Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions

Similar documents
Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions. Alessandro Notarpietro, Bank of Italy Stefano Siviero, Bank of Italy

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

Risky Mortgages in a DSGE Model

Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy 1

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Reforms in a Debt Overhang

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

On the new Keynesian model

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates

Macroprudential Policy Implementation in a Heterogeneous Monetary Union

CAPITAL FLOWS AND FINANCIAL FRAGILITY IN EMERGING ASIAN ECONOMIES: A DSGE APPROACH α. Nur M. Adhi Purwanto

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

A Policy Model for Analyzing Macroprudential and Monetary Policies

A Model with Costly-State Verification

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles

Bank Capital Requirements: A Quantitative Analysis

Capital Flows, Financial Intermediation and Macroprudential Policies

The Eurozone Debt Crisis: A New-Keynesian DSGE model with default risk

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases

Self-fulfilling Recessions at the ZLB

Asset Price Bubbles and Monetary Policy in a Small Open Economy

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Asset Prices, Collateral and Unconventional Monetary Policy in a DSGE model

Bank Capital, Agency Costs, and Monetary Policy. Césaire Meh Kevin Moran Department of Monetary and Financial Analysis Bank of Canada

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

GHG Emissions Control and Monetary Policy

Fiscal Consolidation in a Currency Union: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes

Financial intermediaries in an estimated DSGE model for the UK

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

Probably Too Little, Certainly Too Late. An Assessment of the Juncker Investment Plan

Schäuble versus Tsipras: a New-Keynesian DSGE Model with Sovereign Default for the Eurozone Debt Crisis

Monetary Policy Rules in the Presence of an Occasionally Binding Borrowing Constraint

Monetary policy and the asset risk-taking channel

Lecture 4. Extensions to the Open Economy. and. Emerging Market Crises

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Gali Chapter 6 Sticky wages and prices

Household Leverage, Housing Markets, and Macroeconomic Fluctuations

Exchange Rate Adjustment in Financial Crises

House Prices, Credit Growth, and Excess Volatility:

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Leverage Restrictions in a Business Cycle Model. March 13-14, 2015, Macro Financial Modeling, NYU Stern.

2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic. 3. Capital, labor account for small fraction of output drop,

Mortgage Amortization and Amplification

DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Debt Covenants and the Macroeconomy: The Interest Coverage Channel

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

MONETARY POLICY EXPECTATIONS AND BOOM-BUST CYCLES IN THE HOUSING MARKET*

A MODEL OF SECULAR STAGNATION

Optimality of Inflation and Nominal Output Targeting

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Oil Price Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy

Leverage Restrictions in a Business Cycle Model

Household Leverage, Housing Markets, and Macroeconomic Fluctuations

On the Merits of Conventional vs Unconventional Fiscal Policy

Interest-rate pegs and central bank asset purchases: Perfect foresight and the reversal puzzle

On the (in)effectiveness of LTV regulation in a multiconstraint framework

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

Monetary Economics. Financial Markets and the Business Cycle: The Bernanke and Gertler Model. Nicola Viegi. September 2010

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont)

Monetary Policy and the Predictability of Nominal Exchange Rates

Structural Reforms in a Debt Overhang

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

Leverage Restrictions in a Business Cycle Model

The Role of the Net Worth of Banks in the Propagation of Shocks

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

The Interaction between the Basel Regulations and Monetary Policy: Fostering Economic and Financial Stability

Fiscal Consolidations in Currency Unions: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes

The science of monetary policy

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

A Model with Costly Enforcement

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

Lorant Kaszab (MNB) Roman Horvath (IES)

Principles of Banking (III): Macroeconomics of Banking (1) Introduction

WORKING PAPER SERIES 15. Juraj Antal and František Brázdik: The Effects of Anticipated Future Change in the Monetary Policy Regime

Output Gaps and Robust Monetary Policy Rules

Quantitative Easing and Financial Stability

Money, Sticky Wages, and the Great Depression

Does a Currency Union Need a Capital Market Union?

Inflation Stabilization and Default Risk in a Currency Union. OKANO, Eiji Nagoya City University at Otaru University of Commerce on Aug.

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence

Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment

Country Spreads and Emerging Countries: Who Drives Whom? Martin Uribe and Vivian Yue (JIE, 2006)

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture

Transcription:

Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions A. Notarpietro S. Siviero Banca d Italia 1 Housing, Stability and the Macroeconomy: International Perspectives Dallas Fed - IMF - JMCB November 14-15, 2013 Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas 1 Usual disclaimers apply

Overview Should monetary policy systematically respond to house price fluctuations?

Overview Should monetary policy systematically respond to house price fluctuations? How does the traditional monetary policy prescription (i.e. inflation targeting) modify in the presence of financial frictions?

Overview Should monetary policy systematically respond to house price fluctuations? How does the traditional monetary policy prescription (i.e. inflation targeting) modify in the presence of financial frictions? Housing and collateralized borrowing: should the price of collateral be part of monetary policy objectives/targets?

Overview Should monetary policy systematically respond to house price fluctuations? How does the traditional monetary policy prescription (i.e. inflation targeting) modify in the presence of financial frictions? Housing and collateralized borrowing: should the price of collateral be part of monetary policy objectives/targets? Main result: financial frictions modify optimal policy rule, in particular the response to house prices

Overview Should monetary policy systematically respond to house price fluctuations? How does the traditional monetary policy prescription (i.e. inflation targeting) modify in the presence of financial frictions? Housing and collateralized borrowing: should the price of collateral be part of monetary policy objectives/targets? Main result: financial frictions modify optimal policy rule, in particular the response to house prices Central bank s knowledge of the economy crucially affects results

Motivation Monetary policy and asset prices: where do we stand?

Motivation Monetary policy and asset prices: where do we stand? Consolidated (pre-crisis) view: asset price variations should influence monetary policy only insofar as they help forecasting inflation (Bernanke and Gertler 2001)

Motivation Monetary policy and asset prices: where do we stand? Consolidated (pre-crisis) view: asset price variations should influence monetary policy only insofar as they help forecasting inflation (Bernanke and Gertler 2001) Financial crisis tightly related to US housing market: macro-financial interactions matter; revision of models used for policy analysis

Motivation Monetary policy and asset prices: where do we stand? Consolidated (pre-crisis) view: asset price variations should influence monetary policy only insofar as they help forecasting inflation (Bernanke and Gertler 2001) Financial crisis tightly related to US housing market: macro-financial interactions matter; revision of models used for policy analysis Role of housing-related shocks and borrowing constraints in general equilibrium models for policy analysis (Iacoviello 2005, Iacoviello and Neri 2010)

Motivation Monetary policy and asset prices: where do we stand? Consolidated (pre-crisis) view: asset price variations should influence monetary policy only insofar as they help forecasting inflation (Bernanke and Gertler 2001) Financial crisis tightly related to US housing market: macro-financial interactions matter; revision of models used for policy analysis Role of housing-related shocks and borrowing constraints in general equilibrium models for policy analysis (Iacoviello 2005, Iacoviello and Neri 2010) What role for house prices in monetary policy? Does a systematic reaction help stabilize business cycle?

Motivation Monetary policy and asset prices: where do we stand? Consolidated (pre-crisis) view: asset price variations should influence monetary policy only insofar as they help forecasting inflation (Bernanke and Gertler 2001) Financial crisis tightly related to US housing market: macro-financial interactions matter; revision of models used for policy analysis Role of housing-related shocks and borrowing constraints in general equilibrium models for policy analysis (Iacoviello 2005, Iacoviello and Neri 2010) What role for house prices in monetary policy? Does a systematic reaction help stabilize business cycle? What about social welfare? How related to business cycle stabilization?

Related literature Iacoviello (2005): standard loss function minimization, no role for house price targeting

Related literature Iacoviello (2005): standard loss function minimization, no role for house price targeting Mendicino and Pescatori (2008), Rubio (2011): welfare-optimal rules, pure inflation targeting no longer optimal, redistributive issues

Related literature Iacoviello (2005): standard loss function minimization, no role for house price targeting Mendicino and Pescatori (2008), Rubio (2011): welfare-optimal rules, pure inflation targeting no longer optimal, redistributive issues Source of shocks matters: news (Lambertini et al. 2013)

Related literature Iacoviello (2005): standard loss function minimization, no role for house price targeting Mendicino and Pescatori (2008), Rubio (2011): welfare-optimal rules, pure inflation targeting no longer optimal, redistributive issues Source of shocks matters: news (Lambertini et al. 2013) Jeske and Liu (2012): no financial frictions; optimal rule should stabilize sticky rental prices

Related literature Iacoviello (2005): standard loss function minimization, no role for house price targeting Mendicino and Pescatori (2008), Rubio (2011): welfare-optimal rules, pure inflation targeting no longer optimal, redistributive issues Source of shocks matters: news (Lambertini et al. 2013) Jeske and Liu (2012): no financial frictions; optimal rule should stabilize sticky rental prices Multi-sector models: focus on relative price stickiness and consumption weight (Aoki 2001, Benigno 2004, Mankiw and Reis 2003); Erceg and Levin (2006): optimal rule should assign larger weight to durable goods than their relative share in consumption

Results preview Quadratic loss function minimization (business cycle stabilization): no sizeable nor systematic gain from response to house prices

Results preview Quadratic loss function minimization (business cycle stabilization): no sizeable nor systematic gain from response to house prices Social welfare loss minimization: a systematic response to house prices improves social welfare

Results preview Quadratic loss function minimization (business cycle stabilization): no sizeable nor systematic gain from response to house prices Social welfare loss minimization: a systematic response to house prices improves social welfare Welfare gain is small: no sizeable difference if central bank does not react to house prices

Results preview Quadratic loss function minimization (business cycle stabilization): no sizeable nor systematic gain from response to house prices Social welfare loss minimization: a systematic response to house prices improves social welfare Welfare gain is small: no sizeable difference if central bank does not react to house prices However, systematic response is optimal if central bank is uncertain about actual degree of financial frictions: not responding generates large welfare losses

Model Closed-economy DSGE model, calibrated on euro-area data

Model Closed-economy DSGE model, calibrated on euro-area data Two-sector (housing, non-housing), two-agent (patient, impatient) setup (Iacoviello and Neri 2010)

Model Closed-economy DSGE model, calibrated on euro-area data Two-sector (housing, non-housing), two-agent (patient, impatient) setup (Iacoviello and Neri 2010) Households utility: { E 0 (β) t 1 (X t ) 1 σ X L } C (N t=0 1 σ X 1+σ C,t ) 1+σ L L C D (N LC 1+σ D,t ) 1+σ L D LD

Model Closed-economy DSGE model, calibrated on euro-area data Two-sector (housing, non-housing), two-agent (patient, impatient) setup (Iacoviello and Neri 2010) Households utility: { E 0 (β) t 1 (X t ) 1 σ X L } C (N t=0 1 σ X 1+σ C,t ) 1+σ L L C D (N LC 1+σ D,t ) 1+σ L D LD Consumption index: X t [ ( ) 1 ε D 1 η t ω D D (C t hc t 1 ) η D 1 η 1 + ε D η t ω D D (D t) ηd 1 η D ] ηd η D 1

Model Closed-economy DSGE model, calibrated on euro-area data Two-sector (housing, non-housing), two-agent (patient, impatient) setup (Iacoviello and Neri 2010) Households utility: { E 0 (β) t 1 (X t ) 1 σ X L } C (N t=0 1 σ X 1+σ C,t ) 1+σ L L C D (N LC 1+σ D,t ) 1+σ L D LD Consumption index: X t [ ( ) 1 ε D 1 η t ω D D (C t hc t 1 ) η D 1 η 1 + ε D η t ω D D (D t) ηd 1 η D ] ηd η D 1 ε D t : housing preference shock, following AR(1) process

Model Financial frictions: a fraction ω of households face collateral constraint: } bt b = ε LTV t (1 χ)e t {T D,t+1 Dt b π t+1 R t

Model Financial frictions: a fraction ω of households face collateral constraint: } bt b = ε LTV t (1 χ)e t {T D,t+1 Dt b π t+1 R t ε LTV t : loan-to-value ratio shock, following AR(1) process

Model Financial frictions: a fraction ω of households face collateral constraint: } bt b = ε LTV t (1 χ)e t {T D,t+1 Dt b π t+1 R t ε LTV t : loan-to-value ratio shock, following AR(1) process Amplification effect: T D,t = collateral value = b b t = C t, D t = T D,t+1,...

Model Financial frictions: a fraction ω of households face collateral constraint: } bt b = ε LTV t (1 χ)e t {T D,t+1 Dt b π t+1 R t ε LTV t : loan-to-value ratio shock, following AR(1) process Amplification effect: T D,t = collateral value = bt b = C t, D t = T D,t+1,... Financial accelerator: fluctuations in collateral price = volatility of real variables

Model Financial frictions: a fraction ω of households face collateral constraint: } bt b = ε LTV t (1 χ)e t {T D,t+1 Dt b π t+1 R t ε LTV t : loan-to-value ratio shock, following AR(1) process Amplification effect: T D,t = collateral value = bt b = C t, D t = T D,t+1,... Financial accelerator: fluctuations in collateral price = volatility of real variables Asymmetric transmission of monetary policy due to (i) agents heterogeneity and (ii) nominal debt contracts: in real interest rate (debt repayment) detrimental to borrowers but beneficial to savers

Analysis Study optimal monetary policy in the class of simple and operational interest-rate rules (Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe 2007): R ( t R = πt ) ( ) (1 ρ)φπ (1 ρ)φ y ( Yt πd,t π Y t 1 π D ) (1 ρ)φπd ( ) ρ Rt 1 R

Analysis Study optimal monetary policy in the class of simple and operational interest-rate rules (Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe 2007): R ( t R = πt ) ( ) (1 ρ)φπ (1 ρ)φ y ( Yt πd,t π Y t 1 π D ) (1 ρ)φπd ( ) ρ Rt 1 R Choose φ π, φ y, φ πd and ρ to maximize some objective function

Analysis Study optimal monetary policy in the class of simple and operational interest-rate rules (Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe 2007): R ( t R = πt ) ( ) (1 ρ)φπ (1 ρ)φ y ( Yt πd,t π Y t 1 π D ) (1 ρ)φπd ( ) ρ Rt 1 R Choose φ π, φ y, φ πd and ρ to maximize some objective function Quadratic loss function (business cycle stabilization)

Analysis Study optimal monetary policy in the class of simple and operational interest-rate rules (Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe 2007): R ( t R = πt ) ( ) (1 ρ)φπ (1 ρ)φ y ( Yt πd,t π Y t 1 π D ) (1 ρ)φπd ( ) ρ Rt 1 R Choose φ π, φ y, φ πd and ρ to maximize some objective function Quadratic loss function (business cycle stabilization) Ex-ante social welfare (second-order approximation to household utility)

Analysis Study optimal monetary policy in the class of simple and operational interest-rate rules (Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe 2007): R ( t R = πt ) ( ) (1 ρ)φπ (1 ρ)φ y ( Yt πd,t π Y t 1 π D ) (1 ρ)φπd ( ) ρ Rt 1 R Choose φ π, φ y, φ πd and ρ to maximize some objective function Quadratic loss function (business cycle stabilization) Ex-ante social welfare (second-order approximation to household utility) Shocks: housing demand, LTV ratio, productivity

Calibration Parameter Description Value Preferences β B Discount factor (patient) 0.99 β S Discount factor (impatient) 0.96 σx Intertemporal elasticity of substitution 1.00 σlc Labor supply elasticity (non-housing) 2.00 σld Labor supply elasticity (housing) 2.00 ω Share of impatient agents 0.20 Final consumption hs Habit persistence (patient) 0.82 hb Habit persistence (impatient) 0.28 ωd Share of housing services in consumption 0.10 ηd Nondurable consumption housing substitution 1.00 δ Housing depreciation rate 0.01 χ Downpayment ratio 0.20 Investment δk Capital depreciation rate 0.03 φ Investment adjustment cost (non-residential) 0.10 ψ Capital utilization adjustment cost (non-residential) 3 φd Investment adjustment cost (residential) 0.005 ψd Capital utilization adjustment cost (residential) 10 Firms αc Share of capital (non-residential) 0.30 αd Share of capital (residential) 0.30 αl Share of land (residential) 0.15 µc Intermediate non-residential goods substitution 4.33 µd Intermediate residential goods substitution 4.33 µw Labor varieties substitution (residential) 4.33 µw Labor varieties substitution (non-residential) 4.33 Nominal rigidities θc Calvo non-residential (goods) 0.92 γc Indexation non-residential (goods) 0.50 θd Calvo residential (goods) 0.00 γd Indexation residential (goods) 0.00 θwc Calvo non-residential (labor) 0.92 γwc Indexation non-residential (labor) 0.23 θwd Calvo residential (labor) 0.93 γwd Indexation residential (labor) 0.44

Calibration Parameter Description Value Monetary policy rule Interest-rate persistence ρ 0.85 Response to inflation φ π 1.25 Response to GDP growth φ y 0.015 Exogenous shocks: persistence Technology (non-residential) ρ A 0.90 Technology (residential) ρ AD 0.90 Housing demand ρ D 0.95 Financial (loan-to-value) ρ LTV 0.95 Exogenous shocks: standard deviation Technology (non-residential) σ A 1.50 Technology (residential) σ AD 1.10 Housing demand σ D 2.85 Financial (loan-to-value) σ LTV 0.01

Calibration Steady state ratios: Variable Description Value R Nominal interest rate (annualized) 4.00 C /Y Consumption-to-output ratio 0.58 T D Z D /Y Residential investment-to-output ratio 0.03 I /Y Investment-to-output ratio 0.21 B/(4Y) Private debt-to-annual-output ratio 0.50 P H G /Y Public expenditure-to-output ratio 0.18 Second moments: Model Data GDP 2.54 2.21 Consumption 2.35 2.20 Investment 6.23 6.18 Residential investment 6.51 5.70 Household debt 8.07 5.84 Nominal interest rate 0.32 0.39 CPI inflation 0.32 0.46 House price inflation 0.99 1.03

Business cycle stabilization Does a systematic response to house prices help achieve business cycle stabilization? Quadratic loss function: L A = σ 2 π + λσ 2 y + µσ 2 r Result: optimal response to house prices is virtually zero. Reacting is irrelevant Figure What if central bank has a preference over stabilizing house prices?

Business cycle stabilization Does a systematic response to house prices help achieve business cycle stabilization? Quadratic loss function: L A = σ 2 π + λσ 2 y + µσ2 r + νσ2 π D Result: optimal response to house prices is virtually zero. Reacting is irrelevant Figure What if central bank has a preference over stabilizing house prices? Augmented loss Systematic (non-zero) response may be optimal, but results heavily depend on central bank s preferences Overall best performance: inflation targeting and no response to house prices Figure

Welfare maximization Central bank s objective: social welfare loss function Computed as second order approximation to households utility W social t ωw b t +(1 ω)w s t Definitions Largely used in the literature since Rotemberg and Woodford (1997) to rank performance of alternative monetary policy rules Allows to account for heterogeneous consumption choices and capture sectoral dynamics, relative price movements

Welfare maximization A systematic response to house prices improves social welfare: W tot φ π φ y ρ φ πd Response to house prices 0.086 2.36 1.84 0.08-0.12 No response to house prices 0.091 1.64 0.87 0.00 0.00

Welfare maximization A systematic response to house prices improves social welfare: W tot φ π φ y ρ φ πd Response to house prices 0.086 2.36 1.84 0.08-0.12 No response to house prices 0.091 1.64 0.87 0.00 0.00 Welfare gain is small: no sizeable difference if central bank does not react to house prices

Welfare maximization A systematic response to house prices improves social welfare: W tot φ π φ y ρ φ πd Response to house prices 0.086 2.36 1.84 0.08-0.12 No response to house prices 0.091 1.64 0.87 0.00 0.00 Welfare gain is small: no sizeable difference if central bank does not react to house prices Response to house prices is negative: optimal rule strikes balance between opposite forces, due to (i) agents heterogeneity and (ii) nominal debt contracts

Welfare maximization A systematic response to house prices improves social welfare: W tot φ π φ y ρ φ πd Response to house prices 0.086 2.36 1.84 0.08-0.12 No response to house prices 0.091 1.64 0.87 0.00 0.00 Welfare gain is small: no sizeable difference if central bank does not react to house prices Response to house prices is negative: optimal rule strikes balance between opposite forces, due to (i) agents heterogeneity and (ii) nominal debt contracts Overall response of R also depends on GDP and inflation (never after demand shock) IRFs

Welfare maximization A systematic response to house prices improves social welfare: W tot φ π φ y ρ φ πd Response to house prices 0.086 2.36 1.84 0.08-0.12 No response to house prices 0.091 1.64 0.87 0.00 0.00 Welfare gain is small: no sizeable difference if central bank does not react to house prices Response to house prices is negative: optimal rule strikes balance between opposite forces, due to (i) agents heterogeneity and (ii) nominal debt contracts Overall response of R also depends on GDP and inflation (never after demand shock) IRFs Conclusion: no substantial welfare improvement from responding to house prices

Welfare maximization A systematic response to house prices improves social welfare: W tot φ π φ y ρ φ πd Response to house prices 0.086 2.36 1.84 0.08-0.12 No response to house prices 0.091 1.64 0.87 0.00 0.00 Welfare gain is small: no sizeable difference if central bank does not react to house prices Response to house prices is negative: optimal rule strikes balance between opposite forces, due to (i) agents heterogeneity and (ii) nominal debt contracts Overall response of R also depends on GDP and inflation (never after demand shock) IRFs Conclusion: no substantial welfare improvement from responding to house prices However, financial frictions play a key role. Central bank information is also crucial Sensitivity

The role of financial frictions Financial frictions measured by share of borrowers (ω) and average loan-to-value ratio (LTV) Suppose the actual measures are: ω = 30% (instead of 20%) LTV = 90% (instead of 80%) Economy is expected to display larger fluctuations in prices and quantities in response to shocks Result: slightly positive response to house prices is optimal ω LTV W tot φ π φ y ρ φ πd Response to house prices 0.3 0.9 0.1038 1.69 1.04 0.00 0.03 No response to house prices 0.2 0.8 0.1041 2.00 1.51 0.08 0.00 Compute implicit weight assigned to housing in optimal price index that CB targets: π O t = π α D,t π1 α t : α = 0.02 Smaller than share in consumption (0.1), closer to weight in GDP

The role of financial frictions: fault-tolerance analysis Fault tolerance (Levin and Williams 2003): evaluate increase in welfare loss as one single parameter of optimized interest-rate rule varies, holding others at optimal values

The role of financial frictions: fault-tolerance analysis Fault tolerance (Levin and Williams 2003): evaluate increase in welfare loss as one single parameter of optimized interest-rate rule varies, holding others at optimal values Flat curves: policy is fault tolerant, i.e. model misspecification does not lead to large increase in loss

The role of financial frictions: fault-tolerance analysis Fault tolerance (Levin and Williams 2003): evaluate increase in welfare loss as one single parameter of optimized interest-rate rule varies, holding others at optimal values Flat curves: policy is fault tolerant, i.e. model misspecification does not lead to large increase in loss Aim: assess scope for deviations from optimal rule, particularly interested in φ πd

The role of financial frictions: fault-tolerance analysis Fault tolerance (Levin and Williams 2003): evaluate increase in welfare loss as one single parameter of optimized interest-rate rule varies, holding others at optimal values Flat curves: policy is fault tolerant, i.e. model misspecification does not lead to large increase in loss Aim: assess scope for deviations from optimal rule, particularly interested in φ πd Thought experiment: what if CB does not know exactly the degree of financial frictions in the economy?

The role of financial frictions: fault-tolerance analysis Fault tolerance (Levin and Williams 2003): evaluate increase in welfare loss as one single parameter of optimized interest-rate rule varies, holding others at optimal values Flat curves: policy is fault tolerant, i.e. model misspecification does not lead to large increase in loss Aim: assess scope for deviations from optimal rule, particularly interested in φ πd Thought experiment: what if CB does not know exactly the degree of financial frictions in the economy? Suppose CB enacts rule that is optimal for benchmark economy (ω = 0.2,LTV = 0.8), but true degree of financial frictions is instead ω = 0.3,LTV = 0.9: any additional welfare cost?

The role of financial frictions: fault-tolerance analysis Response to CPI inflation, GDP and lagged interest rate: no sizeable additional loss Figure

The role of financial frictions: fault-tolerance analysis Response to CPI inflation, GDP and lagged interest rate: no sizeable additional loss Figure Response to house prices: large additional loss

The role of financial frictions: fault-tolerance analysis Response to CPI inflation, GDP and lagged interest rate: no sizeable additional loss Figure Response to house prices: large additional loss However: if CB implements rule that is optimal in the high FF case when the true degree of FF is the benchmark one, additional cost is much smaller

The role of financial frictions: fault-tolerance analysis Response to CPI inflation, GDP and lagged interest rate: no sizeable additional loss Figure Response to house prices: large additional loss However: if CB implements rule that is optimal in the high FF case when the true degree of FF is the benchmark one, additional cost is much smaller Borrowers behavior drives the result: Figure

The role of financial frictions: fault-tolerance analysis Response to CPI inflation, GDP and lagged interest rate: no sizeable additional loss Figure Response to house prices: large additional loss However: if CB implements rule that is optimal in the high FF case when the true degree of FF is the benchmark one, additional cost is much smaller Borrowers behavior drives the result: Figure Conclusion: systematic positive response to house prices is optimal if CB is uncertain about true degree of FF

The role of financial frictions: fault-tolerance analysis Response to CPI inflation, GDP and lagged interest rate: no sizeable additional loss Figure Response to house prices: large additional loss However: if CB implements rule that is optimal in the high FF case when the true degree of FF is the benchmark one, additional cost is much smaller Borrowers behavior drives the result: Figure Conclusion: systematic positive response to house prices is optimal if CB is uncertain about true degree of FF Rationale: inefficiencies associated to house price volatility outweigh those related to consumer price inflation. Contrasting house price movements reduces volatility in consumption induced by financial accelerator

Conclusions Welfare maximization: a systematic response to house prices improves social welfare, but gain is small

Conclusions Welfare maximization: a systematic response to house prices improves social welfare, but gain is small Systematic response to house prices is optimal if central bank is uncertain about actual degree of financial frictions: not responding generates large welfare losses

Conclusions Welfare maximization: a systematic response to house prices improves social welfare, but gain is small Systematic response to house prices is optimal if central bank is uncertain about actual degree of financial frictions: not responding generates large welfare losses Next: role of financial intermediation, model uncertainty

Thanks

Sensitivity analysis House price stickiness: response to house prices increasing in sectoral price stickiness; positive for θ D > 0.3 Presence of financial frictions does not alter traditional policy prescriptions (Aoki 2001, Benigno 2004) Wage stickiness: wage flexibility = stronger response to CPI inflation and relevance of FF-distortions = optimal response to house prices 0 Financial frictions: Varying share of borrowers: without borrowers, no incentive to accommodate in house prices = response to h.p. positive and large Varying LTV ratio: response to house prices with LTV (more leveraged economy) Persistence of housing demand shocks: no role Back

Optimal policy frontiers 2 1.8 no response to house prices response to house prices 1.6 Inflation variance 1.4 1.2 1 0.8 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 GDP variance Back

Welfare cost under alternative policy objectives Back

Business cycle stabilization (2) Augmented loss function: L A = σ 2 π + λσ 2 y + νσ 2 π D + µσ 2 r with λ [0,1], ν [0.001,1], µ = 0.001 Note: cannot compare minimum values of L A and L S, since arguments are different Compute second-order approximation of individual (and aggregate) utility functions under the two optimal rules and compare Back

Welfare loss calculations Consumption equivalent: fraction of consumption from given policy regime (ψ) to be given to each agent to achieve steady-state welfare level. Solve: { W b = E 0 (β b) t 1 ( X b,a ) t=0 1 σ t (1+ψ b ) 1 σx w L ( C,b C,b,t X 1+ σ LC,b N b,a C,t ) 1+σLC,b w D,s,t L D,b 1+ σ LD,b ( } N b,a ) 1+σLD,b D,t { } W s = E 0 (β s ) t 1 (X s,a t=0 1 σ t (1+ψ s ))) 1 σ X w L ( C,s C,b,t N s,a ) 1+σLC,s X 1+ σ C,t w L ( D,s D,b,t N s,a ) 1+σLD,s LC,s 1+σ D,t LD,s Aggregate welfare cost: ψ ωψ b +(1 ω)ψ s Back

Housing demand shock 0.15 GDP 0.02 Cons. (savers) 0.5 Cons. (borrowers) 0.3 Investment 0.1 0.04 0.4 0.25 0.06 0.3 0.2 0.05 0.2 0.15 0.08 0 0.1 0.1 0.1 0 0.05 0.05 0.12 0.1 0 0.1 5 10 15 20 0.14 5 10 15 20 0.2 5 10 15 20 0.05 5 10 15 20 Welfare max. rule Standard Taylor rule 4 Household debt 0.14 Nominal int. rate (Annualized) 0.1 Inflation rate (Ann.) 1 Real house price 3.5 0.12 0.08 0.9 3 2.5 0.1 0.08 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.8 0.7 2 0 1.5 1 0.04 0.02 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.02 0.08 0.4 0 5 10 15 20 0.04 5 10 15 20 0.1 5 10 15 20 5 10 15 20

LTV ratio shock 8 x 10 3 GDP 3.5 x 10 3 Cons. (savers) 0.05 Cons. (borrowers) 9 x 10 3 Investment 7 3 0.04 8 6 7 5 2.5 0.03 6 4 2 0.02 5 3 1.5 0.01 4 2 1 0 3 1 2 0 0.5 0.01 1 1 5 10 15 20 0 5 10 15 20 0.02 5 10 15 20 0 5 10 15 20 Welfare max. rule Standard Taylor rule 0.5 Household debt 12 x 10 3 Nominal int. rate (Annualized) 4 x 10 4 Inflation rate (Ann.) 0.014 Real house price 0.45 10 3 0.012 0.4 0.35 8 2 0.01 0.3 6 0.008 1 0.25 4 0.006 0.2 2 0 0.004 0.15 0.1 0 1 0.002 0.05 5 10 15 20 2 5 10 15 20 2 5 10 15 20 0 5 10 15 20

Productivity shock (non-housing) 0.7 GDP 0.6 Cons. (savers) 0.4 Cons. (borrowers) 1.8 Investment 0.6 0.55 0.2 1.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.5 0.45 0.4 0 0.2 1.4 1.2 1 0.35 0.4 0.2 0.1 0 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.6 0.8 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.1 0.15 1 0.2 0.2 5 10 15 20 0.1 5 10 15 20 1.2 5 10 15 20 0 5 10 15 20 Welfare max. rule Standard Taylor rule 2 Household debt 0 Nominal int. rate (Annualized) 0.02 Inflation rate (Ann.) 1 Real house price 1.5 0.05 0 0.9 1 0.5 0.1 0.02 0.04 0.8 0.7 0.15 0.06 0 0.6 0.2 0.08 0.5 1 0.25 0.1 0.12 0.5 0.4 1.5 0.3 0.14 0.3 2 5 10 15 20 0.35 5 10 15 20 0.16 5 10 15 20 0.2 5 10 15 20

Productivity shock (housing) 0.1 GDP 16 x 10 3 Cons. (savers) 0.1 Cons. (borrowers) 0.07 Investment 0.09 14 0.05 0.06 0.08 0.07 0.06 12 10 8 0 0.05 0.05 0.04 0.05 0.03 0.04 0.03 0.02 6 4 2 0.1 0.15 0.02 0.01 0.01 0 0.2 0 0 5 10 15 20 2 5 10 15 20 0.25 5 10 15 20 0.01 5 10 15 20 Welfare max. rule Standard Taylor rule 0.4 Household debt 0.16 Nominal int. rate (Annualized) 6 x 10 3 Inflation rate (Ann.) 0.1 Real house price 0.2 0 0.2 0.14 0.12 0.1 5 4 0.12 0.14 0.16 0.18 0.08 3 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 0.06 0.04 0.02 2 1 0.22 0.24 0.26 0.28 1 5 10 15 20 0 5 10 15 20 0 5 10 15 20 0.3 5 10 15 20 Back

Fault-tolerance analysis 0.7 Response to non durable inflation 0.4 Response to GDP growth 0.6 0.35 0.5 0.3 0.4 0.25 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.15 0.1 Baseline High FF 0.1 Baseline High FF 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 0.05 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 0.16 Response to lagged interest rate 0.45 Response to house prices 0.15 0.4 0.14 0.35 0.13 0.3 0.12 0.25 0.11 0.2 0.1 0.15 0.09 Baseline High FF 0.1 Baseline High FF 0.08 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 0.05 0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 Back

Fault-tolerance analysis 0.6 Response to house prices, savers welfare loss 0.6 Response to house prices, borrowers welfare loss 0.55 0.5 0.5 0.45 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.35 0.2 0.3 0.25 0.1 0.2 0 0.15 Baseline High FF 0.1 0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 Baseline High FF 0.1 0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 Back