Killing two birds with one stone: Reducing fiscal and welfare loss of tax evasion

Similar documents
University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser.

Aggressive Corporate Tax Behavior versus Decreasing Probability of Fiscal Control (Preliminary and incomplete)

Who is audited? Experimental study on rule-based and human tax auditing schemes

An Experimental Study of Compliance and Leverage in Auditing and Regulatory. Enforcement * Timothy N. Cason Purdue University. and

Endowment inequality in public goods games: A re-examination by Shaun P. Hargreaves Heap* Abhijit Ramalingam** Brock V.

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Risk Aversion and Tacit Collusion in a Bertrand Duopoly Experiment

Optimal income tax structure with favoritism

An Experimental Study of Compliance and Leverage in Auditing and Regulatory. Enforcement * Timothy N. Cason Purdue University. and

Debt and (Future) Taxes: Financing Intergenerational Public Goods

Citation Economic Modelling, 2014, v. 36, p

Investment Decisions and Negative Interest Rates

Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals. Donald J. Wright

Endogenous audits, uncertainty, and taxpayer assistance services: Theory and experiments 1

Tax Evasion and Monopoly Output Decisions Revisited: Strategic Firm Behavior

Limitations of Dominance and Forward Induction: Experimental Evidence *

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

Mental Accounting in Tax Evasion Decisions An Experiment on Underreporting and Overdeducting

Historical Trends in the Degree of Federal Income Tax Progressivity in the United States

Effectiveness of the Cutoff Audit Rule and Inequality of Income

Ostracism and the Provision of a Public Good Experimental Evidence

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

Who is audited? Experimental study on rule-based tax auditing schemes

Informal Sector and Taxation

Mixed strategies in PQ-duopolies

Department of Economics Working Paper

FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information

PhD Qualifier Examination

Sean M. Collins, Duncan James, Maroš Servátka and Daniel. Woods

The Hidden Costs of Tax Evasion

Unemployment, tax evasion and the slippery slope framework

Key words : Tax Evasion; Conspicuous Consumption; Signal Auditing JEL Classification: H26

Rational Choice and Moral Monotonicity. James C. Cox

Alex A. T. Rathke School of Economics, BA and Accounting, University of São Paulo, Brazil

Moral Hazard Example. 1. The Agent s Problem. contract C = (w, w) that offers the same wage w regardless of the project s outcome.

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

ONLINE APPENDIX (NOT FOR PUBLICATION) Appendix A: Appendix Figures and Tables

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

Volume 39, Issue 1. Tax Framing and Productivity: evidence based on the strategy elicitation

On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation

Determinants of Bounced Checks in Palestine

Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

THE INDIVIDUAL TAXPAYER UTILITY FUNCTION WITH TAX OPTIMIZATION AND FISCAL FRAUD ENVIRONMENT

Contracts, Reference Points, and Competition

Income Tax Evasion and the Penalty Structure. Abstract

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

Aggressive Corporate Tax Behavior versus Decreasing Probability of Fiscal Control

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

IS TAX SHARING OPTIMAL? AN ANALYSIS IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT FRAMEWORK

Academic Editor: Emiliano A. Valdez, Albert Cohen and Nick Costanzino

SHSU ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Web Appendix Figure 1. Operational Steps of Experiment

Bias in Reduced-Form Estimates of Pass-through

Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior

Ideal Bootstrapping and Exact Recombination: Applications to Auction Experiments

A Theory of Value Distribution in Social Exchange Networks

A Theory of Value Distribution in Social Exchange Networks

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Volume 29, Issue 3. The Effect of Project Types and Technologies on Software Developers' Efforts

Economics and Computation

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Economic Effects of Tax Evasion on Jordanian Economy

Group-lending with sequential financing, contingent renewal and social capital. Prabal Roy Chowdhury

Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

FIGURE A1.1. Differences for First Mover Cutoffs (Round one to two) as a Function of Beliefs on Others Cutoffs. Second Mover Round 1 Cutoff.

Technology cooperation between firms of developed and less-developed countries

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade

HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation 2011

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

Effect of Nonbinding Price Controls In Double Auction Trading. Vernon L. Smith and Arlington W. Williams

MATH 4321 Game Theory Solution to Homework Two

An Experimental Study of Taxpayer Compliance. Behavior Under Alternative Reporting Regimes

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

Self-Government and Public Goods: An Experiment

Risk Aversion and Compliance in Markets for Pollution Control

A new model of mergers and innovation

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

Ambiguity Aversion in Standard and Extended Ellsberg Frameworks: α-maxmin versus Maxmin Preferences

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

Asset Pricing in Financial Markets

WAGE DIFFERENTIALS IN THE CZECH AGRICULTURAL SECTOR IN THE PERIOD OF THE 1ST QUARTER 2000 TO THE 3RD QUARTER 2012 AND LABOR PRODUCTIVITY

Research Article Welfare Comparison of Leader-Follower Models in a Mixed Duopoly

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Solving real-life portfolio problem using stochastic programming and Monte-Carlo techniques

International Trade: Lecture 3

This is the author s final accepted version.

Transcription:

Noname manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Killing two birds with one stone: Reducing fiscal and welfare loss of tax evasion Rostislav Staněk Ondřej Krčál Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Tax evasion constitutes a fiscal loss to the tax authority and a welfare loss for the society because it induces socially wasteful activities during which taxpayers spend real resources in order to hide their undisclosed income. We develop a theoretical model that explores the effect of audit selection rules on the losses from tax evasion. In the proposed experimental design, we test the main prediction of the model, that the competitive audit selection mechanism reduces both the fiscal and welfare loss of tax evasion. Furthermore, our model shows that a higher basic audit probability motivates taxpayers to increase their socially wasteful activities. Our experimental results confirm the predictions of the model. Our paper shows not only that the competitive audit selection mechanism provides an additional benefit if socially wasteful concealment activities are possible, but also its relative advantage compared to an increase in the audit probability. Keywords Tax evasion Concealment activities Audit selection mechanism JEL classification H26 1 Introduction In the biggest tax evasion prosecution in U.S. history, Walter Anderson was charged with using a complex scheme to conceal approximately $450 million in earnings between 1995 and 1999 from the US authorities. This scheme involved the formation of offshore firms in the British Virgin Islands and Panama, with the aim of concealing Mr. Anderson s investments in several telecommunications companies whose stock prices increased dramatically during the 1990s. 1 Walter Anderson was This research was supported by grant 17-00496S of the Czech Science Foundation. Corresponding author: Rostislav Staněk Department of Economics, Masaryk University, Lipová 41a, 602 00 Brno, Czech Republic Tel.: +420 549 49 6332 E-mail: rostanek@mail.muni.cz Ondřej Krčál Department of Economics, Masaryk University 1 US v. Anderson, 384 F. Supp. 2d 32 (D.C. 2005).

2 Rostislav Staněk, Ondřej Krčál by no means alone in the shady business. The so-called Panama Papers 2 suggest not only that people avoid and evade taxes on a scale larger that previously suspected, but also that people are willing to pay a substantial amounts of money for the concealment services these firms offer. And the activities revealed by Panama papers represent just the tip of the iceberg. In the United States, the average annual tax gap in 2008 2010 was estimated at $458 billion, which corresponds to the compliance rate of 81.7% (IRS, 2016). Similarly, concealment activities may include not only the high-end services of offshore companies, but also various other costly actions such as keeping two sets of books, making false entries in books and records, claiming false or overstated deductions on a return, hiding or transferring assets or income, etc. 3 As shown in these examples, tax evasion constitutes not only fiscal losses for governments, but also creates welfare losses by inducing socially wasteful activities, e.g. by making taxpayers spend real resources in order to conceal their taxable income. In this paper, we study how these fiscal and welfare losses are influenced by two parameters of the audit selection mechanism (ASM): The basic probability that a taxpayer is selected for audit and the sensitivity of a taxpayer s audit probability to income reported by her and by other taxpayers (this parameter will be also called competitiveness of the ASM). We formulate a model of tax compliance in a world where costly concealment activities are possible. The model predicts that increasing competitiveness of the ASM reduces both the fiscal and social loss of tax evasion, while increasing the basic audit probability reduces the fiscal loss but increases the social loss of tax evasion. Using experimental methods, we confirm that increasing competitiveness of the ASM leads to better outcomes than increasing the audit probability. There is a large economic literature on tax compliance (see Torgler, 2002; Slemrod, 2007; Alm, 2012, for surveys). This paper builds on two strains of this literature: on papers studying endogenous audit selection mechanisms, and on the literature on tax evasion concealment. In an endogenous ASM, the audit probability depends not only on the income reported by the taxpayer, but also on the reported incomes of other taxpayers. Two forms of endogenous audit mechanisms have been examined in the experimental literature. The mechanism proposed by Alm and McKee (2004) uses the relative ranking of taxpayers based on their reported income within a group of taxpayers with the same income. The taxpayer with the lowest reported income is selected for audit. Alm and McKee show that this mechanism results in higher tax compliance than a random audit selection rule. On the other hand, Gilpatric, Vossler, and McKee (2011) (henceforth GVM) assume that the tax office has noisy but unbiased information about the actual income of taxpayers. The tax office then audits the taxpayers with the largest observed tax fraud, which equals the difference between the noisy observation of the actual income and the reported income. This structure can be generalized to an audit selection rule where the probability of being audited is an increasing function of the difference between taxpayers observed tax fraud and the average observed tax fraud in the peer group. The results of GVM s analysis confirm that such a rule results in higher tax compliance. This is also found by Cason et al (2016). 2 The Panama Papers are 11.5 million documents of the Panamanian law firms Mossack Fonseca leaked on 15 April 2016 (Harding, 2016). 3 http://www.bizfilings.com/toolkit/sbg/tax-info/fed-taxes/tax-avoidance-and-taxevasion.aspx (Accessed February 2017)

Killing two birds with one stone: Reducing fiscal and welfare loss of tax evasion 3 In this paper we follow Alm and McKee (2004) in assuming that we are able to divide the taxpayers in groups with the same income. In a real tax enforcement setting, tax authorities would need to observe not only reported incomes, but also several other characteristics of taxpayers. These characteristics would be used to match taxpayers in peer groups. A successful matching should generate peer groups containing taxpayers with similar incomes. Taking advantage of the same-income assumption, we follow GVM in proposing an endogenous ASM in which the audit probability a taxpayer is increasing in the difference between the average reported income of her peer taxpayers and her reported income. The literature on tax evasion concealment focuses mainly on the effects of tax rate and tax penalty on concealment activities. Bayer (2006) provides a theoretical model in which detected tax evasion depends on the taxpayers investment into concealment activities and the auditors investment into detection. The audit is therefore modeled as a detection-concealment contest. Bayer and Sutter (2009) study this situation experimentally. They find that concealment activities depend positively on the tax rate and do not depend on the penalty imposed when tax evasion is detected. In contrast to these studies, our theoretical model and experimental design studies the effect of audit probability and competitiveness of the ASM on tax compliance and concealment activities. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 introduces the theoretical model. Section 3 translates the model into an experimental design. Section 4 presents the results of the experiment and Section 5 concludes. 2 Model In the model, the taxpayers choose not only how much income to disclose but also how much to invest into tax concealment activities. This investment determines the probability that the undisclosed income is verifiable by tax authority when the taxpayer is selected for audit. 2.1 Timing of the model The timing of the model is as follows: 1. Each taxpayer is endowed with the same income I. 2. The taxpayer declares his taxable income r [0, I] and chooses the probability p that the undisclosed income is verifiable by the tax authority given that the taxpayer is selected for audit. The reported income r is subject to the tax rate τ. The choice of the verification probability p induces monetary costs c(p) where c(p) is decreasing and convex function, c(1) = 0 and c(0). 3. The audit selection rule decides whether the taxpayer is selected for audit or not. If the taxpayer is selected for audit, the nature decides whether the tax evasion is verifiable or not. If the taxpayer is audited and the tax evasion is verifiable, the taxpayer has to pay the fine which is equal to the undisclosed income z = I r. The audit selection rule determines the probability Π that the taxpayer is selected for audit. We examine two audit selection rules. The random selection

4 Rostislav Staněk, Ondřej Krčál rule states that each taxpayer may be selected for audit with the same probability Π = π. When the endogenous audit selection rule is applied, the audit probability depends on the income reported by the taxpayer and also on the income reported by other taxpayers Π(r i, r i, π, β) where π and β are parameters that define the audit selection rule. Parameter π defines the basic audit probability and parameter β defines the sensitivity of the audit selection rule to the disclosed income (competitiveness). The endogenous audit selection rule has the following properties: 1. The audit probability is decreasing in the reported income Π r i < 0. 2. If the reported income is the same for all taxpayers, then the audit probability is π, i.e. Π = π if r i = r i. 3. The higher is the parameter β the higher is the sensitivity of the audit probability with respect to the undisclosed income, i.e. Π r i β < 0 or alternatively Π z i β > 0. 4. Random audit selection rule is a special case of the endogenous audit selection rule, i.e. Π = π if β = 0. We assume that the taxpayer is risk-neutral. His expected payoff is therefore given as follows U(r i, r i ) = Π(r i, r i )p i (r i (1 τ)) + (1 Π(r i, r i )p i )(I τr i ) c(p i ). (1) The first term is the taxpayer s payoff when he is audited and tax evasion is verifiable. The second term is the taxpayer s payoff when the undisclosed income is successfully evaded. The last term c(p i ) represents the cost of the tax concealment activity. 2.2 Equilibrium By taking derivatives according to the variable r i and p i, we obtain the following first order conditions which implicitly define the best response functions. Π(I r i ) c (p i ) = 0 (2) Π r i p i (I r i ) τ + Πp i = 0 (3) By restricting our attention to symmetric equilibrium (r, p ), we get the equilibrium conditions. There are four possible equilibrium situations. 1. Interior solution π(i r ) c (p ) = 0 (4) Π rp (I r ) τ + πp = 0 (5) where the following second order conditions are satisfied c (p ) > 0 (6) Π rr(p )(I r ) + 2Π rp < 0 (7) ( c )( Π rrp (I r ) + 2Π rp ) (π Π r(i r)) 2 > 0 (8)

Killing two birds with one stone: Reducing fiscal and welfare loss of tax evasion 5 2. Partly corner solution with p = 1 and r (0, I) π(i r ) c (p ) > 0 (9) Π r i p (I r ) τ + πp = 0 (10) 3. Partly corner solution with r = 0 and p (0, 1) π(i r ) c (p ) = 0 (11) Π r i p (I r ) τ + πp < 0 (12) 4. Corner solution with p = 1 and r = I π(i r ) c (p ) > 0 (13) Π r i p (I r ) τ + πp > 0 (14) 2.3 Comparative statics The aim of this subsection is to show how the equilibrium values r and p depends on the the audit selection mechanism. In particular, we are interested what happens if we change the basic audit probability π or the sensitivity parameter β. Suppose that there is the interior solution. By taking derivatives of the equations (2) and (3) according to β and π we get the following comparative static results The effect of sensitivity The effect of the sensitivity parameter β is given by following equations: p β = πr β c (15) r β ( Π r r(i r )p + p Π r) + p β (π Π r(i r )) = Π rβp (I r ) (16) By substitution we get the effect of sensitivity on reported income r β [c ( Π rr(i r )p + p Π r)) + π(π Π r(i r )] = c Π rβp (I r ) As the right-hand side is always negative, the effect depends on the sign of the expression in the square brackets on the left-hand side. From the second order condition 8 we can see that this expression is negative if the following condition holds c ( Π rr(i r )p +p Π r)) (π Π r(i r)) > π(( c )( Π rrp (I r )+2Π rp )) }{{} = τ p By substitution from the first order condition (5) and after some algebraical manipulation, we get the following condition. Π rr(i r )p (τ p π) + Π rp (2p π τ) > 0

6 Rostislav Staněk, Ondřej Krčál Given the assumption the that the audit probability function Π is non-concave with respect to reported income, the condition is satisfied if τ > 2πp (17) Therefore the reported income is increasing in the sensitivity parameter, rβ > 0, under this mild condition. Moreover, it follows from equation 15 that p β > 0. We can summarize this results in the following proposition. Proposition 1 : Suppose that condition 17 holds. Equilibrium reported income is increasing in the sensitivity parameter. Equilibrium probability that the undisclosed income is verifiable is increasing in the sensitivity parameter. The effect of basic audit probability By applying the implicit function theorem we can see that the effect of basic audit probability on verification probability is given by the following equation π [c ( Π rr(i r )p + p Π r)) + π(π Π r(i r )] = }{{} τ>2p π <0 p = (I r )p Π r πp +(I r )(Π rr(i r )p ) }{{} τ 2p π We know from the previous sections that the expression in the square brackets on the left-hand side is negative if τ > 2p π. The same condition ensures that the right-hand side of the equation is positive. Henceforth, the probability that the undisclosed income is verifiable is decreasing in the basic audit probability. The effect of basic audit probability on the reported income is given by the following condition (differentiation of the first equilibrium condition according to π). (I r ) + πr π c p π = 0. As it holds that p π < 0 it has to hold also that rπ > 0. Propostion 2 summarizes the effect of changes in the basic audit probability parameter. Proposition 2 : Suppose that condition (17) holds. Equilibrium reported income is increasing in the basic audit probability parameter. Equilibrium probability that the undisclosed income is verifiable is decreasing in the basic audit probability. 3 Experimental design We test predictions of the model in an economic experiment. Each experimental session consists of 20 rounds. In the treatments with endogenous ASM, the subjects are divided into pairs of peer taxpayers. In order to keep the one-shot incentives of the theoretical model and at the same time have two independent observations per session, the partner for each subject is randomly selected from the same half of subjects participating in a given session.

Killing two birds with one stone: Reducing fiscal and welfare loss of tax evasion 7 At the beginning of each round, all taxpayers receive the same income I = 100 CZK. 4 Their task is to choose the reported income r (0, 100) and the verification probability p (0.25, 1). The reported income is taxed at ( a rate ) τ = 0.6. Each 1 verification probability entails a concealment cost c(p) = 20 p 1 CZK. Next, the tax authority selects taxpayer i for audit with a probability ( ) r i r i Π i = π + β, (18) r i + r i where r i is the reported income of taxpayer i, r i is the reported income of the peer taxpayer, π is the basic audit probability, and β determines sensitivity of the ASM to reported incomes (competitiveness). We used π = {0.4, 0.6} for the basic audit probability and β = {0, 0.2, 0.4} for the sensitivity parameter. Thus we have six treatments, one for each combinations of π and β parameters. If taxpayer i is selected for audit, her true income is verified with the probability p i. If verified, the subject pays a penalty equal to her unreported income 100 r i. The taxpayer i s payoff in a given round is 0.4r i + (100 r i ) c(p i ) if she is not selected for audit, or she is selected but her actual income is not verified. Her income is only 0.4r i c(p i ) if she is selected for audit and her true income is verified. The experiment was conducted in MUEEL in Brno, the Czech Republic, in October 2016. It was organized using hroot system (Bock et al, 2012) and the experimental environment was prepared in ztree (Fischbacher, 2007). We used neutral instructions (the instructions are available upon request from the corresponding author). We ran 6 sessions one session per treatment (between-subject design) with 15 20 participants each. The sessions lasting between 70 and 90 minutes. The total number of participants was 110. The subjects received a showup fee and payoffs from two randomly selected rounds. The mean payoff was 190 CZK (approx. $7). 4 Results The main focus of this section will lie in how the treatment variables affect reported incomes and verification probabilities chosen by the experimental taxpayers. Each treatment consists of 20 identical rounds. The experimental situation is quite complex, so we expect that subjects will adjust their choices during the initial periods substantially (learning effect). Indeed, the visual inspection of the data suggests that subject were adjusting their strategy in the first 5 10 periods in most of the sessions. For this reason, we will use only data from the rounds 11 20 in the analysis. Hence our data set contains 10 observations per subject, 1,100 observations in total. Table 1 shows summary statistics for some of the variables. Our theoretical model suggests that each change in parameters of the ASM affects both choice variables simultaneously. Also, there is a clear strategic substitutability between the parameters. Subjects with a high reported income have a low motivation to incur a costly concealment investment, and vice-versa. So we 4 At the time of the experiment, this amount approximately equaled $4, which roughly corresponded to an hourly wage of unqualified student labor in the Czech Republic.

8 Rostislav Staněk, Ondřej Krčál Table 1 Summary statistics Min. 1st Qu. Median Mean 3rd Qu. Max. Reported income r 0 25 43.00 48.03 75 100 Verification probability p 0.28 0.58 0.79 0.77 1 1 Concealment cost c 0 0 5.5 8.7 14.5 51.4 Audit probability Π 0 0.40 0.52 0.51 0.60 1 Payoff (CZK) 95 160 190 190 222 314 expect a positive correlation between random errors of regressions that explain reported income and verification probability with the treatment variables. For this reason, we use seemingly unrelated regression models in our analysis. Furthermore, Table 1 shows that the lowest and highest possible value of the reported income and the highest possible value of verification probability were chosen, so the data is censored. The left column of Table 2 presents OLS regression. 5 In order to deal with the problem of censoring, we use the average reported income and the average verification probability as dependent variables. We find that a more competitive ASM significantly increases income for both changes of β from 0 to 0.2 and from 0 to 0.4. The effect on the average verification probability is positive and statistically significant only for a change of β from 0 to 0.4. The effect of an increase in the base audit probability from 0.4 to 0.6 has no effect on reported income, but significantly reduces the verification probability. The results show that a more competitive mechanism increases compliance and reduces concealment. A higher audit probability, on the other hand, motivates people to conceal more while having no significant effect on tax compliance. The Tobit-SUR model presented in the right column Table 2 provides very similar results. A more competitive ASM again motivates people to report more and, in the case of a change from β = 0 to 0.4, also to conceal less. The increase in the base audit probability has no statistically significant effect on reporting and concealment. 5 Conclusion This paper examines the effect of two policies on tax compliance and investment in concealment activities. We propose a theoretical model that predicts that a higher audit probability leads to more compliance, but also to higher investment into concealment. On the other hand, a more competitive mechanism is predicted to create more compliance and less concealment. Hence, the endogenous audit selection might reduce both the fiscal and welfare cost of tax evasion. We test these predictions using an economic experiment. The results are very much consistent with the model. In particular, we find that a high increase in competitiveness of the mechanism increases the reporting and reduces concealment. If the increase is relatively small, the effect on concealment are no longer statistically significant. Furthermore, a rise in the base audit probability leads to more compliance and more concealment, but effects are small and often not statistically significant. 5 The OLS-SUR model gives the same result as a simple OLS regression if the independent variables are the same in both equations.

Killing two birds with one stone: Reducing fiscal and welfare loss of tax evasion 9 Table 2 Explaining the reported income and verification probability: OLS and Tobit-SUR model with errors clustered at the level of subject Model: OLS model Tobit-SUR model Dependent variable: Average reported income Individual reported income Constant 33.04 33.27 (4.91) (4.96) β = 0.2 12.64 13.44 (5.83) (6.36) β = 0.4 21.87 24.37 (5.65) (6.65) π = 0.6 5.63 8.03 (4.67) (5.45) Dependent variable: Average verification probability Individual verification probability Constant 0.773 0.832 (0.036) (0.054) β = 0.2 0.017 0.009 (0.043) (0.065) β = 0.4 0.097 0.149 (0.042) (0.062) π = 0.6 0.068 0.084 (0.034) (0.055) Note: p < 0.1; p < 0.05; p < 0.01 The results of the experiment suggest that a more competitive ASM might reduce both tax evasion and tax concealment, while a more frequent auditing has no significant impact on tax compliance, and even might increase investment in concealment activities. A smarter ASM seems to be superior to a more active ASM. This advantage seems even clearer if we take into account the costs of both policies. While more frequent auditing due to a higher audit probability is bound to increase the administrative costs, the audit frequency under a more competitive ASM remains constant. The only additional costs of the endogenous ASM consist in a system selecting of taxpayers with similar incomes. Hence, the endogenous audit selection mechanism seems to outperform more frequent auditing not only in terms of results, but also in terms of administrative costs. References Alm J (2012) Measuring, explaining, and controlling tax evasion: lessons from theory, experiments, and field studies. International Tax and Public Finance 19(1):54 77 Alm J, McKee M (2004) Tax compliance as a coordination game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 54(3):297 312 Bayer RC (2006) A contest with the taxman the impact of tax rates on tax evasion and wastefully invested resources. European Economic Review 50(5):1071 1104 Bayer RC, Sutter M (2009) The excess burden of tax evasionan experimental detection concealment contest. European Economic Review 53(5):527 543

10 Rostislav Staněk, Ondřej Krčál Bock O, Nicklisch A, Baetge I (2012) Hamburg registration and organization online tool. H-Lab Working Paper (1) Cason TN, Friesen L, Gangadharan L (2016) Regulatory performance of audit tournaments and compliance observability. European Economic Review 85:288 306 Fischbacher U (2007) z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental economics 10(2):171 178 Gilpatric SM, Vossler CA, McKee M (2011) Regulatory enforcement with competitive endogenous audit mechanisms. The RAND Journal of Economics 42(2):292 312 Harding L (2016) What are the panama papers? a guide to history s biggest data leak. [online] (Accessed February 2017), URL https://www.theguardian.com/news/2016/apr/03/what-you-need-to-knowabout-the-panama-papers IRS (2016) Tax gap estimates for tax years 2008 2010. [online] (Accessed February 2017), URL https://www.irs.gov/uac/the-tax-gap Slemrod J (2007) Cheating ourselves: The economics of tax evasion. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 21(1):25 48 Torgler B (2002) Speaking to theorists and searching for facts: Tax morale and tax compliance in experiments. Journal of Economic Surveys 16(5):657 683