Multi-period mean variance asset allocation: Is it bad to win the lottery?

Similar documents
Optimal Trade Execution: Mean Variance or Mean Quadratic Variation?

Mean-Quadratic Variation Portfolio Optimization: A desirable alternative to Time-consistent Mean-Variance Optimization?

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo

Time-consistent mean-variance portfolio optimization: a numerical impulse control approach

CS 774 Project: Fall 2009 Version: November 27, 2009

Time-consistent mean-variance portfolio optimization: a numerical impulse control approach

Continuous Time Mean Variance Asset Allocation: A Time-consistent Strategy

Hedging Costs for Variable Annuities under Regime-Switching

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Optimal order execution

Fourier Space Time-stepping Method for Option Pricing with Lévy Processes

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Optimal Dividend Policy of A Large Insurance Company with Solvency Constraints. Zongxia Liang

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

QI SHANG: General Equilibrium Analysis of Portfolio Benchmarking

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

Management of Withdrawal Risk Through Optimal Life Cycle Asset Allocation

Optimal liquidation with market parameter shift: a forward approach

Numerical solution of the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman formulation for continuous time mean variance asset allocation under stochastic volatility

Numerical Methods for Optimal Trade Execution

Effectiveness of CPPI Strategies under Discrete Time Trading

Portfolio Management and Optimal Execution via Convex Optimization

Evaluation of proportional portfolio insurance strategies

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard

Variable Annuities with Lifelong Guaranteed Withdrawal Benefits

Pricing Methods and Hedging Strategies for Volatility Derivatives

Principal-Agent Problems in Continuous Time

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Portability, salary and asset price risk: a continuous-time expected utility comparison of DB and DC pension plans

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 2014

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management

Introduction Credit risk

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

The Uncertain Volatility Model

Optimal Order Placement

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Characterization of the Optimum

Fees for variable annuities: too high or too low?

Optimal Credit Limit Management

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Portfolio optimization problem with default risk

On Using Shadow Prices in Portfolio optimization with Transaction Costs

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

The Black-Scholes Model

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

Pricing and hedging in incomplete markets

Forward Dynamic Utility

Optimum Thresholding for Semimartingales with Lévy Jumps under the mean-square error

Limited liability, or how to prevent slavery in contract theory

Valuing the Guaranteed Minimum Death Benefit Clause with Partial Withdrawals

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Infinite Reload Options: Pricing and Analysis

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios

Asset Allocation and Pension Liabilities in the Presence of a Downside Constraint

Numerical Methods for Optimal Stochastic Control in Finance

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

Mathematics in Finance

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Managing Systematic Mortality Risk in Life Annuities: An Application of Longevity Derivatives

Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index

Robust Hedging of Options on a Leveraged Exchange Traded Fund

Path Dependent British Options

The Black-Scholes Model

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Incorporating Managerial Cash-Flow Estimates and Risk Aversion to Value Real Options Projects. The Fields Institute for Mathematical Sciences

ON MAXIMIZING DIVIDENDS WITH INVESTMENT AND REINSURANCE

Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications

Recovering portfolio default intensities implied by CDO quotes. Rama CONT & Andreea MINCA. March 1, Premia 14

FINANCIAL OPTIMIZATION. Lecture 5: Dynamic Programming and a Visit to the Soft Side

A Data Driven Neural Network Approach to Optimal Asset Allocation for Target Based Defined Contribution Pension Plans

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Singular Stochastic Control Models for Optimal Dynamic Withdrawal Policies in Variable Annuities

Multi-Period Trading via Convex Optimization

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Good Deal Bounds. Tomas Björk, Department of Finance, Stockholm School of Economics, Lausanne, 2010

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Risk minimizing strategies for tracking a stochastic target

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

Drawdowns Preceding Rallies in the Brownian Motion Model

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

The British Russian Option

The Black-Scholes Model

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance

Optimization Models in Financial Mathematics

Monte Carlo Methods (Estimators, On-policy/Off-policy Learning)

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

Aversion to Risk and Optimal Portfolio Selection in the Mean- Variance Framework

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

Transcription:

Multi-period mean variance asset allocation: Is it bad to win the lottery? Peter Forsyth 1 D.M. Dang 1 1 Cheriton School of Computer Science University of Waterloo Guangzhou, July 28, 2014 1 / 29

The Basic Problem Many financial problems have unhedgeable risk Optimal trade execution (sell a large block of shares) Maximize average price received, minimize risk, taking into account price impact Long term asset liability management (insurance) Match liabilities with minimal risk Minimum variance hedging of contingent claims (with real market constraints) Liquidity effects, different rates for borrowing/lending Pension plan investments. Wealth management products 2 / 29

Risk-reward tradeoff All these problems (and many others) involve a tradeoff between risk and reward. A classic approach is to use some sort of utility function But this has all sorts of practical limitations What is the utility function of an investment bank? What risk aversion parameter should be selected by the Pension Investment Committee? Alternative: mean-variance optimization When risk is specified by variance, and reward by expected value Non-technical managers can understand the tradeoffs and make informed decisions 3 / 29

Multi-period Mean Variance Some issues: Standard formulation not amenable to use of dynamic programming Variance as risk measure penalizes upside as well as downside Pre-commitment mean variance strategies are not time consistent I hope to convince you that multi-period mean variance optimization is Intuitive Can be modified slightly to be (effectively) a downside risk measure Motivating example: Wealth Management (target date fund) 4 / 29

Example: Target Date (Lifecycle) Fund with two assets Risk free bond B db = rb dt r = risk-free rate Amount in risky stock index S ds = (µ λκ)s dt + σs dz + (J 1)S dq µ = P measure drift ; σ = volatility dz = increment of a Wiener process dq = { 0 with probability 1 λdt 1 with probability λdt, log J N (µ J, σj 2 ). ; κ = E[J 1] 5 / 29

Optimal Control Define: X = (S(t), B(t)) = Process x = (S(t) = s, B(t) = b) = (s, b) = State (s + b) = total wealth Let (s, b) = (S(t ), B(t )) be the state of the portfolio the instant before applying a control The control c(s, b) = (d, B + ) generates a new state b B + s S + S + = (s + b) B + }{{}}{{} d wealth at t withdrawal Note: we allow cash withdrawals of an amount d 0 at a rebalancing time 6 / 29

Semi-self financing policy Since we allow cash withdrawals The portfolio may not be self-financing The portfolio may generate a free cash flow Let W a = S(t) + B(t) be the allocated wealth W a is the wealth available for allocation into (S(t), B(t)). The non-allocated wealth W n (t) consists of cash withdrawals and accumulated interest 7 / 29

Constraints on the strategy The investor can continue trading only if solvent W a (s, b) = s + b > 0. (1) }{{} Solvency condition In the event of bankruptcy, the investor must liquidate S + = 0 ; B + = W a (s, b) ; if W a (s, b) 0 }{{} bankruptcy Leverage is also constrained S + W + q max W + = S + + B + = Total Wealth. 8 / 29

Mean and Variance under control c(x (t), t) E c( ) t,x [ ] }{{} Reward Var c( ) t,x [ ] }{{} Risk = Expectation conditional on (x, t) under control c( ) = Variance Mean Variance (MV) problem: for fixed λ find control c( ) which solves: { } sup c( ) Z E c( ) t,x [W a (T )] }{{} Reward as seen at time t λ Var c( ) t,x [W a (T )] }{{} Risk as seen at time t, Z = set of admissible controls ; T = target date Varying λ [0, ) traces out the efficient frontier 9 / 29

Embedding( Zhou and Li (2000), Li and Ng (2000) ) Equivalent formulation: 1 2 for fixed λ, if c ( ) solves the standard MV problem, γ such that c ( ) minimizes Once c ( ) is known [( inf E c( ) t,x W a (T ) γ ) 2 ]. (2) c( ) Z 2 Easy to determine E c ( ) t,x [W a (T )], Var c ( ) t,x [W a (T )] Repeat for different γ, traces out efficient frontier 1 We are determining the optimal pre-commitment strategy (Basak,Chabakauri: 2010; Bjork et al: 2010). See (Wang and Forsyth (2012)) for a comparison of pre-commitment and time consistent strategies. 2 We do not require convex constraints. 10 / 29

Equivalence of MV optimization and target problem MV optimization is equivalent 3 to investing strategy which 4 Attempts to hit a target final wealth of γ/2 There is a quadratic penalty for not hitting this wealth target From (Li and Ng(2000)) γ 2 }{{} wealth target = 1 + E c( ) t=0,x }{{} 2λ 0 [W a (T )] }{{} risk aversion expected wealth Intuition: if you want to achieve E[W a (T )], you must aim higher 3 Vigna, Quantitative Finance, to appear, 2014 4 Strictly speaking, since some values of γ may not represent points on the original frontier, we need to construct the upper left convex hull of these points (Tse, Forsyth, Li (2014), SIAM J. Control Optimization) 11 / 29

HJB PIDE Determination of the optimal control c( ) is equivalent to determining the value function { } V (x, t) = inf Et,x[(W c a (T ) γ/2) 2 ], c Z Define: LV σ2 s 2 J V 2 V ss + (µ λκ)sv s + rbv b λv, 0 p(ξ)v (ξs, b, τ) dξ p(ξ) = jump size density and the intervention operator M(c) V (s, b, t) M(c) V (s, b, t) = V (S + (s, b, c), B + (s, b, c), t) 12 / 29

HJB PIDE II The optimal control c( ) is given by solving the impulse control HJB equation: [ ] max V t + LV + J V, V inf (M(c) V ) = 0 c Z Along with liquidation constraint if insolvent V (s, b, t) = V (0, (s + b), t) if (s + b > 0) (3) if (s + b) 0 and s 0 (4) Easy to generalize the above equation to handle the discrete rebalancing case. 13 / 29

Computational Domain 5 + (S,B) [0, ] x[, + ] Solve HJB equation Solve HJB equation B (0,0) Solve HJB equation S + B= 0 S + Liquidate Solve HJB Equation 5 If µ > r it is never optimal to short S 14 / 29

Well behaved utility function Definition (Well-behaved utility functions) A utility function Y (W ) is a well-behaved function of wealth W if it is an increasing function of W. Proposition Pre-commitment MV portfolio optimization is equivalent to maximizing the expectation of a well-behaved quadratic utility function if W a (T ) γ 2. (5) Obvious, since value function V (x, t) is { } V (x, t) = sup Ec x,t [Y (W a (T )] c Z Y (W ) = (W γ/2) 2 15 / 29

Dynamic MV Optimal Strategy Theorem (Vigna (2014)) Assuming that (i) the risky asset follows a pure diffusion (no jumps), (ii) continuous re-balancing, (iii) infinite leverage permitted, (iv) trading continues even if bankrupt: then the optimal self-financing MV wealth satisfies W a (t) F (t) ; t F (t) = γ 2 e r(t t) = discounted wealth target MV optimization maximizes a well behaved quadratic utility Result can be generalized 6 to the case of Realistic constraints: finite leverage and no trading if insolvent But, we must have continuous rebalancing and no jumps 6 Dang and Forsyth (2013) 16 / 29

Global Optimal Point Examination of the HJB equation allows us to prove the following result Lemma (Dang and Forsyth (2013)) The value function V (s, b, t) is identically zero at V (0, F (t), t) 0 ; F (t) = γ 2 e r(t t), t Since V (s, b, t) 0 V (0, F (t), t) = 0 is a global minimum Any admissible policy which allows moving to this point is an optimal policy Once this point is attained, it is optimal to remain at this point 17 / 29

Movement of Globally Optimal Point 7 B V(0, F(t) ) = 0 F(t) = e r(t t) (γ/2) Increasing (T t) Move to optimal point W = 0 S W = F(t) Liquidate 7 This is only admissible if γ > 0 18 / 29

Optimal semi-self-financing strategy Theorem (Dang and Forsyth (2013)) If W a (t) > F (t), 8 t [0, T ], an optimal MV strategy is 9 Withdraw cash W a (t) F (t) from the portfolio Invest the remaining amount F (t) in the risk-free asset. Corollary (Well behaved utility function) In the case of discrete rebalancing, and/or jumps, the optimal semi-self-financing MV strategy is Equivalent to maximizing a well behaved quadratic utility function 10 8 F (t) is the discounted wealth target 9 A similar semi-self-financing strategy for the discrete rebalancing case was first suggested in (Cui, Li, Wang, Zhu (2012) Mathematical Finance). 10 A similar idea is termed time consistency in efficiency (Li, Cui, Zhu (2011)) 19 / 29

Intuition: Multi-period mean-variance Optimal target strategy: try to hit W a (T ) = γ/2 = F (T ). If W a (t) > F (t) = F (T )e r(t t), then the target can be hit exactly by Withdrawing W a (t) F (t) from the portfolio Investing F (t) in the risk free account Optimal control for the target problem optimal control for the Mean Variance problem This strategy dominates any other MV strategy And the investor receives a bonus in terms of a free cash flow 20 / 29

What happens if we win the lottery? Classic Mean Variance If you win the lottery, and exceed your wealth target Since gains > target are penalized. Optimal strategy: lose money! Precommitment, semi-self-financing optimal strategy If you win the lottery, and exceed your wealth target Invest F (t) 11 in a risk-free account Withdraw any remaining cash from the portfolio No incentive to act irrationally 11 F (t) is the discounted target wealth 21 / 29

Numerical Method We solve the HJB impulse control problem numerically using a finite difference method We use a semi-lagrangian timestepping method Can impose realistic constraints on the strategy Maximum leverage, no trading if insolvent Arbitrarily shaped solvency boundaries Continuous or discrete rebalancing Nonlinearities Different interest rates for borrowing/lending Transaction costs Regime switching (i.e. stochastic volatility and interest rates) We can prove 12 that the method is monotone, consistent, l stable Guarantees convergence to the viscosity solution 12 Dang and Forsyth (2014) Numerical Methods for PDEs 22 / 29

Numerical Examples initial allocated wealth (W a (0)) 100 r (risk-free interest rate) 0.04450 T (investment horizon) 20 (years) q max (leverage constraint) 1.5 discrete re-balancing time period 1.0 (years) mean downward jumps mean upward jumps µ (drift) 0.07955 0.12168 λ (jump intensity) 0.05851 0.05851 σ (volatility) 0.17650 0.17650 mean log jump size -0.78832 0.10000 compensated drift 0.10862 0.10862 23 / 29

Efficient Frontier: discrete rebalancing 1200 semi-self-financing + free cash (upward jump) 1000 semi-self-financing (upward jump) Exp Val 800 600 downward jump self-financing (upward jump) 400 200 0 200 400 600 800 Std Dev Figure: T = 20 years, W a (0) = 100. 24 / 29

Example II Two assets: risk-free bond, index Risky asset follows GBM (no jumps) According to Benjamin Graham 13, most investors should Pick a fraction p of wealth to invest in an index fund (i.e. p = 1/2). Invest (1 p) in bonds Rebalance to maintain this asset mix How much better is the optimal asset allocation vs. simple rebalancing rules? 13 Benjamin Graham, The Intelligent Investor 25 / 29

Long term investment asset allocation Investment horizon (years) 30 Drift rate risky asset µ.10 Volatility σ.15 Risk free rate r.04 Initial investment W 0 100 Benjamin Graham strategy Constant Expected Standard Quantile proportion Value Deviation p = 0.0 332.01 NA NA p = 0.5 816.62 350.12 Prob(W (T ) < 800) = 0.56 p = 1.0 2008.55 1972.10 Prob(W (T ) < 2000) = 0.66 Table: Constant fixed proportion strategy. p = fraction of wealth in risky asset. Continuous rebalancing. 26 / 29

Optimal semi-self-financing asset allocation Fix expected value to be the same as for constant proportion p = 0.5. Determine optimal strategy which minimizes the variance for this expected value. We do this by determining the value of γ/2 (the wealth target) by Newton iteration Strategy Expected Standard Quantile Value Deviation Graham p = 0.5 816.62 350.12 Prob(W (T ) < 800) = 0.56 Semi-self-financing 816.62 142.85 Prob(W (T ) < 800) = 0.19 Table: T = 30 years. W (0) = 100. Semi-self-financing: no trading if insolvent; maximum leverage = 1.5, rebalancing once/year. Standard deviation reduced by 250 %, shortfall probability reduced by 3 27 / 29

Cumulative Distribution Functions 1 Prob(W T < W) 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 Risky Asset Proportion = 1/2 Optimal Allocation E[W T ] = 816.62 for both strategies Optimal policy: W risk off; W (t) risk on Optimal allocation gives up gains target in order to reduce variance and probability of shortfall. 0.1 0 200 400 600 800 1000 1200 1400 W Investor must pre-commit to target wealth 28 / 29

Conclusions Pre-commitment mean variance strategy Equivalent to quadratic target strategy Semi-self-financing, pre-commitment mean variance strategy Minimizes quadratic loss w.r.t. a target Dominates self-financing strategy Extra bonus of free cash-flow Example: target date fund Optimal strategy dominates simple constant proportion strategy by a large margin Probability of shortfall 3 times smaller! But Investors must pre-commit to a wealth target Optimal stochastic control: teaches us an important life lesson Decide on a life target ahead of time and stick with it If you achieve your target, do not be greedy and want more 29 / 29