2 e ψu b+ae ψu du. Performing the two integrations we get IC) = 2 be ψτ ) bψ ln +a + 2 b+ae b+a aψ ln b+a ). b,

58 M.M. Chawla This can be written as IC) = 2 bψ = 2 b τ + 2 ψ [ b+ae ψτ +ln b+a 1 b + 1 a ) ln )] + 2 b+ae b+a b+ae aψ ln b+a ). ) Since 1 1 = b ψ +γ = ψ γ 2 = a 2, 1 b + 1 a = a+b = 2ψ/ ab 2/ = ψ, therefore IC) = aτ + 2 ln b+ae b+a ). 3.3) For the evaluation of I C 2), substituting for C 2 u) from the differential equation in 2.9) we have I C 2) = 2 [ ] dcu) +γcu) 1. du With the initial condition C) =, we get I C 2) = 2 [Cτ)+γI C) τ]. 3.4) Substituting from 3.3) and 3.4) into 3.2) we have Aτ) = ηi C)+ β [Cτ)+γI C) τ] = η + βγ ) IC)+ β Cτ) τ) = η + βγ )[aτ + 2 b+ae ln b+a )] + β Cτ) τ), from which we finally obtain ) δa β Aτ) = τ + β ) 2δ b+ae Cτ)+ 2 ln, 3.5) b+a δ = βγ η.

ON THE FOUR-PARAMETER BOND PRICING MODEL 59 Thus, for the four-parameter model price of a zero-coupon bond is given by 2.7) with Cτ) and Aτ) given by 3.1) and 3.5). With the values of Aτ) and Cτ) given by 3.5) and 3.1), from 2.4) the yield curve for the four-parameter bond pricing model is given by Since Y t,t) = 1 τ [Aτ) rcτ)] ) β δa = 1 [ ) β τ r Cτ)+ 2δ b+ae )] 2 ln. 3.6) b+a lim τ Cτ) = 2 b ) ) b+ae b and lim ln = ln, τ b+a b+a it is clear that asymptotic τ ) behavior of the yield curve for the fourparameter model is ) β δa Y t,t). 3.7) This is positive if β > δa. 3.1. Solution for the Vasicek Case We next consider the special case of Vasicek model [14] which corresponds to random walk for the short rate 2.1)-2.2) with =. For = equation 2.9) simplifies to dc γc 1 = dτ. Integrating we get γc 1 = k 2 e γτ. The initial condition C) = gives k 2 = 1, and the solution now called C V τ) is, for γ >, C V τ) = 1 e γτ γ. 3.8) Next, for the solution of 2.8) with the initial condition A) =, integrating from to τ the solution now called A V τ) is given as A V τ) = ηic V ) 1 2 βi C 2 V). 3.9)

6 M.M. Chawla Note that with = from 2.9) we have C V = 1 γ With 3.1) we immediately have I C V ) = Again, with 3.1) we obtain C V u)du = 1 γ I CV 2 ) τ = CV 2 u)du = 1 γ = 1 γ With 3.12) from 3.9) we get 1 dc V dτ ). 3.1) 1 dc ) V u) du du = 1 γ τ C V τ)). 3.11) [ IC V ) 1 2 C2 V τ) A V τ) = ηic V ) β 2γ = η + β 2γ C V u) 1 dc ) V u) du du ]. 3.12) [ IC V ) 1 ] 2 C2 V τ) ) IC V )+ β 4γ C2 V τ). Substituting for I C V ) from 3.11) we finally get A V τ) = 1 η + β ) [C V τ) τ]+ β γ 2γ 4γ C2 V τ). 3.13) Thus, for the Vasicek model the price of a zero-coupon bond is given by 2.7) where C V τ) and A V τ) are given by 3.8) and 3.13). The yield curve for the Vasicek model is Since = 1 γ Y V t,t) = 1 τ [A V τ) rc V τ)] η + β )[ 1 C ] V τ) β CV 2 τ) + r 2γ τ 4γ τ τ C V τ). 3.14) lim C V τ) = 1 τ γ,

ON THE FOUR-PARAMETER BOND PRICING MODEL 61 asymptotic behavior of the Vasicek yield curve is Y V t,t) 1 η + β ). 3.15) γ 2γ If, in addition to =, we set γ = we have the Ho and Lee [6] model of short rate 1.3) with a constant θ. We denote the corresponding results by a subscript HL. Now, with = γ =, integrating 2.9) from to τ with the initial condition C) = we have C HL τ) = du = τ, while integration of 2.8) with the initial condition A) = gives A HL τ) = η = 1 2 ητ2 1 6 βτ3, and the yield curve for the Ho-Lee model is udu 1 2 β u 2 du Y HL t,t) = 1 τ [A HLτ) rc HL τ)] = r + 1 2 ητ + 1 6 βτ2. In order that the yield remains finite for τ we must have, in addition, η = and β =, implying an asymptotic yield with constant rate of interest: Y HL t,t) r. 3.2. Solution for the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross Case The special case of Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model [4] corresponds to random walk for the short rate 2.1)-2.2) with β =. Now, we need not perform any new calculations and the results for this case can simply be obtained by substituting β = in our general four-parameter model. We denote the corresponding results by putting a subscript CIR. Note that solution of 2.9) remains the same as obtained in 3.1), thus 1 e C CIR τ) = 2 b+ae. 3.16)

62 M.M. Chawla With β =, from 3.5) we have A CIR τ) = η [aτ + 2 )] b+ae ln. 3.17) b+a From 3.6), with β =, the yield curve for the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model is Y CIR t,t) = ηa+ 1 τ [rc CIR τ)+ 2η ln b+ae b+a )], 3.18) with asymptotic value Y CIR t,t) ηa. 3.19) 3.3. Behavior of the Price of a Zero-Coupon Bond We show here analytically that the value of a zero-coupon bond Bt,T) decreases steadily, subject to variation in the value of rt), from its value Z at maturity T down to a value at time t. For >, from 3.1) Cτ) >. If =, from 3.8) C V τ) > for γ > ; if in addition γ =, then C HL τ) >. So, Cτ) is always positive. Now, from 2.8) for η > and β, da dτ <. Since A) = it follows that Aτ) is negative for τ > and that Aτ) monotonically increases negatively with τ increasing. As for Cτ), we may write 2.9), as in Section 3, as dcτ) dτ = 1 a C)C +b). 2 For >, clearly C +b >. For a C, with 3.1) we can write it as where we have set 1 e a C = a 2 b+ae Num = b+ae, Num = ab+a 2 e 2 1 e ). Since ab = 2, Num = a 2 + 2 ) e.

ON THE FOUR-PARAMETER BOND PRICING MODEL 63 Now, a 2 = 1 2 ψ 2 +γ 2 2γψ ), and substituting for ψ 2, a 2 = 2 γψ γ)) 2 = 2 1 γa). Therefore, Num = 2 2 γa)e. Again, since we get 2 γψ γ) 2 γa = = ψ2 γψ = ψa, Num = 2 ψae. We thus obtain a C = 2 ψa e b+ae. This shows that a C > for >. So, for >, dc dτ > implying that Cτ) monotonically increases with τ increasing. For =, for γ > from 3.8) we have dc V /dτ = e γτ ; if in addition γ =, then dc HL /dτ = 1, implying that in both these cases also Cτ) with τ. We have thus shown that in all cases Aτ) steadily increases negatively and Cτ) steadily increases positively with τ increasing. It follows that the price of a zero-coupon bond Bt,T) in the four-parameter model given by 2.7) decreases steadily, subject to variation in the value of rt), from its value Z at maturity to a value at time t. 4. Identification of Results in Two Special Cases For special cases of the four-parameter random walk 2.1)-2.2), solutions of the bond pricing equation have been given using different notations with different

64 M.M. Chawla forms of solution. In this section we identify our results obtained here for the general four-parameter model in the two special cases of Vasicek [14] and Cox- Ingersoll-Ross [4] with those given by these authors. We note that alternatively bond price is written as P t,t) = At,T)e rbt,t). So, in our notation, with Z = 1, this corresponds to our Bt,T) P t,t), At,T) lnat,t), Ct,T) Bt,T). Now, the Vasicek short rate model 1.1), in our notation corresponds to =, β = σ 2, γ = a, η = ab. From equation 3.8) with γ = a we have C V τ) = 1 e aτ a Again, from 3.13), switching to the above notation, we get A V τ) = 1 ) ab σ2 [C V τ) τ] σ2 a 2a 4a C2 V τ). These results agree with those given for the Vasicek model in Hull [8]. If in addition a =, then from the results following equation 3.15), with η = ab = we have C HL τ) = τ, A HL τ) = σ2 6 τ3, which agree with the results given in Hull [8]. Next, the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross short rate model 1.2), in our notation corresponds to β =, = σ 2, η = ab, γ = a, ψ γ = a 2 +2σ 2, b = γ +a σ 2, a = γ a σ 2. Switching to the above notation, from 3.16) we have C CIR τ) = 2 1 e γτ σ 2 b+ae γτ 2e γτ 1) = γ +a)e γτ 1)+2γ..

ON THE FOUR-PARAMETER BOND PRICING MODEL 65 From 3.17) we have A CIR τ) = η [aτ + 2 b+ae ln b+a )]. Combining the two terms in square brackets, this can be written as A CIR τ) = 2η ln be ψτ ) +a. 2 = ψ+γ 2 b+a)e ψ a/2)τ Since ψ a, and simplifying we get A CIR τ) = 2η ψ +γ) e ψτ ln 1 ) ) +2ψ = 2ψe ψ+γ)/2)τ 2ψe ψ+γ)/2)τ ψ +γ)e ψτ 1)+2ψ Finally switching to the above notation we have 2γe γ+a)τ/2 A CIR τ) = γ +a)e γτ 1)+2γ )2η. ) 2ab/σ 2 These results for the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model agree with those given in Hull [8]. 4.1. The Case of Fitting Initial Yield We also include identification of results obtained in Chawla [3] with those of Ho and Lee model [6] and the extended Vasicek model of Hull and White [9] in the case of fitting today s yield to the four-parameter model with short rate 2.1)-2.2) for the case =. The idea is to treat η as a function of time and utilize it to fit today s at t = ) term structure of interest rates into the bond pricing model. For the purpose, write equation 3.2) as At,T) = where from 3.11) and 3.12), T I CV 2 ) 1 = γ ηs)c V s,t)ds 1 2 βi C 2 V), 4.1) [ 1 γ τ C V τ)) 1 ] 2 C2 V τ)..

66 M.M. Chawla Fitting today s yield from 2.4): to 4.1) we can write Y,T) = 1 T A,T) r)c,t)), where we have set T ηs)c V s,t)ds = F T), 4.2) F T) = TY,T) r)c V,T) 1 2 βi C 2 V). We solve 4.2) for η = ηt) and get the corresponding A = A t,t) from 4.1). From Chawla [3] we have with minor correction): C V τ) = 1 e γτ γ η t) = d dt r,t)+γr,t) 1 2 βc V,t) 1+e γt), 4.3) and, with the simplification: that C 2 V τ) {C V,T) C V,t)} 2 = C 2 V τ) 1 e 2γτ), A t,t) = f,t,t)τ +r,t)c V τ)+ β 4γ C2 V τ) 1 e 2γτ). 4.4) Note that r,t) = F,t) is forward rate at time t and f,t,t) is the forward yield which with 2.4) can be written as Y,T)T Y,t)t f,t,t) = T t = 1 ) B,T) τ ln. B,t) For the Ho and Lee model [4], since C HL τ) = τ and 1 e 2γt) lim = 2t, γ γ,

ON THE FOUR-PARAMETER BOND PRICING MODEL 67 from 4.3) and 4.4) we get and θ t) = d dt r,t)+σ2 t, A t,t) = f,t,t)τ +r,t)c HL τ) σ2 2 tτ2. These results agree with those given for the Ho and Lee model in Hull [8]. For the extended Vasicek model of Hull and White [9], from 4.3) and 4.4), with C V τ) = 1 e aτ a, we have and θ t) = d σ2 r,t)+ar,t)+ dt 2 C V,t) 1+e at), A t,t) = f,t,t)τ +r,t)c V τ) σ2 4a C2 V τ) 1 e 2at). These results agree with those given for the extended Vasicek model of Hull and White in Hull [8]. References [1] F. Black, E. Derman and W. Toy, A one-factor model of interest rates and its application to treasury bond options, Financial Analysts Journal, 46 199), 33-39. [2] D. Brigo and F. Mercurio, A deterministic-shift extension of analytically tractable and time-homogeneous short rate models, Finance and Stochastics, 5 21), 369-388. [3] M. M. Chawla, On solutions of the bond pricing equation, Internat. J. Appl. Math., 23 21), 661-68. [4] J.C. Cox, J.E. Ingersoll and S.A. Ross, A theory of the term structure of interest rates, Econometrica, 53 1985), 385-47. [5] D. Duffie and R. Kan, A yield-factor model of interest rates, Mathematical Finance, 64 1996), 379-46. [6] T.S. Ho and S.B. Lee, Term structure movements and pricing interest rate contingent claims, Journal of Finance, 41 1986), 1129-1142.

68 M.M. Chawla [7] L. Hughston, Ed., Vasicek and Beyond: Approaches to Building and Applying Interest Rate Models, Risk Books, London, 1997. [8] J.C. Hull, Options, Futures and Other Derivative Securities, 6th Ed., Prentice-Hall, New York, 25. [9] J. Hull and A. White, Pricing interest rate derivative securities, The Review of Financial Studies, 4 199), 573-592. [1] R. Klugman, Interest rate modelling, OCIAM Working Paper, Mathematical Institute, Oxford University, 1992. [11] R. Klugman and P. Wilmott, A four parameter model for interest rates, OCIAM Working Paper, Mathematical Institute, Oxford University, 1993. [12] Y. Maghsoodi, Solution of the extended CIR term structure and bond option valuation, Mathematical Finance, 6 1996), 89-19. [13] S.E. Shreve, Stochastic Calculus for Finance II: Continuous-Time Models, Springer Intern. Ed., 3rd Indian Reprint, New Delhi, 214. [14] O. Vasicek, An equilibrium characterization of the term structure, Journal of Financial Economics, 5 1977), 177-188. [15] P. Wilmott, S. Howison and J. Dewynne, The Mathematics of Financial Derivatives: A Student Introduction, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1995.