Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

Similar documents
Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06. Chapter 11 Models of Asset Dynamics (1)

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

Homework Assignments

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

MORNING SESSION. Date: Wednesday, April 30, 2014 Time: 8:30 a.m. 11:45 a.m. INSTRUCTIONS TO CANDIDATES

Lecture 3. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6

INVESTMENTS Class 2: Securities, Random Walk on Wall Street

Value at Risk Ch.12. PAK Study Manual

(1) Consider a European call option and a European put option on a nondividend-paying stock. You are given:

3.1 Itô s Lemma for Continuous Stochastic Variables

The stochastic calculus

Probability in Options Pricing

Seminar 2 A Model of the Behavior of Stock Prices. Miloslav S. Vosvrda UTIA AV CR

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Simulation Analysis of Option Buying

1 Geometric Brownian motion

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 2 Solutions

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

The Black-Scholes Model

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

The Black-Scholes Model

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

1 The continuous time limit

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Lattice (Binomial Trees) Version 1.2

Financial Engineering and Structured Products

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Errata, Mahler Study Aids for Exam 3/M, Spring 2010 HCM, 1/26/13 Page 1

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

CHAPTER 5 ELEMENTARY STOCHASTIC CALCULUS. In all of these X(t) is Brownian motion. 1. By considering X 2 (t), show that

Modeling Uncertainty in Financial Markets

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

WITH SKETCH ANSWERS. Postgraduate Certificate in Finance Postgraduate Certificate in Economics and Finance

FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

MS-E2114 Investment Science Exercise 10/2016, Solutions

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Deriving and Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Ornstein-Uhlenbeck Theory

Market interest-rate models

Financial Risk Management

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

Version A. Problem 1. Let X be the continuous random variable defined by the following pdf: 1 x/2 when 0 x 2, f(x) = 0 otherwise.

Question from Session Two

Market Volatility and Risk Proxies

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

One note for Session Two

Non-semimartingales in finance

Stochastic Calculus - An Introduction

Monte Carlo Simulation of Stochastic Processes

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing?

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

Continuous Processes. Brownian motion Stochastic calculus Ito calculus

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

Risk Neutral Valuation

"Pricing Exotic Options using Strong Convergence Properties

Asset Price Dynamics and Related Topics

STEX s valuation analysis, version 0.0

Logarithmic derivatives of densities for jump processes

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Computational Finance

2.1 Mathematical Basis: Risk-Neutral Pricing

Introduction Taylor s Theorem Einstein s Theory Bachelier s Probability Law Brownian Motion Itô s Calculus. Itô s Calculus.

Geometric Brownian Motions

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

Forecasting Life Expectancy in an International Context

Ch 1. Wiener Process (Brownian Motion)

Continuous time; continuous variable stochastic process. We assume that stock prices follow Markov processes. That is, the future movements in a

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility

The Black-Scholes Equation

Lattice Model of System Evolution. Outline

Partial differential approach for continuous models. Closed form pricing formulas for discretely monitored models

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

King s College London

Hedging Errors for Static Hedging Strategies

13.3 A Stochastic Production Planning Model

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Stochastic Processes and Brownian Motion

Transcription:

Dr. Maddah ENMG 65 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06 Chapter 11 Models of Asset Dynamics () Random Walk A random process, z, is an additive process defined over times t 0, t 1,, t k, t k+1,, such that z( t ) = z( t ) + ε t, k + 1 k + 1 k k t = t + t, k where ε k are iid standard normal r.vs. and z(t 0 ) = 0. For j < k, k 1 z( t ) z( t ) = ε ( t ) t. k j i i= j Therefore, z(t k ) z(t j ) is a normal r.v. with mean 0 and variance k 1 k 1 t var[ ε ( t )] = t = t t. i k j i= j i= j The two random variables z(t k ) z(t j ) and z(t m ) z(t l ), with j < k < l < m, are independent. Brownian motion The limit of a random walk as t 0 is a Brownian motion (or a Wiener process). A Brownian motion is represented symbolically as dz = ε ( t) dt, where ε(t) are iid standard normal r.v. 1

A more rigorous approach is to define a Brownian motion as a stochastic process z(t) that satisfies the following: 1. For any s < t, z(t) z(s) is a normal r.v. with mean 0 and variance t s.. For any z(t ) z(t 1 ) 0 t 1 < t < t 3 < t 4, z(t ) z(t 1 ) and z(t 4 ) z(t 3 ) are independent. 3. Pr{z(0) = 0} = 1. A Brownian motion is not differentiable in time since z( s) z( t) E[( z( s) z( t)) ] 1 E = =, as s t. s t ( s t) s t However, the term dz/dt is utilized and is termed white noise.

Generalized Wiener process A generalized Wiener process is a stochastic process x(t) such that dx( t) = adt + bdz, where z is a Brownian motion, and a and b are constants. Integration gives Ito Process x( t) = x(0) + at + bz( t). This is even more general. It s defined by dx( t) = a( x( t), t) dt + b( x( t), t) dz. No closed-form expression for x(t) exists in general. 3

Lemma (Ito s lemma) Let x(t) be an Ito process. Define the process y(t)=f(x(t), t). Then, F( x, t) F( x, t) 1 F( x, t) F( x, t) dy( t) = a( x, t) + + ( b( x, t)) dt b( x, t) dz. + x t x x Proof. The proof follows by noting that y(t) is obtained from Taylor s series expansion of F(x(t), t) up to first order on t and second order on x. (This is the case since dx is function of dz, which is of the order t ). f x t t f x t t f x t t y( t) = x( t) + t + ( x( t)) ( ( ), ) ( ( ), ) 1 ( ( ), ) x( t) t x ( t) f x t t f x t t f x t t = ( a t + b z) + t + ( a t + b z) ( ( ), ) ( ( ), ) 1 ( ( ), ) x( t) t x ( t) f ( x( t), t) f ( x( t), t) 1 = ( a t + z) + t + x( t) t f x t t x ( t) The result then follows by taking the limit as t 0 lim z = lim ( ε ( t)) t = t 1. that ( ) t 0 t 0 ( ( ), ) [ a ( t ) + ab t z + b ( z ) ] and noting Remark. For a two-variable function f(x, t), the second-order Taylor s series expansion is F( x, t) F( x, t) F( x + x, t + t) = F( x, t) + x + t x t 1 F( x, t) F( x, t) 1 F( x, t) 3 + ( x) + x t + ( t) + O ( x, t), x x t t 3 lim ( x, t) (0,0) O ( t, x) / t + x = 0. Therefore, where ( ) F( x, t) = F( x + x, t + t) F( x, t) F( x, t) F( x, t) 1 F( x, t) F( x, t) 1 F( x, t) x+ t+ x + x t+ t x t x x t t ( ) ( ) 1 An intuitive explanation of this is that (ε(t)) t is a chi-square r.v. with mean t and variance t. 4

Geometric Brownian motion This is the preferred stock price model. It is a continuous version of the multiplicative model defined by the following differential equation on the stock price, S(t), d ln( S( t)) = ν dt + σ dz, where v and σ 0 are constants, and z is a Brownian motion. S(t) is a special case of a generalized Wiener process. Integrating the differential equation gives ln( S( t)) = ln( S(0)) + ν t + σ z( t). Therefore, ln(s(t)) is a normal r.v. with mean ln S(0) + vt and variance σ t. It follows that the stock price S(t) is a lognormal r.v. with parameters S(0) + vt and σ t. Then, E S t e e S e S e E[ln( S ( t )] + var[ln( S ( t)]/ ln( S (0)) + vt+ σ t / ( v+ σ / ) t µ t [ ( )] = = = (0) = (0), stdev S t e e S e e E[ln( S ( t)] + var[ln( S ( t )]/ var[ln( S ( t )] 1/ µ t σ t 1/ [ ( )] = ( 1) = (0) ( 1), where µ v σ / +. Note that the parameter µ can be seen as the expected rate of return for the stock (assuming continuous compounding). The parameter σ is known as the stock price volatility. 5

Geometric Brownian motion in standard Ito form Ito s lemma allows us to determine a differential equation that S(t) satisfies. Note that S(t) = F(x(t), t) = e x(t), where x(t) = ln(s(t)) and dx( t) = νdt + σdz. Note that F( x, t) x( t) F( x, t) x( t) F( x, t) = e, = e, and = 0. x x t Then, Ito s lemma implies that F ( x, t) F( x, t) 1 F( x, t) F( x, t) ds( t) = v + + σ dt σdz + x t x x ( 0 ( σ / ) ) ( ( σ / ) ) ( σ ) = + + + σ x( t) x( t) x( t) ve e dt e dz = + + σ ln( S ( t)) ln( S ( t)) ln( S ( t )) ve e dt e dz = vs( t) + ( / ) S( t) dt + σ S( t) dz. This is the geometric Brownian motion in standard Ito form, ds( t) ds( t) = µ S( t) dt + σ S( t) dz = µ dt + σ dz. S( t) This form provide further justification for seeing µ and σ as the expected ROR of and volatility of the stock. This follows since in a small time t the relative (%) change in the stock price is a normal r.v. with mean µ t and variance σ t. Similar to the multiplicative (discrete time), the change in the relative percent return is independent of price level. 6

Simulating Geometric Brownian motion There are two ways. Both require a long series of small time periods defined by t 0, t 1,, where t k+1 t k = t. The first method utilizes the standard Ito form and proceed to generating a sample path from the equation S( t ) S( t ) = µ S( t ) t + σ S( t ) z = µ S( t ) t + σ S( t ) ε ( t ) t k+ 1 k k k k k k ( µ σε ) S( t ) = S( t ) 1 + t + ( t ) t k+ 1 k k where S(t 0 ) = S 0. The second method works on the differential equation of the ln(s(t)) ln( S( t )) ln( S( t )) = v t + σ z = v t + σε ( t ) t k + 1 k k S t = S t e v t+ σε ( tk ) t ( k + 1) ( k ), where S(t 0 ) = S 0. To simulate the standard normal random variables ε(t k ) one may use the inverse transform method where a random variate ˆ( ε t k ) is generated as 1 ˆ( tk ) ( u( tk )) ε = Φ, where u(t k ) is a random number between 0 and 1 and Φ 1 is the inverse of the standard normal cdf. In Excel, A standard normal random variate is generated by the formula =NORMSINV(RAND())., 7

Binomial Lattice Revisited The discrete-value binomial lattice model is similar to the continuous-time multiplicative model. The parameters u, d, and p can be chosen so that the binomial lattice matches the multiplicative model. One fact that supports this matching is that the logarithmic of the stock price under the binomial lattice model follow a binomial distribution. This binomial distribution is a good approximation to the normal distribution for a large number of time intervals. Hence, for a large number of time intervals both models lead to a lognormal stock price distribution. The matching of the two models is done by equating the mean and variance of the stock price logarithm after one period, S 1, assuming that the initial price is S(0) = 1. Let the parameters of the multiplicative model be v and σ, and let t be the time interval. Then, matching leads to E[ln S ] = p ln u + (1 p) ln d = v t, 1 var[ln S1] = p(ln u) + (1 p)(ln d) [ p ln u + (1 p)ln d] = t. Assuming ln d = ln u, and solving for ln u and p gives with σ some approximation 1 1 v σ t σ t p = + t, u = e, d = e. σ Remark. With these parameters, the binomial lattice model approximate the geometric Brownian motion for small t. 8