Working Paper. Working Papers in Interdisciplinary Economics and Business Research

Similar documents
Live Long and Prosper? Demographic Change and Europe s Pensions Crisis. Dr. Jochen Pimpertz Brussels, 10 November 2015

EU-28 RECOVERED PAPER STATISTICS. Mr. Giampiero MAGNAGHI On behalf of EuRIC

THE IMPACT OF THE PUBLIC DEBT STRUCTURE IN THE EUROPEAN UNION MEMBER COUNTRIES ON THE POSSIBILITY OF DEBT OVERHANG

EU BUDGET AND NATIONAL BUDGETS

NOTE. for the Interparliamentary Meeting of the Committee on Budgets

EMPLOYMENT RATE Employed/Working age population (15 64 years)

European Advertising Business Climate Index Q4 2016/Q #AdIndex2017

The Tax Burden of Typical Workers in the EU

DG TAXUD. STAT/11/100 1 July 2011

Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, THE COUNCIL, THE EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COMMITTEE AND THE COMMITTEE OF THE REGIONS

EMPLOYMENT RATE IN EU-COUNTRIES 2000 Employed/Working age population (15-64 years)

Fiscal rules in Lithuania

EUROPA - Press Releases - Taxation trends in the European Union EU27 tax...of GDP in 2008 Steady decline in top corporate income tax rate since 2000

Lowest implicit tax rates on labour in Malta, on consumption in Spain and on capital in Lithuania

TRENDS IN THE DEVELOPMENT OF INDIRECT TAXES IN THE MEMBER STATES OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

EMPLOYMENT RATE Employed/Working age population (15-64 years)

PUBLIC PROCUREMENT INDICATORS 2011, Brussels, 5 December 2012

STAT/12/ October Household saving rate fell in the euro area and remained stable in the EU27. Household saving rate (seasonally adjusted)

The Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base. Christoph Spengel

Taxation trends in the European Union Further increase in VAT rates in 2012 Corporate and top personal income tax rates inch up after long decline

EU KLEMS Growth and Productivity Accounts March 2011 Update of the November 2009 release

Analysis of European Union Economy in Terms of GDP Components

Raising the retirement age is the labour market ready for active ageing: evidence from EB and Eurofound research

Statistics: Fair taxation of the digital economy

Youth Integration into the labour market Barcelona, July 2011 Jan Hendeliowitz Director, Employment Region Copenhagen & Zealand Ministry of

Courthouse News Service

Quarterly Gross Domestic Product of Montenegro 3 rd quarter 2017

A BRIEF OVERVIEW OF THE ACTIVITY EFFICIENCY OF THE BANKING SYSTEM IN ROMANIA WITHIN A EUROPEAN CONTEXT

Quarterly Gross Domestic Product of Montenegro 4 th quarter 2018 (p)

Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT. Annex to the

How to complete a payment application form (NI)

2017 Figures summary 1

CANADA EUROPEAN UNION

Adopted on 26 November 2014

Quarterly Gross Domestic Product of Montenegro 2st quarter 2016

Electricity & Gas Prices in Ireland. Annex Business Electricity Prices per kwh 2 nd Semester (July December) 2016

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION

Turkish Economic Review Volume 3 March 2016 Issue 1

Official Journal of the European Union L 172. Legislation. Non-legislative acts. Volume July English edition. Contents REGULATIONS

ANNUAL REVIEW BY THE COMMISSION. of Member States' Annual Activity Reports on Export Credits in the sense of Regulation (EU) No 1233/2011

A. INTRODUCTION AND FINANCING OF THE GENERAL BUDGET. EXPENDITURE Description Budget Budget Change (%)

EIOPA Statistics - Accompanying note

Communication on the future of the CAP

EIOPA Statistics - Accompanying note

EU Pension Trends. Matti Leppälä, Secretary General / CEO PensionsEurope 16 October 2014 Rovinj, Croatia

Lithuania: in a wind of change. Robertas Dargis President of the Lithuanian Confederation of Industrialists

JOINT STATEMENT. The representatives of the governments of the Member States, meeting within the Council of

11 th Economic Trends Survey of the Impact of Economic Downturn

October 2010 Euro area unemployment rate at 10.1% EU27 at 9.6%

3 Labour Costs. Cost of Employing Labour Across Advanced EU Economies (EU15) Indicator 3.1a

PREZENTĀCIJAS NOSAUKUMS

January 2010 Euro area unemployment rate at 9.9% EU27 at 9.5%

3 Labour Costs. Cost of Employing Labour Across Advanced EU Economies (EU15) Indicator 3.1a

Measuring financial protection: an approach for the WHO European Region

Quarterly Financial Accounts Household net worth reaches new peak in Q Irish Household Net Worth

MULTINATIONAL COMPANIES AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

Special scheme for small enterprises under the VAT Directive 2006/112/EC - Options for review

Greek Parliamentary Budget Office Public Financial Management financial transparency and accountability

Quarterly Gross Domestic Product of Montenegro for period 1 st quarter rd quarter 2016

ANNUAL REVIEW BY THE COMMISSION. of Member States' Annual Activity Reports on Export Credits in the sense of Regulation (EU) No 1233/2011

June 2014 Euro area international trade in goods surplus 16.8 bn 2.9 bn surplus for EU28

THE EVOLUTION OF SOCIAL INDICATORS DEVELOPED AT THE LEVEL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION AND THE NEED TO STIMULATE THE ACTIVITY OF SOCIAL ENTERPRISES

Trade Performance in EU27 Member States

TAXATION OF TRUSTS IN ISRAEL. An Opportunity For Foreign Residents. Dr. Avi Nov

BRIEFING ON THE FUND FOR EUROPEAN AID FOR THE MOST DEPRIVED ( FEAD )

26/10/2016. The Euro. By 2016 there are 19 member countries and about 334 million people use the. Lithuania entered 1 January 2015

Consumer Credit. Introduction. June, the 6th (2013)

Single Market Scoreboard

Dividends from the EU to the US: The S-Corp and its Q-Sub. Peter Kirpensteijn 23 September 2016

Borderline cases for salary, social contribution and tax

Current health expenditure increased 3.0% in 2017

Sustainability of upper tier structures impact of BEPS

Technical report on macroeconomic Member State results of the EUCO policy scenarios

Taxation trends in the European Union EU27 tax ratio at 39.8% of GDP in 2007 Steady decline in top personal and corporate income tax rates since 2000

EIOPA Statistics - Accompanying note

Reforming Policies for Regional Development: The European Perspective

Council conclusions on "First Annual Report to the European Council on EU Development Aid Targets"

International Seminar on Strengthening Public Investment and Managing Fiscal Risks from Public-Private Partnerships

RENEWABLE ELECTRICTY SUPPORT IN THE EU WHAT LESSONS CAN BE LEARNED?

REGIONAL PROGRESS OF THE LISBON STRATEGY OBJECTIVES IN THE EUROPEAN REGION EGRI, ZOLTÁN TÁNCZOS, TAMÁS

Ireland, one of the best places in the world to do business. Q Key Marketplace Messages

May 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 6.9 bn euro 3.8 bn euro deficit for EU27

WP4: 2030 (RES) targets & effort sharing

Macroeconomic scenarios for skill demand and supply projections, including dealing with the recession

Study on the framework conditions for High Growth Innovative Enterprises (HGIEs)

First estimate for 2011 Euro area external trade deficit 7.7 bn euro bn euro deficit for EU27

Aggregation of periods for unemployment benefits. Report on U1 Portable Documents for mobile workers Reference year 2016

January 2014 Euro area international trade in goods surplus 0.9 bn euro 13.0 bn euro deficit for EU28

June 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 14.9 bn euro 0.4 bn euro surplus for EU27

COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS OF THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT IN THE MEMBER STATES OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

August 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 6.6 bn euro 12.6 bn euro deficit for EU27

VALUE ADDED TAX COMMITTEE (ARTICLE 398 OF DIRECTIVE 2006/112/EC) WORKING PAPER NO 924

Report Penalties and measures imposed under the UCITS Directive in 2016 and 2017

Spain France. England Netherlands. Wales Ukraine. Republic of Ireland Czech Republic. Romania Albania. Serbia Israel. FYR Macedonia Latvia

Sustainability and Adequacy of Social Security in the Next Quarter Century:

EU State aid: Guidelines on State aid for environmental protection and energy making of -

4,400 OF BRITISH IN THE TIME IT TAKES TO READ THIS TITLE WILL HAVE SPENT TAXPAYERS MONEY THE EUROPEAN UNION

Macroprudential indicators of the financial sector

Transcription:

28 Working Paper Institute of Interdisciplinary Research Working Papers in Interdisciplinary Economics and Business Research The competition analysis in the field of corporate income tax in the EU Beáta Blechová February 2016

Working Papers in Interdisciplinary Economics and Business Research Silesian University in Opava School of Business Administration in Karviná Institute of Interdisciplinary Research Univerzitní nám. 1934/3 733 40 Karviná Czech Republic http://www.iivopf.cz/ email: iiv@opf.slu.cz +420 596 398 237 Citation BLECHOVÁ, B. 2016. The competition analysis in the field of corporate income tax in the EU. Working Paper in Interdisciplinary Economics and Business Research no. 28. Silesian University in Opava, School of Business Administration in Karviná.

Abstract Beáta Blechová: The competition analysis in the field of corporate income tax in the EU With the emergence of multinational corporations and globalization of their economic activities, the competition between these companies is being expanded also on the competition between individual states. This competition is also manifested in the tax area, when less economically developed countries are trying to attract the foreign investors from economically advanced countries to their country through a lower corporate tax burden, which is considered as harmful tax competition. This article contains a comparative analysis of developments in the corporate income tax burden in the EU, with the aim to assess the merits of the opinion on the harmful impact of tax policy in this area, used by thirteen new, economically less developed EU member countries. As an indicator of the size of the tax burden are used herein both the statutory and the effective corporate tax rates. Key words corporate income tax rates, global economy, tax competition, tax coordination and harmonization JEL: F21, F62, H25, H26 Contacts Beáta Blechová, Department of Finance and Accounting, School of Business Administration, Silesian University, Univerzitní nám. 1934/3, 733 40 Karviná, Czechia, e-mail: blechova@opf.slu.cz. Acknowledgement This paper was supported by the Ministry of Education, Youth and Sports Czech Republic within the Institutional Support for Long-term Development of a Research Organization in 2016.

Introduction Much discussed topic today is the globalization process, which has developed into its present form as a result of continuous development of the world economy. J. Stiglitz characterizes the globalization as the closer integration of the countries and peoples of the world, brought about by the enormous reduction of costs of transportation and communication, and the breaking down of artificial barriers to the flows of goods, services, capital, knowledge, and people across borders (Stiglitz, 2002). Globalization is indissolubly linked with the emergence of Multinational Corporations (MNC), i.e. companies which have their headquarters in one country and develop continuous operation under its control in at least two other countries with the use of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI). The poorer countries are trying their best to attract investments of these companies, since they enable them capital inflows and attracting or invoking secondary investment. They also provide them with access to advanced technologies, to advanced managerial experiences, to the developed markets and also create new jobs at the same time. The one of the tools used for this is the lower rate of corporate income tax burden, causing the emergence of tax competition, which most economically advanced states considered harmful. However, tax competition may also represent certain medicine against efforts to expansion of state power and to increasing of the government spending associated with them, which have an impact on the taxes increasing. So it can act more effectively than political mechanisms, because in this case it has the same effect as competition in business. Under the influence of tax competition, governments would be forced to behave more efficient and more responsive to the priorities of their "customers" i.e. the business entities and private individuals. Numerous discussions about the impact of tax competition on economic and fiscal situation in each country are currently being held among politicians and among economists also within the EU. Economists and politicians from the original fifteen Member States (EU15MS) mostly critically evaluate tax policy of thirteen new economically less developed Member States (EU13MS) that manifests an effort to attract capital from EU15MS by decreasing the statutory tax rates on corporate income and by providing various tax benefits. They argue that these activities of EU13MS give rise to harmful tax competition, which has a negative impact on their tax and fiscal policy. As a result, they are themselves forced to reduce the tax burden of incomes, to prevent the leakage of capital to the EU13MS, causing the reduction of their tax revenues. This then has resulted in limiting their opportunities in the provision of public goods and in fulfilling of social functions. These states therefore endeavour to enforce greater tax coordination and harmonization within the EU, particularly in the area of income taxation. 1. Review of Relevant Literature The articles concerning the consequences of uncoordinated fiscal policies in different political jurisdictions were already presented relatively long time ago, for example Tiebout (1956). He argue that fiscal autonomy enables to apply different tax systems for local governments. Individuals and companies can then choose the appropriate tax jurisdiction, while the tax competition causes screening of various preferences, which are provided to economic units and relate with public expenditure, to different tax rates. 1

Other articles, e.g. Wilson (1986) or Zodrow and Mieszkowski (1986) are inclined to think, that due to the effect of tax competition, governments will shift the tax burden from mobile production factors, falling into economic function "capital", on the immobile factors falling into the economic functions "labour" and "consumption". This can cause the effect known as "Race to the Bottom" in the taxation of mobile factors and lead to economic decrease due to the reduction in consumption, caused by higher tax burden of labor and consumption. Bradford and Oates (1971) also argue that the involvement of jurisdictions to tax competition will lead to a limitation of the scope of provided public goods, because the result of efforts to attract mobile production factors will be set tax rates lower than optimal. The opinion that tax competition is harmful and leads to sub-optimal low tax rates for mobile production factors supported among others also Wilson (1986), Bucovetsky (1991) and Wildasin (1988). However, other literary sources, e.g. Ludema and Wootton (2000) or Baldwin and Krugman (2004), point to the fact that competition in the area of FDI flows is affected not only by the amount of applied tax rates, but also by the agglomeration advantages existing in some states. These benefits can e.g. include the proximity of sources of necessary raw materials, the assumption of high sales, the proximity of companies that can provide the necessary cooperation, quality local education system, enough skilled workers, advanced infrastructure, etc. This agglomeration benefits may in fact to ensure also the higher profits for companies taking up residence in those jurisdictions. Therefore the jurisdictions that offer more of agglomeration advantages can afford to apply a higher tax rate. A certain area of the literature dealing with international tax competition also deals with the consequences of tax coordination, see e.g. Wang (1999) or Konrad (2009). These authors incline to believe that if this coordination was possible and did not require the increase in costs, it could lead to an optimal result. However, with regard to various restrictions of coordination capacity it is not clear, whether the tax coordination could lead to an increase in the average level of welfare. In generally, tax competition is defined as utilization of such activities by stakeholders within the tax policies that can preserve or increase the attractiveness of a given area as a good place to settle these taxpayers. This competition may take place within one country (between regions, due to better conformity of the tax burden with the needs of the region), or between countries. At a summit in Brussels in 1997, the European Commission defined "Harmful Tax Competition" as "the level of freedom in the area of tax law, which contributes to significant differences between the taxation of domestic and foreign investment and even to liberation of foreign investment from tax in some EU countries." The phenomenon of harmful tax competition has provoked a reaction also from the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), which theoretically has accepted tax competition leading to tax cuts and forcing governments to streamline state spending, but at the same time she has implemented activities aimed against harmful tax competition. This is manifested not only between EU Member States, but already represents a global problem and weakens the positive effects of tax competition. In 1998, the OECD has drawn up a comprehensive report "Harmful Tax Competition - An Emerging Global Issue" (OECD, 1998), which dealt with this issue. In its report were identified factors that are typical for the harmful preferential tax regimes, which can potentially cause harmful tax competition and the emergence of "tax havens". This report has proposed the measures, which should help to eliminate the factors leading to harmful tax competition. A similar position to the issue of harmful tax competition is also presented in the EU, where can 2

be reported the efforts to harmonization or at least to some coordination of tax systems. However, this effort has not yet been very successful because of the differing opinions of individual MS on the extent of this harmonization, which is in many cases influenced by the interests of large multinationals. 2. Analysis of the extent of tax competition in the area of the corporate income taxation between EU13MS and EU15MS according to the development of corporate income tax rates 2.1. Top statutory corporate income tax rates In assessing the degree of tax competition between EU MS in corporate income taxes is most often based on a comparison of statutory tax rates that are applied at the corporate income tax (SCITR - Statutory Corporate Income Tax Rates). These statutory rates are widely used because of their easy availability. In addition to nominal tax rates they also include the effects of various tax surcharges or reductions, including tax rates concerning local taxes. Their structure is not so uniform in different states. The following Table 1 shows how have developed the maximum value SCITR in the EU MS in the years 2000-2015. In the reporting period, there has been a decline in the average value of this rate within EU28MS by 9.2 pp, which was affected by approximately the same decline of this average in both groups of EU MS. The average value of SCITR at EU13MS has decreased by 9.6 pp (from 28.2% to 18.6%), at EU15MS this value also decreased by 8.9 pp (from 35.4% to 26.5%). Approximately the same degree of the SCITR average values reduction in both groups EU MS has resulted also the very little change in the difference between the average values for both groups within the observed period, namely the increase of 0.7 pp (from 7.2 pp to 7.9 pp). Tab. 1: The development of the corporate income tax rates in EU countries State SCITR ECITR1 ECITR2 Year 2000 2015 Δ1 2002 2013 Δ2 2002 2013 Δ2 (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) p.b. (%) (%) p.b. Belgium 40,2 34,0-6,2 3,0 3,1 0,1 6,7 6,5-0,2 Bulgaria 32,5 10,0-22,5 3,0 1,9-1,1 10,5 6,8-3,7 Czech Republic 31,0 19,0-12,0 4,2 3,2-1,0 12,0 9,2-2,8 Denmark 32,0 23,5-8,5 2,9 2,7-0,2 6,0 5,6-0,4 Germany 51,6 30,2-21,4 1,6 2,5 0,9 4,2 6,3 2,1 Estonia 26,0 20,2-5,8 1,1 0,3-0,8 3,6 0,9-2,7 Ireland 24,0 12,5-11,5 3,7 2,4-1,3 13,1 7,9-5,2 Greece 40,0 29,0-11,0 3,4 1,3-2,1 10,0 3,5-6,5 Spain 35,0 28,0-7,0 3,2 2,2-1,0 9,3 6,6-2,7 France 37,8 38,0 0,2 2,6 2,7 0,1 5,9 5,7-0,2 Croatia 35,0 20,0-15,0 1,8 2,0 0,2 4,9 5,5 0,6 Italy 41,3 31,4-9,9 2,7 2,5-0,2 6,6 5,8-0,8 Cyprus 29,0 12,5-16,5 6,0 6,5 0,5 19,6 20,6 1,0 Latvia 25,0 15,0-10,0 2,0 1,6-0,4 7,1 5,7-1,4 Lithuania 24,0 15,0-9,0 0,6 1,4 0,8 2,0 5,1 3,1 Luxembourg 37,5 29,2-8,3 8,0 4,9-3,1 20,4 12,1-8,3 3

Hungary 19,6 20,6 1,0 2,3 1,3-1,0 6,1 3,3-2,8 Malta 35,0 35,0 0 3,5 5,6 2,1 11,8 16,5 4,7 Netherlands 35,0 25,0-10,0 3,6 2,2-1,4 9,4 5,8-3,6 Austria 34,0 25,0-9,0 2,4 2,2-0,2 5,5 5,1-0,4 Poland 30,0 19,0-11,0 2,0 1,8-0,2 6,3 5,5-0,8 Portugal 35,2 29,5-5,7 3,3 3,4 0,1 10,5 9,0-0,5 Romania 25,0 16,0-9,0 2,6 2,0-0,6 9,3 7,3-2,0 Slovenia 25,0 17,0-8,0 1,6 1,2-0,4 4,1 3,2-0,9 Slovakia 29,0 22,0-7,0 2,5 2,9 0,4 7,6 9,5 1,9 Finland 29,0 20,0-6,0 4,2 2,2-2,0 9,3 5,0-4,3 Sweden 28,0 22,0-6,0 2,0 2,7 0,7 4,3 6,0 1,7 United Kingdom 30,0 20,0-10,0 2,8 2,4-0,4 8,1 6,8-1,3 arithm. Ø EU28 32,0 22,8-9,2 3,0 2,6-0,4 8,4 7,3-1,1 arithm. Ø EU15 35,4 26,5-8,9 3,3 2,6-0,7 8,6 6,5-2,1 arithm. Ø EU13 28,2 18,6-9,6 2,6 2,4-0,2 7,5 7,6 0,1 Δ3 7,2 7,9 0,7 0,7 0,2-0,5 1,1-1,1 2,2 Δ1 = 2015 2000 (pp), Δ2 = 2013 2002 (pp), Δ3 = Ø EU15 Ø EU13 Source: Eurostat, own calculation So the SCITR development within the observed period shows the more significant influence of the SCITR level and the extent of their reduction in EU13MS on the development of these rates in EU15MS (see Figure 1). 4

Fig. 1: The development of SCITR values in EU countries between the years 2000-2015 (Source: Table 1) 2.2. Effective corporate income tax rates op statutory corporate income tax rates The comparison of degree of the corporate income tax burden in different countries by using the statutory rates do not seem as satisfactory access. The possibility of objective tax burden comparison in different countries according to statutory rates is significantly reduced due to different rules for determining the amount of the corporate income tax base arising from tax legislation in these states. So the statutory tax rates are mainly used for the purposes of the mutual tax burden comparison in different countries due to the simplicity their findings. However, they cannot fulfil the role of objective indicator and therefore the Effective Corporate Income Tax Rates (ECITR) are also used for such purposes. These effective tax rates take into account not only the size of the statutory tax rates, but also other aspects of tax systems determining the total amount of really paid taxes. Thus, they take into account both the tax base and the method (if any) by which the systems of corporate and personal income tax are integrated. Comparison of statutory and effective tax rates gives an idea of the tax incentives provided by the authorities in individual countries. Comparison of effective tax rates across countries also provides an indication of whether there are fundamentally different tax approaches to the taxpayers with the same characteristics, but residing in different countries. These data can show whether behind the large variances of the statutory tax rates are not hidden only the small differences in effective taxation, because the countries with high statutory tax rates can reduce the size of the tax base or soften tax enforceability. The analysis of the effective corporate taxation can thus better illuminate the workings of tax competition between countries. Table 1 and Fig.2.shows the evolution of the tax burden on corporate income in the EU MS between the years 2002 to 2013 using two kinds of effective tax rates, set by methods known as macro backward-looking methods (Nicodème 2001), namely, as a percentage of aggregate tax revenues from corporate income in a given country to its GDP (Effective Corporate Income Tax Rates 1 - ECITR1) or to its total tax revenues (ECITR2). A different 5

tracking range of the time span than in the case SCITR is here affected by the availability of the underlying statistical data. The Table 1 shows that the average value of tax rate ECITR1 decreased by 0.4 pp within EU28MS due to a decrease in both groups of MS. In EU15MS this decrease amounted to 0.7 pp (from 3.3% to 2.6%), when in 10 MS has been reported the ECITR1 reduction and in 5 MS its increase on the contrary. In EU13MS the average value of ECITR1 decreased by 0.2 pp (from 2.6% to 2.4%), when the 8 MS showed reduction of ECITR1 and 5 MS its increase. As a result of the higher ECITR1 average value decline in the EU15MS compared to EU13MS, the difference between these values at the end of the reporting period decreased compared to its beginning. This conclusion, however, cannot be universally applied for each MS in both groups, where it showed the considerably different trends. Nevertheless we can say that tax competition between EU15MS and EU13MS had a certain coordinating effect on the corporate income taxation, expressed by rate ECITR1. Fig. 2: The development of ECITR1 and ECITR2 values in EU countries between the years 2002-2013 (Source: Table 1) If we use the effective tax rate ECITR2 for the assessment of the competitive effects in the area of corporate income taxation between EU15MS and EU13MS, then according to the data in Table 1, we can conclude that the average value of this rate have decreased within EU28MS by 1.1 pp (from 8.4% to 7.3%). In EU15MS this decrease amounted to 2.1 pp (from 8.6% 6.5%), when in 13 MS has been reported the ECITR2 reduction and in 2 MS its increase on the contrary. In EU13MS the average value of ECITR2 has increased by 0.1 pp (from 7.5% to 7.6%), when the 8 MS showed reduction of ECITR2 and 5 MS its increase. The average value of ECITR2 in EU15MS in 2002 was by 1.1 pp greater than in the EU13 MS, while in 2013 it was the opposite. From the development of ECITR2 average values in both groups of MS so cannot be deduced that the development of this value in the EU15MS was influenced by the 6

development in the EU13MS. However, we can also observe here the considerably different trends in the development of corporate income tax burden, expressed by ECITR2 rate, in individual Member States in both their groups. Conclusion The comparative analysis showed that the dependence of the development of corporate income tax burden in the EU15MS on development in the EU13MS had a different character according to the used tax rate. Unambiguous dependence has proven by using the statutory tax rates, when the development of their average value showed a significant decrease in both MS groups in the reporting period. However, the evaluation of the tax burden by using the statutory tax rates is not objective because it does not take into account the amount of tax bases neither various tax advantages granted to tax subjects. When using the effective tax rate, determined the percentage of the aggregate corporate income tax revenues to GDP in individual states, is possible assume a certain dependence of the income tax burden corporate in the EU15MS on its development in the EU13MS, although there were only minor changes in both groups of MS. In the case that has been applied the effective tax rate, determined by the percentage of the aggregate revenues of this tax in total tax revenues in individual states, then the development of corporate income tax burden had opposite trend in both groups MS. From the development of this effective tax rate cannot therefore be assumed that the development of the corporate income tax burden in the EU13MS had an influence on its development in a group of EU15MS. The effect of competition in the area of corporate income tax between EU MS should also be reflected in the volume of foreign direct investment (FDI) flows between the EU MS. However, an analysis (Blechová, 2015) shows that FDI trends in the EU in the period 2004 to 2012 showed no functional dependency on the development of both the statutory and the effective corporate income tax rates. Random character of this dependence also does not indicate the harmful impact of the corporate income tax rates development in EU13MS on this development in EU15MS. Far more harmful effect on the development of the corporate income tax burden and on the development of revenues from these taxes in all EU countries have tax jurisdiction, referred to as "tax havens" and "offshore financial centers". References [1] Baldwin, R. E., and P. Krugman, 2004. Agglomeration, integration and tax harmonization, European Economic Review Vol.48 (1). pp.1-23. [2] Blechová, B., 2015. Analysis of dependence FDI flows on the size of corporate income tax rates in EU countries. In the 7th International Scientific Conference Finance and Performance of Firms in Science, Education and Practice. Tomas Bata University in Zlín, Faculty of Management and Economics, pp. 124-136. ISBN 978-80-7454-482-8. [3] Bradford, D., and W.Oates, 1971. The analysis of revenue sharing in a new approach to collective fiscal decisions, Quarterly Journal of Economics Vol. 85 (3), pp. 416-439. [4] Bucovetsky, S., 1991. Asymmetric tax competition, Journal of Urban Economics Vol. 30 (2), pp. 167-181. [5] Eurostat, 2014. Taxation trends in the European Union, Statistical Book, 2014 edition, ISBN 978-92-79-35672-8, ISSN 1831-8789. 7

[6] Eurostat, 2015. Taxation trends in the European Union, Statistical Book, 2015 edition, ISBN 978-92-79-51578-1, ISSN 2467-0073. [7] Konrad, K.A., 2009. Non-binding minimum taxes may foster tax competition. Economics Letters Vol.102 (2), pp. 109-111. [8] Ludema, R.D., and I.Wooton, 2000. Economic geography and the fiscal effects of regional integration, Journal of International Economics Vol. 52 (2), pp. 331-357. [9] Nicodème, G., 2001. Computing effective corporate tax rates: comparison and results. European Commission Directorate General for Economic and Financial Affairs, Economic paper Nr. 153, ECFIN E2/358/01-EN, Brussels, 2001. [10] OECD, 1998. Harmful Tax Competition: An Emerging Global Issue, OECD Publications 2, 1998, ISBN 92-64-16090-6 No. 50097. [11] Stiglitz, J. E., 2002. Jiná cesta k trhu hledání alternativy k současné podobě globalizace (Globalization and its discontents), Praha: Prostor, 2003, ISBN 80-7260-095-8. [12] Tiebout, C., 1956. A pure theory of local expenditures, Journal of Political Economy No 64 (5), The University of Chicago Press, pp. 416-424. [13] Wang Y.Q., 1999. Commodity taxes under fiscal competition: Stackelberg equilibrium and optimality, American Economic Review Vol. 89 (4), pp. 974-981. [14] Wildasin D.E., 1988. Nash equilibria in models of fiscal competition, Journal of Public Economics Vol. 35 (2), pp. 229-240. [15] Wilson, J. D., 1986. A theory of interregional tax competition, Journal of Urban Economics Vol. 19 (3), pp. 296-315. [16] Zodrow, G. R., and P.Mieszkowski, 1986. Pigou, Tiebout, property taxation and the under-provision of local public goods, Journal of Urban Economics Vol. 19 (3), pp. 356-370. 8