The text book to this class is available at

Similar documents
Financial Economics. A Concise Introduction to Classical and Behavioral Finance Chapter 1. Thorsten Hens and Marc Oliver Rieger

The text book to this class is available at

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights?

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Arrow Debreu Equilibrium. October 31, 2015

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

GE in production economies

Gains from Trade. Rahul Giri

Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Financial Innovation in Segmented Markets

CONVENTIONAL AND UNCONVENTIONAL MONETARY POLICY WITH ENDOGENOUS COLLATERAL CONSTRAINTS

Unemployment equilibria in a Monetary Economy

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

ECON 581. Introduction to Arrow-Debreu Pricing and Complete Markets. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Financial Economics: Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing in General Equilibrium c

1 Dynamic programming

Game Theory Fall 2003

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

Introduction to Game Theory Evolution Games Theory: Replicator Dynamics

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

Economia Financiera Avanzada

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 3

A. Introduction to choice under uncertainty 2. B. Risk aversion 11. C. Favorable gambles 15. D. Measures of risk aversion 20. E.

You may not start to read the questions printed on the subsequent pages of this question paper until instructed that you may do so by the Invigilator

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

Inflation. David Andolfatto

9 D/S of/for Labor. 9.1 Demand for Labor. Microeconomics I - Lecture #9, April 14, 2009

ECON Micro Foundations

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

14.05: SECTION HANDOUT #4 CONSUMPTION (AND SAVINGS) Fall 2005

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

Game Theory Fall 2006

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

Slides III - Complete Markets

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

1. Introduction of another instrument of savings, namely, capital

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Volume 29, Issue 3. The Effect of Project Types and Technologies on Software Developers' Efforts

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

Chapter 10: Mixed strategies Nash equilibria, reaction curves and the equality of payoffs theorem

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. Fiscal Policy. Ramsey Taxation. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Competitive Outcomes, Endogenous Firm Formation and the Aspiration Core

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Social Common Capital and Sustainable Development. H. Uzawa. Social Common Capital Research, Tokyo, Japan. (IPD Climate Change Manchester Meeting)

An Entrepreneur s Problem Under Perfect Foresight

Optimal Allocation of Policy Limits and Deductibles

Bargaining and Coalition Formation

Chapter 6: Correcting Market Distortions: Shadow Prices Wages & Discount Rates

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Lecture Notes on The Core

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

Answer Key: Problem Set 4

Equilibrium Corporate Finance: Makowski meets Prescott and Townsend

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

Problem Set: Contract Theory

Problem set Fall 2012.

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

Exercises March 13, 2003

Alternating-Offer Games with Final-Offer Arbitration

Public Information and Effi cient Capital Investments: Implications for the Cost of Capital and Firm Values

Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance

Games of Incomplete Information

General Equilibrium with Risk Loving, Friedman-Savage and other Preferences

Online Appendix for Debt Contracts with Partial Commitment by Natalia Kovrijnykh

COMP331/557. Chapter 6: Optimisation in Finance: Cash-Flow. (Cornuejols & Tütüncü, Chapter 3)

Problem Set: Contract Theory

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Lecture 7. The consumer s problem(s) Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2018 Last updated: April 28, 2018

1 Two Period Production Economy

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Game theory for. Leonardo Badia.

Transcription:

The text book to this class is available at www.springer.com On the book's homepage at www.financial-economics.de there is further material available to this lecture, e.g. corrections and updates.

Financial Economics A Concise Introduction to Classical and Behavioral Finance Chapter 6 Thorsten Hens and Marc Oliver Rieger Swiss Banking Institute, University of Zurich / BWL, University of Trier August 6, 2010 T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 1 / 57

Theory of the Firm The great difference between the industry of today as compared to that of yesterday is what might be referred to as the necessity of the scientific approach, the elimination of operation by hunches. Alfred P. Sloan T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 2 / 57

Theory of the Firm We will now extend the financial economy E F to cover problems of production and production units, i.e. firms. This allows conclusions about the behavior of firms in markets. So far we assumed bond payoffs to be exogenous, ignoring the decision-making process of the bonds issuers. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 3 / 57

Basic Model Basic Model The model builds on the two-period model introduced in Sec. 4.1. In time t = 0 a set of bonds K := {1,..., K} can be traded; in time t = 1 they payoff in dependence of the state of the world. Formally, there are S + 1 states of the world, where s = 0 corresponds to t = 0 and in t = 1 one state s {1,..., S} is realized. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 4 / 57

Basic Model Households and Firms In this chapter we consider two types of economic agents: A set of households I := {1,..., I } (or agents in the narrower sense). A set of firms J := {1,..., J}. A household s main interest lies in consumption. Let X i R S+1 be a set of consumption plans, where x i X i describes agent i s consumption for each state s. Let for a household i the mapping U i : X i R represent its utility. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 5 / 57

Basic Model Households and Firms The firms genuine task is to produce. Each firm j J is characterized by its exogenous production technology Y j R S+1. The net output is denoted by y j := (y j 0,..., y j S ) Yj, where y j s > 0 is the net output of firm j in state s. y j s < 0 is interpreted as the net input. Let Y := j J Yj be the set of all production capabilities and let Y R (S+1) J be a production matrix of the entire economy. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 6 / 57

Basic Model Households and Firms Assumption (Production technology set) We make the following assumptions on the production technology set Y j of a firm: (i) Y j R S+1 is closed, (ii) Y j is convex, (iii) Y j R S+1 0, (iv) Y j R S+1 0 = {0}, (v) for all ω R S+1 0 we have (ω + Y) R 0 S+1 compact. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 7 / 57

Basic Model Households and Firms (i) has only technical character. (ii) implies that the technologies have non-increasing returns to scale. (iii) means on the one hand that 0 R S+1 belongs to the technology of every firm; i.e., it has the option of producing nothing. On the other hand every firm can freely dispose its resources: a given output does not have to be produced with minimal possible input. (iv) is a kind of no arbitrage condition (NAC) for the production: a positive output in one state can only be produced by investing a strictly positive input in another. (v) formalizes the limitations of production: given the resources in an economy, production is bounded; which implies that for any price system q cash-flows are bounded. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 8 / 57

Basic Model Financial Market Both types of economic agents actively participate in the bond market. Let Z i be the set of a household s possible portfolios, i.e., its portfolio space. An element z i := (z1 i,..., zi K ) Zi describes its position on the bond market, where zk i denotes the position for the k-th bond. Let Z := i I Z i be the set of all portfolio spaces. Similarly, we denote by P j R K a firm s portfolio space, with an element ξ j := (ξ j 1,..., ξj K ) Pj. We call a firm s portfolio ξ j its financial policy to distinguish it from a household s portfolio. Let P := j J Pj denote the set of all portfolio spaces. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 9 / 57

Basic Model Financial Market In time t = 0 the set of bonds K := {1,..., K} are traded at some prices q R K. Each bond s payoff can be described by a S K matrix with entries A k s denoting the payoff of bond k in state s. We will distinguish between non-incorporated and incorporated companies. In the context of non-incorporated companies, the agents exogenously hold firm shares, and cannot trade them. On the other hand, in an economy with incorporated companies these shares are tradable on a market. This distinction leads to two variants of the set up. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 10 / 57

Basic Model Financial Market In the benchmark case the financial market A only consists of bonds. Firm shares are held by households who do not sell them. Let δ i = ( δ 1 i,..., δ J i ) RJ 0 denote the initial distribution of firm shares of agent i, where δ j i is its share of firm j. In the case of incorporated companies firm shares are tradeable (in a stock market). The market for firm shares is assumed to be open to both, households and firms. Let H i R J be a household s portfolio space on this market. An element h i = (h i 1,..., hi J ) means that the i-th agent holds hi j shares in the j-th firm. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 11 / 57

Basic Model Financial Market As in the benchmark case, we assume that any household is endowed with some portfolio δ i, which can be sold now. Since there are no transaction costs, we let the agents sell their stocks δ i, and then demand δ i on the market. The firms now may also buy shares of other firms, so that they are connected by cross ownership. We assume they do not hold any such shares at the beginning. Let T j be the set of possible firm shares. As before, T j R J. Let T := j J T j be the set of firm interdependencies. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 12 / 57

Basic Model Financial Market The dependencies can be described from a firm s point of view by vectors τ j = (τ j 1,..., τ j j J ), meaning the j-th firm holds τl shares in the l-th firm. In period t = 0 firm shares are traded at some prices p R J. If traded or not, holding firm shares leads to dividends in both periods. Let the matrix D := (d 1,..., d J ) R (S+1) J describe the dividend of all firms (in any state). Dividends can also be negative which would mean a liability (to subsequent payment). T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 13 / 57

Basic Model Example: Dividend policy Consider a firm j and only two states s = {0, 1}. For a given production decision y j Y j and a given financial policy ξ j P j it might fix the following dividends: ( ) d j = y j q + ξ j A that is d j 0 = y j 0 k K qk ξ j k and d j 1 = y j 1 k K Ak s ξ j k. Differing financial policies determine different dividends, as can be seen in the following cases. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 14 / 57

Basic Model Example: Dividend policy 100% equity finance: ξ j = 0 d j = y j d j 0 = y j 0 complete equity finance d j 1 = y j 1 full risk 100% bonded capital finance: q ξ j = y j 0 ( ) d j = y j q + ξ j d j A 0 = 0 100% risk coverage: Aξ j = y j 1 d j d j 0 = y j 0 q ξ j d j 1 = 0. d j 1 = y j 1 + Aξj T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 15 / 57

Basic Model Financial Economy with Production Definition (Financial Economy with Production E P F ) A financial economy with production E P F (I, X, U, ω, Z, δ, J, Y, P, [H, T ], A) is an economy with (i) I economical agents, their consumption spaces X, utility functions U, initial distributions of goods ω, initial distribution of firm shares δ, portfolio spaces Z (and corresponding firm share portfolios H); (ii) J firms with technologies Y j, portfolio spaces P (and corresponding firm share portfolios T ); (iii) and a financial market A for bonds (and shares). T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 16 / 57

Basic Model Financial Economy with Production We need to restate a few already known concepts in the setting of a financial economy with production. Let φ Y, φ P, and φ T be the corresponding production allocation, financial policy allocation and share allocation (respectively) of the firms. Definition (Achievability) An allocation of goods φ X and a production allocation φ Y are achievable, if (i) x i X i for all i, (ii) y j Y j for all j, (iii) i I (x i ω i ) j J y j. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 17 / 57

Basic Model Budget Restriction / Households Decisions and Firms Decisions At the beginning of the first period, the agents and firms plan all traded and produced quantities for all S + 1 states. This means that at t = 0, not only the production plans for t = 1 have to be set, but in particular their financing has to be guaranteed in advance. This set-up leads to a list of budget restrictions. We will keep the distinction between incorporated and non-incorporated firms, because it plays an important role in the description of the budget restrictions. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 18 / 57

Basic Model Non-Incorporated Companies Since firm shares are not tradeable, households hold just their initial firm shares h i = δ i. At time t = 0, agent i s expenses for consumption x0 i and investment in bonds zk i may not exceed the value of its initial assets ω0 i and its dividends J j=1 d 0 δ j j i from its firm shares, i.e. at t = 0, x0 i + q k zk i ωi 0 + d0 δ j j i. (1) k K j J At t = 1, in a given state s, the agent gains the payoff of its portfolio and the dividends which can all be used for consumption. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 19 / 57

Basic Model Non-Incorporated Companies Hence the budget restriction for t = 1 are xs i ws i + A k s zk i + d j δ s j i. (2) k K j J We combine the two conditions (1) and (2), where the latter shall hold for all states s 1: B i (q, ω i, δ i, A, D) ( (x i, z i ) := X i Z i x i 0 + P k K qk z i k ω i 0 + P j J d j 0 δ i j x i s w i s + P k K Ak s z i k + P j J d j s δ i j, for all s 1 ). T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 20 / 57

Basic Model Non-Incorporated Companies The budget set can also be written in matrix form: { B i (q, ω i, δ i (x, A, D) = i, z i ( ) } ) X i Z i x i ω i q + z i + D δ i. A Therefore, an economic agent i is confronted with the following utility maximization problem: max U i (x) such that (x i, z i ) B i (q, ω i, δ i, A, D). x i X i z i Z i T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 21 / 57

Basic Model Non-Incorporated Companies A firm, on the other hand, should maximize its total profit. Since profits also arise at t = 1 and in different states, they have to be discounted or weighted. In the following, we assign a vector π j R S+1 to every firm j, for which the NAC holds (q k = S s=1 Ak s πs, j for all k; see Th. 4.2). In t = 0, a firm s dividends are restricted by its net production and its actions on the bond market. In t = 1 for any state s 1, the dividends may not exceed the net output and the payoffs from the bond market. Thus, we consider the following maximization problem: ( max π j d j such that d j y j q + A d j R S+1 y j Y j ξ j P j ) ξ i. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 22 / 57

Basic Model Incorporated Companies Households and firms be allowed to trade firm shares at some prices p. The budget restriction of a household i needs to be changed to account for this possibility. At t = 0, agent i has a demand for goods x i 0 and for bonds zi k and shares δ i j. Apart from the initial distribution of goods ω0 i, the sales revenue from the initial distribution and the dividends of its shares limit a household s decisions, i.e., x i 0 + k K q k z i k + j J p j δ i j ω i 0 + j J d j 0 δi j + j J p j δ i j. (3) T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 23 / 57

Basic Model Incorporated Companies The revenues and expenses at t = 1 in a given state s are: xs i ωs i + A k s zk i + dsδ j j i. (4) k K j J We combine the two conditions of the budget restriction, where the latter shall hold for all states s 1: B i (q, p, ω i, δ i, A, D) = { (x i, z i, δ i ) X i Z i H i (3) and (4) hold } which can be written more compactly as B i (q, p, ω i, δ i, A, D) = { (x i, z i, δ i ) X i Z i H i (5) holds } where ( ) x i ω i q + z i + A ( (D0 p) D 1 ) δ i + ( ) p δi. (5) 0 T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 24 / 57

Basic Model Incorporated Companies D 0 R J is the vector of dividends of all J firms at t = 0, and D 1 R S J is the matrix of dividends of all firms in all states at t = 1. An economic agent i is therefore confronted with the following utility maximization problem: max U i (x) such that (x i, z i, δ i ) B i (q, p, ω i, δ i, A, D) x i X i z i Z i δ i H i Now consider the budget restriction of an incorporated firm. For a given production decision y j and a given financial policy (ξ j, τ j ), the maximal dividends of firm j are: ( d j = y j q + A ) ξ j + ( (D0 p) D 1 ) τ j. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 25 / 57

Basic Model Incorporated Companies The dividends of firm j depend on the dividends of all firms. A firm solves the following maximization problem (where the weights π j, again serve to evaluate different dividend vectors): max d j R S+1 y j Y j ξ j P j τ j T j ( π j d j such that d j y j q + A ) ξ j + ( (D0 p) D 1 ) τ j. The budget restriction requires that in any state s the dividends do not exceed the net output plus the payoffs from the financial market. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 26 / 57

Basic Model Incorporated Companies Let { W j (q, p, A, D) := (d j, y j, ξ j, τ j ) R S+1 Y j P j T j } (6) holds where ( ) d j y j q + ξ j + A ( (D0 p) D 1 Now we can formulate the firm s decision problem as max d j R S+1 y j Y j ξ j P j τ j T j ) τ j. (6) π j d j such that (d j, y j, ξ j, τ j ) W j (q, p, A, D). T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 27 / 57

Modigliani-Miller Theorem Modigliani-Miller Theorem We consider financial market equilibria and ask to what extent they depend on the firms financial policies. While in the traditional view, the shareholder value of a firm depends on its debt-equity ratio, Modigliani and Miller show that under well defined conditions the funding of a firm is irrelevant. Their proof is based on an intuitive arbitrage argument. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 28 / 57

Modigliani-Miller Theorem Non-Incorporated Companies Consider a financial economy with production EF P according to Def. 1. An EF P is considered to be in a state of equilbrium, if four conditions are met: (i) Consumers maximize utility within their budget constraints. (ii) Firms maximize profits given their constraints, without allowing for arbitrage. (iii) The allocations must be achievable. (iv) Financial markets clear. Given the model of non-incorporated companies introduced in the last subsection, this leads to the following definition. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 29 / 57

Modigliani-Miller Theorem Non-Incorporated Companies Definition (Financial Market Equilibrium with Endogenous Production) A FME for a financial economy EF P with endogenous production are allocations ( φ X, φ Z, φ H, φ Y, φ P ) and a pricing system ( q, {π j } j J ), such that (i) ( x i, z i, δ i ) B i ( q, ω i, δ i, A, D) and x i arg max U i (x i ) for all i I, ( ) (ii) ( y j, ξ j, d j ) satisfies d q j y j + ξ A j and d j arg max π j d j for all j J, (iii) i I x i i I ωi + j J y j, (iv) i I z i + j J ξ j = 0, where π j satisfies the NAC for all j, i.e., the firms see no opportunity for arbitrage. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 30 / 57

Modigliani-Miller Theorem Non-Incorporated Companies If we do not require condition (ii) to hold, then we speak of a financial market equilibrium with exogenous production decisions. In the following we shall examine how a given equilibrium changes under alternative financial policies of the firms. The answer is given by the Modigliani-Miller theorem (MMT). T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 31 / 57

Modigliani-Miller Theorem Non-Incorporated Companies Theorem (MMT with non-incorporated companies) Let ( φ X, φ Z, φ H, φ Y, φ P ) and ( q, {π j } j J ) be a FME with endogenous production decision and let ˆφ P be any financial policy allocation of the firms, then ( φ X, ˆφ Z, φ H, φ Y, ˆφ P ) and ( q, {π j } j J ) is also an FME with exogenous/endogenous production decision, where ẑ i = z i + ( ξ j ˆξ j) δi j, for all i I. j J This shows that the funding of optimal production plans is irrelevant, as the good allocation φ X, the production φ Y, and the price vector q remain unchanged. Intuitively, the consumers can undo the change of the firms financial policy. The proof can be found in the text book on page 275f. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 32 / 57

Modigliani-Miller Theorem Incorporated Companies Apart from the activity on the bond market, firms can now also buy each other s stock. In this case, variant of MMT holds (see book, page 279). Exceptions for when the MMT does not hold can be found in the text book on page 277f. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 33 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules Firm s Decisions Rules In this section we have a closer look at the decision-making process in firms. First, we question why the shareholders, who are consumers in the end of the day, would maximize profits. Then, we analyze whether shareholders with different preferences would agree on a common production plan. Fisher Separation Theorem T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 34 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules A Simple Market with One Firm We consider a situation where there is no uncertainty and only one firm. A single security with positive payoff A and price q is traded. Let p be the firm s market price and d its dividend at t = 1, while there are no dividends at t = 0. Furthermore, the household initially has a positive share δ i in the firm. This considerably simplifies the budget restriction (3), yielding the following maximization problem for the agent: max U(x i ) such that x i x i R 2 0,δi,z i 0 + qz i + pδ i ω0 i + p δ i and x1 i ω1 i + z i A + δ i d. (7) T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 35 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules Firm s Decisions Rules Thus at t = 0, an household can consume and buy securities and shares in the firm. At t = 1 it gains the earnings from its initial share, security payoffs and the firm s dividends. Suppose the agent would like to consume less at t = 0 and more at t = 1. This results in a utility change. If x 0 and x 1 are very small, we can approximate the utility change by the corresponding first derivatives: t = 0 : t = 1 : U(x 0 x 0, x 1 ) U(x 0, x 1 ) U(x) x 0 x 0 U(x 0, x 1 + x 1 ) U(x 0, x 1 ) U(x) x 1 x 1. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 36 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules Firm s Decisions Rules Setting aside x 0 consumption units at t = 0, one can use the free resources to buy x 0 q units of securities. This yields a payoff of x 0 q A at t = 1 to the extent of which one may finance additional consumption: x 1 x 0 q A. If the agent has strictly monotonic preferences, we even have x 1 = x 0 q A. At the optimum, this transfer of consumption may not change the net utility, i.e.: U(x) x 0 = U(x) x 1. x 0 x 1 Substituting x 1 = x 0 q A, we get U(x) x 0 = U(x) x 0 x 0 x 1 q A MRS 01 = A q. (8) T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 37 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules Firm s Decisions Rules We know that the price q of a bond with payoff A = 1 is determined by q = 1 1+r f, where r f denotes the riskless rate of interest. In this case the right-hand side of (8) becomes MRS 01 = 1 + r f. At the optimum an agent will determine his allocations such that his valuations of consumption at t = 0 and t = 1 agree with the market s. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 38 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules Firm s Decisions Rules Buying shares instead of securities leads to a similar result. Forgoing consumption at t = 0 allows one to buy x 0 p shares to the firm, which in turn yield a profit of x 0 p d consumption units at t = 1. Again, at the optimum this transfer of consumption may not change the net utility, and we get: U(x) x 0 = U(x) x 0 x 0 x 1 p d MRS 01 = d p. Now we have both MRS 01 = 1 + r f and MRS 01 = d p, so 1 + r f = d d p, and thus p = 1+r f. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 39 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules Firm s Decisions Rules We can divide the income at t = 1 by 1 + r f in (7) to convert it to a present income, then sum up both budget restrictions. Some rewriting then leads to ( ) ( ) x0 i ωi 0 + xi 1 ωi 1 1+r f + z i q A 1+r f δ i p + δ i d 1+r f p. The left-hand expression describes the value of the net swapped amounts in t = 0 consumption units. The right-hand side denotes the value of the firm share in consumption units. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 40 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules Firm s Decisions Rules If we substitute q = A 1+r f and p = d 1+r f, the bound simplifies to x i 0 ω i 0 + x i 1 ωi 1 1 + r f = δ i d 1 + r f. Hence the possible consumption increases in proportion to the dividend d. We have also considered the case S = 1, so the demand for a higher dividend can be translated to a demand for a high profit or net present value (NPV). Clearly, the shareholders will strive for maximum profit, i.e., carry out the project with the highest cash-flow. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 41 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules Firm s Decisions Rules y 1 B ū 0 y 1 A (1 + r f ) y 0 y 0 I 1 I 2 I 3 T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 42 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules Firm s Decisions Rules The product technology set is shown in grey. The households, assuming they own and control the firms, will choose a production point that maximizes their available income. In the figure this is ( y 0, y 1 ), which lies on the budget line I 3. The result is independent of the respective preferences, except that they are required to be strictly monotonic. The households can achieve optimum consumption by trading their production ( y 0, y 1 ) on the market for securities. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 43 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules Fisher Separation with Multiple Firms With multiple firms the budget restriction looks a bit more general, but is still a special case of (3): max x i R 2 0 δ i R J z i R U(x i ) such that x i 0 + qz i + j J and x i 1 ω i 1 + z i A + j J p j δ i j ω i 0 + j J d j δ i j. p j δi j (9) Similarly to the first part, we obtain the relation of prices of securities and shares. Accordingly, the budget restrictions in (9) can be written concisely: x0 i ω0 i + x 1 i ωi 1 = δ i d j j. 1 + r f 1 + r j J f T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 44 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules Fisher Separation with Multiple Firms Introducing more firms has not changed the result: a shareholder with strictly monotonic utility function again wants the firm to maximize its profit. The two types of shareholders are illustrated as the slope of I 1 and I 2, showing very high and very low rates of interest, respectively. Accordingly, the former would choose production point A, while the latter would pick B. We compute an average rate of interest, weighted by the corresponding shares, which is shown as the slope of Ī. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 45 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules Fisher Separation with Multiple Firms y 1 B C I 1 I 2 A Ī y 0 T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 46 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules The Theorem of Drèze In Section 6.2 the sole requirement for the firm s decision rules was that it weights its future profits by the elements of a vector π j R S+1. If the markets are complete (rank A = S), this uniquely determines the firm s target function. In the case of incomplete markets, it does not have to be unique. Basically one can work with any vector that does not offer an arbitrage opportunity, i.e., ( ) ( π j q = 0 and π j (Y0 p) ) = 0. A In the case of complete markets, every shareholder would agree with the uniquely determined criterion π N. Y 1 T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 47 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules The Theorem of Drèze This is apparent from the first-order conditions of the utility maximization problem: the normalized utility gradients of all consumers matches the normalized target function vector π N. Let firms be barred from running a financial policy, i.e., ξ j = 0. It immediately follows that D = Y. The Modigliani-Miller theorem showed that in our model, nobody will want to object to this limitation. Furthermore, we will limit ourselves to the non-incorporated companies model. So we have the following underlying maximization problems: max U i (x) such that (x i, z i ) B i (q, ω i, δ i, A, Y ) (10) x i X i z i Z i max y j Y j π j y j such that d j y j. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 48 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules The Theorem of Drèze We now look into firm j s general meeting of shareholders GM j. We also assume that the production policies of all other firms are available. What can GM j improve, given the decisions { z i } i I, {ȳ l } l j? We will assume that GM j only takes into consideration the consumers that own shares of firm j. Hence, let I j := {i I δ i j > 0}, for all j. How does a consumer i value changes of the production policy ȳ j? The obvious criterion is the increase in consumer s utility with the new production policy ŷ j : U i ( x i + (ŷ j ȳ j ) δ i j )U i ( x i ). T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 49 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules The Theorem of Drèze Remark The x i implied by a given ( z, Ȳ ) is ( ) x i := ω i q + z i + Ȳ δ i. A We now give the following unanimity criterion: Definition (Pareto-efficient with respect to GM j ) The production policy ȳ j of firm j is Pareto-efficient with respect to GM j, if ȳ j Y j, and there is no ŷ j Y j with U i ( x i + (ŷ j ȳ j ) δ i j ) U i ( x i ) for all i I j, and U i ( x i + (ŷ j ȳ j ) δ i j ) > U i ( x i ) for at least one i I j. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 50 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules The Theorem of Drèze According to this criterion, an existing production policy is only discarded if all shareholders agree. In general many production policies may fulfill the criterion, so that a manager may not know which one to choose. We therefore allow shareholders to change each other s minds by means of transfer payments: let ρ i j be the net side payment made by shareholder i in the voting process. Then he values the decision of GM j according to the criterion: U i ( x i + (ŷ j ȳ j ) δ i j ρ i je 1 )U i ( x i ). T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 51 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules The Theorem of Drèze Definition (Pareto-efficiency with side payments with respect to GM j ) The production policy ȳ j of firm j is Pareto-efficient with side payments w.r.t. GM j, if ȳ j Y j and there are no ŷ j Y j and {ρ i j } i I j with i I j ρ i j 0, such that U i ( x i + (ŷ j ȳ j ) δ j i ρi j e 1) U i ( x i ) for all i I j, and U i ( x i + (ŷ j ȳ j ) δ j i ρi j e 1) > U i ( x i ) for at least one i I j. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 52 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules The Theorem of Drèze The decision-finding mechanism described in this definition is rather difficult to implement: one would have to iterate through all production policies and transfer payments to find a better production policy. In the following we will describe an equivalent, direct mechanism. To that end, let π N,i (x i ) R S+1 0 be his MRS between consumption in state s and present consumption: π N,i s (x i ) := x i s Ui (x i ) x i 0 U i (x i ), s S. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 53 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules The Theorem of Drèze Now imagine the consumers just tell the manager their vectors π N,i (x i ). He in turn chooses the production policy such that it maximizes the function π j y j, where π j := i δi j πn,i is treated as given by the firm. Therefore, the discounting vector of firm j is the mean discounting vector of the consumers, weighted by their shares. In particular, this decision rule leads to the usual profit maximization rule if the markets are complete. The equivalence of the two mechanisms is shown by the Theorem of Drèze. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 54 / 57

Firm s Decision Rules The Theorem of Drèze Theorem (Theorem of Drèze) The production policy y j Y j is Pareto-efficient with side payments with respect to GM j if and only if for a given π N,j, y j arg max y j Y j πn,j y j, where π N,j = i δ i j πn,i. The proof can be found in the text book on page 284f. T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 55 / 57

References References T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 56 / 57

References References I T. Hens, M. Rieger (Zürich/Trier) Financial Economics August 6, 2010 57 / 57