minutes of service used. The firm has been changing a single price

Similar documents
Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Marshall and Hicks Understanding the Ordinary and Compensated Demand

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

x. The saver is John Riley 7 December 2016 Econ 401a Final Examination Sketch of answers 1. Choice over time Then Adding,

Solution Problem Set 2

Strategy -1- Strategy

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS

Consumer Surplus and Welfare Measurement (Chapter 14) cont. & Market Demand (Chapter 15)

Answers to Odd-Numbered Problems, 4th Edition of Games and Information, Rasmusen. PROBLEMS FOR CHAPTER 14: Pricing

GE in production economies

3 General Equilibrium in a Competitive Market

the price of a soda is

In the short run, at least, the demand for gasoline is quite inelastic with respect to its own price.

Strategy -1- Strategic equilibrium in auctions

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

Notes on a Basic Business Problem MATH 104 and MATH 184 Mark Mac Lean (with assistance from Patrick Chan) 2011W

Chapter 4. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work- Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization. Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

Open Math in Economics MA National Convention 2017 For each question, E) NOTA indicates that none of the above answers is correct.

Compensation Planning: Current vs. Deferred Salary

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

ECON 311 Fall Quarter, 2009 NAME: Prof. Hamilton. FINAL EXAM 200 points

Mechanism Design: Single Agent, Discrete Types

Problems. units of good b. Consumers consume a. The new budget line is depicted in the figure below. The economy continues to produce at point ( a1, b

Bilateral monopoly in telecommunications: bargaining over fixed-to-mobile termination rates

MONOPOLY (2) Second Degree Price Discrimination

Review of Production Theory: Chapter 2 1

6. Deficits and inflation: seignorage as a source of public sector revenue

A. Introduction to choice under uncertainty 2. B. Risk aversion 11. C. Favorable gambles 15. D. Measures of risk aversion 20. E.

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

The objectives of the producer

Economics 11: Solutions to Practice Final

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress

Answers to June 11, 2012 Microeconomics Prelim

Econ Honors: Midterm 2 (Anthony Yuen) November 14, 2007

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

Perverse General Equilibrium Effects of Price Controls

5 Profit maximization, Supply

UVic Econ 103C with Peter Bell Review for Final Exam Final Lecture

ECONOMICS QUALIFYING EXAMINATION IN ELEMENTARY MATHEMATICS

Economics II - Exercise Session # 3, October 8, Suggested Solution

CHAPTER 2: Optimal Decisions Using Marginal Analysis MULTIPLE CHOICE

Economics 335 Problem Set 6 Spring 1998

ECON 311 Winter Quarter, 2010 NAME: KEY Prof. Hamilton

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

ECO 352 International Trade Spring Term 2010 Week 3 Precepts February 15 Introduction, and The Exchange Model Questions

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, UNIVERSITY OF VICTORIA

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

(Note: Please label your diagram clearly.) Answer: Denote by Q p and Q m the quantity of pizzas and movies respectively.

Eastern Mediterranean University Faculty of Business and Economics Department of Economics Fall Semester. ECON 101 Mid term Exam

Exam A Questions Managerial Economics BA 445. Exam A Version 1

Economics 11: Second Midterm

Economics II - Exercise Session, December 3, Suggested Solution

Lesson-36. Profit Maximization and A Perfectly Competitive Firm

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 3 November 2012

The homework is due on Wednesday, September 7. Each questions is worth 0.8 points. No partial credits.

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy

The application of linear programming to management accounting

Chapter 6. Production. Introduction. Production Decisions of a Firm. Production Decisions of a Firm

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

Math: Deriving supply and demand curves

(0.50, 2.75) (0,3) Equivalent Variation Compensating Variation

Honors General Exam PART 1: MICROECONOMICS. Solutions. Harvard University April 2013

Economics 101 Section 5

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Homework Nonlinear Pricing with Three Types. 2. Downward Sloping Demand I. November 15, 2010

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2008

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

University of Toronto June 22, 2004 ECO 100Y L0201 INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS. Midterm Test #1

Problem Set 3. Part I Multiple Choice

TEACHING STICKY PRICES TO UNDERGRADUATES

ECONS 301 Homework #1. Answer Key

G604 Midterm, March 301, 2003 ANSWERS

Question 1: Productivity, Output and Employment (30 Marks)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

Problem 3,a. ds 1 (s 2 ) ds 2 < 0. = (1+t)

max x + y s.t. y + px = m

MIDTERM #2 VERSION 1

ECO 100Y L0101 INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS. Midterm Test #2

PROBLEM SET 3. Suppose that in a competitive industry with 100 identical firms the short run cost function of each firm is given by: C(q)=16+q 2

ANSWER: We can find consumption and saving by solving:

ECON 103C -- Final Exam Peter Bell, 2014

Practice Problems: First-Year M. Phil Microeconomics, Consumer and Producer Theory Vincent P. Crawford, University of Oxford Michaelmas Term 2010

Competitive Firms in the Long-Run

p 1 _ x 1 (p 1 _, p 2, I ) x 1 X 1 X 2

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Section 2 Solutions. Econ 50 - Stanford University - Winter Quarter 2015/16. January 22, Solve the following utility maximization problem:

The supply function is Q S (P)=. 10 points

ECO401 Quiz # 5 February 15, 2010 Total questions: 15

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

Archimedean Upper Conservatory Economics, October 2016

Transcription:

John Riley Background material for UCLA Case Study 17 April 2016 Introduction to indirect price discrimination 1 A firm with constant marginal cost c has two classes of customers with demand price functions p( 1, q) 1 q and p( 2, q) 2 q There are n 1 type 1 customers and n 2 type 2 customers The quantity q is the weekly minutes of service used The firm has been changing a single price p to maximize its profit You have been invited to give a presentation on the advantages of selling plans with different usage ceilings Plan 1 offers q 1 units per week for a weekly cost of r 1 Plan 2 offer a larger quantity q 2 for a weekly cost of r 2 Preferences over outcomes Regardless of the method that a firm uses to extract revenue from a customer, the two things that the customer ultimately cares about are the quantity consumed and how much this costs We call this the outcome for the customer ( qr, ) Given such an outcome the consumer s utility is u(, q, r) B(, q) r High demanders have a higher marginal benefit p(, q) p(, q) 2 1 Participation constraints A customer will only purchase a plan if the total benefit of the plan exceeds the cost Suppose that the firm offers a single plan ( qr, ) If the firm wants both types of customer to participate then it must be the case that B(, q) r 0 1 and 2 B(, q) r 0 The high demander s benefit from q minutes per week is greater, ie 1 This is often called Second Degree Price Discrimination However the early literature is not at all clear on the meaning of second degree This name was popularized and possibly coined my McAfee

B(, q) B(, q) 2 1 Therefore if the goal is to sell to both types of customer, the only binding participation constraint is B(, q) r 0 1 If the firm wants to sell only to the high demanders then the participation constraint is B(, q) r 0 2 To begin, we consider the latter case For any choice of minutes q the firm can raise the weekly fee until the participation constraint is (almost) binding Consider any plan below ( qr ˆ, ˆ) The benefit to the high demander is the area under his demand curve This is shown The firm extracts all the surplus by charging r B( ˆ 2, q) The total cost is cq ˆ Thus the profit is the diagonally shaded region Figure 11: Demand price and total benefit From Figure 11 it is clear that the firm can do even better by increasing the minutes to * q where the demand price (marginal benefit) is equal to marginal cost 2

Two plans If the number of low demand customers is sufficiently large, it will not be profit maximizing to sell only to high demanders Instead the firm offers two plans ( q1, r1) and ( q, r ) 2 2 where q q 2 1 Participation constraint: As argued above we need only consider the participation constraint of the low demand customer B(, q ) r 0 1 1 1 Who purchase the high minute plan? The low demanders will purchase the plan if B(, q ) r B(, q ) r, 1 2 2 1 1 1 That is, the difference in benefit exceeds the difference in plan cost B(, q ) B(, q ) r r 1 2 1 1 2 1 The increased benefit is depicted below The high demanders have higher demand price functions and thus value a bigger plan more Therefore B(, q ) B(, q ) r r implies that B( 2, q2) B( 2, q1 ) r2 r1 1 2 1 1 2 1 We therefore have our first important conclusion Conclusion 1: If the two types of customers purchase different plans, the low types must purchase the low unit plan and the high demanders must purchase the high unit plan 3

Incentive constraints The low demanders must prefer the small plan Equivalently, B(, q ) r B(, q ) r, 1 1 1 1 2 2 B(, q ) B(, q ) r r 1 2 1 1 2 1 For the high demanders the extra benefit from the high plan must be bigger than the extra cost Thus the two incentive constraints and the participation constraint are as follows: B(, q ) B(, q ) r r B(, q ) B(, q ) incentive constraints 2 2 2 1 2 1 1 2 1 1 B(, q ) r 0 participation constraint 1 1 1 Conclusion 2: To maximize profit the participation constraint must be binding To see why this is true, note that we can increase both r 1 and r 2 without affecting the incentive constraints As we do so revenue rises Therefore we continue to do so until the participation constraint is binding Conclusion 3: To maximize profit the high demander must be indifferent between the two plans To understand this, suppose that we increase r 2 until the incentive constraint for the high demander is binding This increases revenue It also relaxes the other incentive constraint We can now use these results to solve for the profit-maximizing plan From conclusion 1 we know that q2 q1 From conclusion 2 we know that all the surplus is extracted from the low demander So the profit is the dotted area in the left figure If the high demander purchases the low plan his benefit is greater His net gain is the diagonally shaded area 4

Figure 13: Profit on each plan Now look at the right figure The total surplus is the sum of the diagonally shaded and dotted areas The diagonally shaded region cannot be extracted because that would reduce the high demanders benefit below his payoff from purchasing the low minute plan Therefore the maximized total profit in each plan are the dotted regions Figure 14: Total profit on each plan 5

Using the same argument as when there was only one plan, more profit can be extracted from high demanders by offering a bigger pan and then extracting additional surplus This is shown in Figure 14 The remaining step is to consider the impact of increasing the number of minutes in the low plan The left figure below shows the extra profit made on low demanders (the dotted area) and the extra surplus high demanders receive if they switch to the low plan with its increased minutes (the diagonally shaded area) Since the high demanders like the new low plan more, the firm cannot extract as much from them in the high plan Let the increased profit be on each low type be 1 and let the increased surplus to high types if they switch be S 2 With n 1 low types and n 2 high types, the net change in profit is n n s 1 1 2 2 Figure 1-5: Marginal benefit and marginal cost of increasing minutes in plan 1 p(, q ) p(, q ) 1 p( 1, q1 ) c 2 2 1 1 1 6

Note that as ˆq 1 gets larger, the extra profit from further increases in minutes, 1 declines towards zero So it is never profit-maximizing to increase demand price (marginal benefit) is equal to marginal cost q 1 to the output where the For efficiency, marginal benefit and marginal cost must be equated This is the case for high demanders However low demanders are undersupplied The net change in profit can be rewritten as follows: n n n n s n ( s ) n [ ( p(, q ) c) ( p(, q ) p(, q ))] q) 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 1 2 2 1 1 2 1 1 1 n2 n2 Therefore, as the proportion of low demanders falls, the profits made from customers with low demands become relatively less important so the profit-maximizing q 1 falls If the ratio n / n gets sufficiently small, it is best to squeeze them out of the market completely Then the firm can extract all the surplus from the high demanders 1 2 7