EMU's Fiscal Rules and Economic Stabilization. Abstract

Similar documents
Estimation of the Mechanisms for Automatic Fiscal Stabilization. The Romanian Case

Comment on Beetsma, Debrun and Klaassen: Is fiscal policy coordination in EMU desirable? Marco Buti *

FISCAL POLICY IN THE EUROPEAN MONETARY UNION: HOW CAN FISCAL DISCIPLINE BE ACHIEVED? ***

FISCAL FORECASTS OF THE AUSTRIAN FISCAL ADVISORY COUNCIL: FORECASTING PRINCIPLES AND METHODS 1 1 PRINCIPLES, FORECAST PERIOD AND UNDERLYING DATA

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Budgetary policy in EMU: times to change?

Reforms in a Debt Overhang

Estimating a Fiscal Reaction Function for Greece

Business Cycles and Public Finances

The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 2001

UK membership of the single currency

FISCAL POLICY COOPERATION IN EMU: LITERATURE REVIEW

Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles. Abstract

What Explains Growth and Inflation Dispersions in EMU?

The Coordination of Fiscal Policies in Europe

The Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence is Zero

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

Macroeconomic stabilisation policies in the EMU: Spillovers, asymmetries, and institutions

Economic analysis from the European Commission s Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs

Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018

Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence at an Inflation-Targeting Central Bank

European Fiscal Rules Require a Major Overhaul

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

Bank Capital, Agency Costs, and Monetary Policy. Césaire Meh Kevin Moran Department of Monetary and Financial Analysis Bank of Canada

What we know about monetary policy

Stability and Growth Pact: An Index to Trigger an Early Warning Earlier? Thierry Warin. January 2005

Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

Optimum Monetary Policy in European Monetary Union

Groupe de Recherche en Économie et Développement International. Cahier de recherche / Working Paper 09-02

1 What does sustainability gap show?

THE TRADEOFF BETWEEN EFFICIENCY AND MACROECONOMIC STABILIZATION

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom

Probably Too Little, Certainly Too Late. An Assessment of the Juncker Investment Plan

ESCB Sovereign Debt Sustainability Analysis: a methodological framework

EMU G overnance: Governance: Fiscal Fiscal Policy

Market Reforms in a Monetary Union: Macroeconomic and Policy Implications

The Real Business Cycle Model

The short run costs of a reduction in tax distortions in a monetary union

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Volume 35, Issue 4. Real-Exchange-Rate-Adjusted Inflation Targeting in an Open Economy: Some Analytical Results

Macroprudential Policy Implementation in a Heterogeneous Monetary Union

Monetary and Fiscal Policy

Fiscal issues and central bank policy in the Czech Republic

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools

Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy in A Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Phillips Curve

On Euro: A Stabilisation Role of Monetary Policy Revisited

Financial Integration in the Arab Region: A Focus on Monetary Coordination and a Presentation of New Ideas and Developments by:

Monetary Policy and Resource Mobility

Suggested Solutions to Assignment 7 (OPTIONAL)

Frequency of Price Adjustment and Pass-through

GHG Emissions Control and Monetary Policy

Inflation Stabilization and Default Risk in a Currency Union. OKANO, Eiji Nagoya City University at Otaru University of Commerce on Aug.

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

The Eurozone Debt Crisis: A New-Keynesian DSGE model with default risk

PUBLIC FINANCE IN THE EU: FROM THE MAASTRICHT CONVERGENCE CRITERIA TO THE STABILITY AND GROWTH PACT

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Has the Inflation Process Changed?

L9. Choice of the Exchange Rate Regime and the Optimum Currency Area

II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 )

Interest Rate Smoothing and Calvo-Type Interest Rate Rules: A Comment on Levine, McAdam, and Pearlman (2007)

INVESTMENT AND THE GOLDEN RULE IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

Article published in the Quarterly Review 2014:2, pp

What determines government spending multipliers?

Monetary Macroeconomics & Central Banking Lecture /

The Zero Lower Bound

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability

Y t )+υ t. +φ ( Y t. Y t ) Y t. α ( r t. + ρ +θ π ( π t. + ρ

Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies

Is the Maastricht debt limit safe enough for Slovakia?

Fiscal frameworks in Europe: Striking the right balance between centralisation and decentralisation

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules

Monetary Policy and Resource Mobility

Fiscal policy coordination in the European Monetary Union. Lecture Udine May 30. Giovanni Di Bartolomeo. University of Teramo Faculty of Communication

Does globalization enhance the role of fiscal policy in economic stabilization? Abstract

Volume 29, Issue 1. Juha Tervala University of Helsinki

Structural budget balance and fiscal policy stance in Tunisia

The Employment and Output Effects of Short-Time Work in Germany

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

Monetary Policy and Medium-Term Fiscal Planning

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

Monetary Policy, Financial Stability and Interest Rate Rules Giorgio Di Giorgio and Zeno Rotondi

Lecture 1: Traditional Open Macro Models and Monetary Policy

The reform of EU s fiscal rules: between centralisation and decentralisation

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Chapter II: Labour Market Policy

Schäuble versus Tsipras: a New-Keynesian DSGE Model with Sovereign Default for the Eurozone Debt Crisis

FINANCIAL REPRESSION AND LAFFER CURVES

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

On the Merits of Conventional vs Unconventional Fiscal Policy

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 11. The Smets-Wouters Model

Transcription:

EMU's Fiscal Rules and Economic Stabilization Christophe Schalck EconomiX, University of Paris X Abstract This paper proposes a quantitative comparison of EMU's different fiscal rules, i.e., the stability and growth Pact, the structural deficit rule and the golden rule. From comparing the economic stabilizing effects of each rule, it concludes that the Pact is not the perfect solution. This paper has benefited from constructive comments from Kevin Beaubrun Diant and Michel Boutillier. All remaining erros are mine. Citation: Schalck, Christophe, (2006) "EMU's Fiscal Rules and Economic Stabilization." Economics Bulletin, Vol. 5, No. 4 pp. 1 8 Submitted: October 25, 2005. Accepted: February 21, 2006. URL: http://www.economicsbulletin.com/2006/volume5/eb 05E60006A.pdf

1 Introduction SinceEMUmembershaveforegonetheuseofnationalmonetaryandexchange rate policies as adjustment mechanisms, they are now searching for alternative ways that can protect them from economic shocks. It is usually recognized that this role should be assigned to fiscal policies. The framework for EU fiscal policy is defined by the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) which requires member States to maintain a fiscal position of close to balance or surplus over the cycle, and never to exceed the 3% of GDP ceiling. The EU s current long economic slowdown and the subsequent deterioration of public finances well beyond the 3% limit have heightened the debate over whether the SGP is an appropriate framework for EMU fiscal policy. The paper deliberately avoids joining the debate but rather chooses to focus on the reform proposals presently under discussion, i.e., the balanced structural budget and the golden rule. The main advantage of the structural deficit ruleisthatitprovidestheincreased flexibility that allows room for the automatic stabilizers to operate fully. In the golden rule, government budgets are to be split into a current budget which must be in balance, and an investment budget which has to be financed through borrowing. The rule is meant to boost the economy s potential growth rate by encouraging higher public investment. This paper aims to rank the reform proposals and the SGP in terms of their relative performance in economic stabilization. Various studies have compare these rules (Buti and al. 2003, Creel 2003). However these studies have used the Kopitz and Symansky model (2001) which implies subjective judgments. We therefore propose to carry out a comparative study based on macroeconomic modeling. The main results show that alternative rules have the same economic stabilization impact and are more efficient than the Pact. The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 develops the analytical framework, Section 3 presents the solution method, Section 4 presents a numerical simulation of the model, and the final section concludes. 2 The Model We use a static model of closed monetary union with two countries i and j in which we introduce an asymmetric demand shock 1. Demand is given by classical terms of literature (Buti and al., 2002): public deficit (d), common interest rate (r), and trade balance include intra-eu competitiveness (defined of inflation differential) 1 We consider only demand shocks because efficiency of fiscal policy to counter supply shocks is widely argued (Brunila and al., 2002). 1

and differences in economic situations. Demand can be written as follows: y d i = γd i ρr + η(y j y i )+ηε(π j π i )+x i (1) where y represents GDP, γ the sensibility of demand to public deficit, ρ the sensibility of demand to interest rate, η the measure of the countries relative openness, ε the elasticity of trade balance to the inflation differential, π the inflation rate and x the asymmetric demand shock. Variables are in logarithms and expressed as deviations from their long-run non-inflationary equilibrium. All the parameters are positive. Because of nominal rigidities, output and prices can diverge from their equilibrium values in the short run. This situation is rendered using a Phillips curve as supply function (Leith and Wren-Lewis, 2002): π i = θy i + η(π j π i ) θ [0; 1] (2) We assume that the European Central Bank (ECB), uses the interest rate as a the tool for conducting its monetary policy. The aim of monetary policy is to minimize a linear-quadratic loss function (LM) which depends on average values. Price stability is the main objective of the single monetary policy. The implications is that inflation is more heavily weighted in the loss function than others variables 2. The monetary loss function can therefore be written as follows: LM = 1 π 2 + β 2 1 y 2 + β 2 r 2 (3) where β 1 and β 2 respectively capture the relative preferences for output stabilization and interest rate smoothing. The behaviour of each government in the monetary union is described by a linearquadratic loss function (LG) which depends on its output deviation of the baseline, its rate of inflation, and its public deficit. Fiscal rules are modelized by a financial penalty f that increases the fiscal loss function. This financial penalty depends on the spread between the actual public deficit and its target: LG i = 1 y 2 2 i + φ 1 π 2 i + φ 2 d 2 i + f(di d) e (4) where φ 1 and φ 2 are the weights of the inflation rate and public deficit in the fiscal loss function, and d e is the deficit target. 2 It must be noted that an extra term has been added to the interest rate in the loss function compare to traditional models. The simulations run on monetary policy rules indeed show that optimal rules lead to an excessive volatility of interest rate, although this situation is not due to the Central Bank s behaviour. The solution then consists to include the interest rate in the loss function (Rudebush and Svensson, 1998). 2

Supply and demand functions allow to determine output and inflation: y i = γd i ρr + Ωγ(d j d i )+(1 2Ω) x i (5) π i = θγd i θρr + θ(ω + µ)γ(d j d i )+θ(1 2(Ω + µ)) x i (6) 1+2η) η (1+ εθ η 1+2η 1+2η(1+ εθ with Ω = 1+2η(1+ 1 2η), µ =. Parameters Ω and µ can be interpreted εθ 1+2η) as the trade balance on output and prices. Both economies are connected by a number of channels through which price and output fluctuations spread across the two EMU member countries. 3 Model Solving 3.1 Solution method We consider that governments internalize the Central Bank behaviour when making their own decisions. Indeed, if they take the single monetary policy s credible commitment to maintain price stability for granted, the alignment of expectations will be enhanced and behaviour conditioned in a way which will lead to implicit coordinated policy outcomes, while concurrently limiting policy conflicts and overall economic uncertainty (Issing, 2002). In order to modelize this situation we use a Stakelberg game in which governments are the leaders and the ECB the follower. Firstly, each government makes its own decision, it also accepts the other governments behaviours as given and takes accounts ECB s function reaction. Then the ECB makes decision considering the governments decisions as given. The resolution of such a game is made by backward induction. 3.2 Interest rate determination The interest rate is determined by the ECB s behaviour. We define the interest rate by minimizing monetary loss function: r = 1 2 ψγ(d i + d j ) (7) with ψ = ρ (θ 2 +β 1 ). The interest rate rises with the average amount of public deficit. Consequently monetary policy depends on fiscal policy, which means ρ 2 (θ 2 +β 1 )+β 2 financial eviction does occur. 3

3.3 Key variables The expression of interest rate allows us to express output and inflation from public deficits and the shock: y i = ad i + bd j + cx i (8) π i = θ (a γµ) d i + θ (b + γµ) d j + θ (c 2µ) x i (9) with a = γ 1γρψ γω, b= γω 1 γρψ, c =1 2Ω. Parameter a capture the net 2 2 impact of fiscal deficit on output. This impact depends on the sensibility of demand to public deficit (γ), interest rate ( 1 γρψ) and trade balance (Ω). Parameter b is the 2 fiscal externality depending on effect on the interest rate and the trade balance. 3.4 Disaggregate public deficit The public deficit can be broken down into three elements: the primary structural deficit, noted d s, consists of the whole set of fiscal discretionary measures which are not apriorimotivated by macroeconomic regulation. This primary structural deficit is made up of the current deficit and public capital expenditures, in proportion h. the cyclical deficit which depends of the economic situation according to sensibility χ. It includes the automatic stabilizers and discretionary measures. interest payment of the public debt (B). From the public deficit breakdown it becomes possible to identify two different targets: the structural balance corresponds to the primary structural deficit, the golden rule is the current deficit. The golden rule stipulates that capital expenditures are financed by loan, which consequently increases the interest burden. The public deficit is written as follows: d =(1 h)d s χy + r(1 + h)b (10) Macroeconomic equilibria are derived from the minimization of the fiscal loss functions and from the public deficit breakdown. 4

4 Numerical Simulation We considere that stabilization consists in reducing the shock impact on welfare losses. We study fiscal stabilization within the model when a negative asymmetric shock occurs (1% of GDP). The sensibility of demand to public deficit on demand is suggested by Bouthevillain and al. (2001). Interest rate sensitivity is issued from Mojon and Peersman (2001). Penalty value f corresponds to the variable part of the Pact financial sanction, i.e. a tenth of the fiscal overrun. Deficit sensitivity to the cycle, debt level and public investment growth are the euro zones average values. The others parameters are issued from Engwerda and al. (2002). They will allow the determination of foreign trade influence (Ω and µ). The set of parameters is givenintablei. Table I. Parameter Values γ ρ η ε θ β 1 β 2 φ 1 φ 2 f h χ B Ω µ 0.75 0.2 0.4 0.5 0.25 0.2 0.25 0.5 0.25 0.1 0.1 0.5 0.6 0.23 0.03 The set of parameters above allows determination impact of interest rate (ψ), public deficit (a), fiscal externality (b) and shock(c). These parameters vary according to which rule is observed, either the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP), the structural deficit rule (SDR) or the golden rule (GR). Parameters are gathered in Table II. Table II. Impact Parameter Values SGP SDR GR ψ 0.201-0.134-0.156 a 0.562 0.411 0.368 b 0.158 0.117 0.104 c 0.539 0.392 0.392 From the public deficit breakdown, it is possible to consider the positive effect of interest payment on demand. These payment decrease the interest rate s negative influence on national product because payment constitutes an additional income for the agents. It consequently modifies the sign of the interest rate impact as interest rate sensitivity is weaker than interest payment (ρ < γb). The structural fiscal rules therefore allow for a consistent policy mix since fiscal activism does not implie a tight monetary policy. The public deficit impact on product (a), fiscal externality (b) and the asymmetrical shock impact on product (c) are weaker than with the SGP. This is mainly due to the role of the automatic stabilizers which absorb part 5

of the shock propagation. Strong growth in public investment can also decrease the width of golden rule s parameters. Simulation results for deficit, product, inflation and fiscal loss can be found in Table III. The results depend on fiscal rule is actually observed. Table III. Results SGP SDR GR d 0.491 0.442 0.381 y -0.340-0.260-0.291 π -0.076-0.058-0.065 LG 0.228 0.162 0.164 Values are variable reactions to a negative shock. deficit is the effective deficit for the SGP, the structural deficit for SDR, and the current deficit for the GR. Since public deficits are counter-cyclical, they evolve in the opposite direction to the shock. Deficit reactions are weaker when the structural rules are observed. They react only to the part of the shock which has not been absorbed by the cyclical deficit. As the golden rule does not take account of public investment, current deficit is weaker than the structural deficit. The risk is then that governments may substitute public expenditure for current expenditure so as to abide by the golden rule. Fiscal impact parameters (a and b) anddeficit reactions are lower with the structural rules than with the SGP. Fluctuations of the national products are consequently weaker, which means better stabilization. The same considerations apply to inflation. It results from this that the SGP is dominated by the structural rules since the shock has greater overall impact on the fiscal loss. The structural deficit rule generate a slightly weaker loss than the golden rule but the future repercussions of the golden rule on public investments also need consideration. 5 Conclusion The objective of this paper is to provide a comparison between the Stability and Growth Pact and the structural rules (the structural deficit rule and the golden rule) in terms of stabilization performance. We used the same framework for all rules and noted that the structural rules lead to better stabilization. Consequently, the application of such rules through a reform of the SGP would be desirable in the EU. The reform of the Pact in March 2005 already constitutes a first step towards the golden rule. 6

The right target obviously needs to be struck between simplicity and effectiveness. Although the structural rules seem more effective, especially towards achieving fiscal stabilization, they also appear more complex than the Pact. Moreover, the application of these rules implies an harmonization of the evaluation techniques. The determination of potential growth must be clarified too. The golden rule also calls a clear definition of public investment and how it can be measured. These conditions must be met so the transparency of the rules can be guaranteed. References [1] Bouthevillain C., Cour-Thimann P., Van den Dool G., Hernandez de Cos P., Langenus G., Mohr M., Momigliano S., Tujula M. (2001) Cyclically adjusted budget balances: an alternative approach ECB Working Paper, n 77. [2] Brunila A., Buti M., Veld J. (2002) Fiscal Policy in Europe: How effective are automatic stabilizers European Commission Working Paper n 177. [3] Buti M., Martinez-Mongway C., Sekkat K., Van den Noord P. (2002) Automatic Stabilisers and Market Flexibility in EMU: Is there a Trade-off? OECD Economic Department Working Paper n 335. [4] Buti M., Eijffinger S.C., Franco D. (2003) Revisiting the SGP: Grand Design or Internal Adjustment? CEPR Discussion Paper n 3692. [5] Creel J. (2003) Ranking Fiscal Policy Rules: the Golden Rule of Public Finance vs the Stability and Growth Pact OFCE Working Paper n 2003 04. [6] Engwerda J, Van Aarle B, Plasmans J (2002) Cooperative and non-cooperative fiscal policies in the EMU Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 26, 451-481. [7] Issing O. (2002). On Macroeconomic Policy Co-ordination in EMU Journal of Common Market Studies, 40(2), 345-358 [8] Kopitz G., Symansky S. (1998) Fiscal Policy Rules IMF Occasional Paper n 162 [9] Leith C., Wren-Lewis S. (2000) Interactions between monetary and fiscal policy rules The Economic Journal, 110, 93-108. [10] Mojon B., Peersman G. (2001) A VAR description of the effects of the monetary policy in the euro zone ECB Working Paper n 94. 7

[11] Rudebush G., Svensson J. (1998) Policy Rules for Inflation Targeting NBER Working Paper, n 6512. 8