Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure

Similar documents
Ambiguous Information and Trading Volume in stock market

1 Dynamic programming

Mathematics in Finance

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2013 D. Romer

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Lecture 3: Return vs Risk: Mean-Variance Analysis

MODELLING OPTIMAL HEDGE RATIO IN THE PRESENCE OF FUNDING RISK

Limits to Arbitrage. George Pennacchi. Finance 591 Asset Pricing Theory

Lecture 4: Return vs Risk: Mean-Variance Analysis

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

Dynamic Trading and Asset Prices: Keynes vs. Hayek

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS. Private and public information

Conditional Value-at-Risk, Spectral Risk Measures and (Non-)Diversification in Portfolio Selection Problems A Comparison with Mean-Variance Analysis

Universal Properties of Financial Markets as a Consequence of Traders Behavior: an Analytical Solution

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Advanced Macroeconomics I ECON 525a - Fall 2009 Yale University

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

Agent Based Trading Model of Heterogeneous and Changing Beliefs

Economics 430 Handout on Rational Expectations: Part I. Review of Statistics: Notation and Definitions

Estimating a Dynamic Oligopolistic Game with Serially Correlated Unobserved Production Costs. SS223B-Empirical IO

Are Bitcoin Prices Rational Bubbles *

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation

An Agent-Based Simulation of Stock Market to Analyze the Influence of Trader Characteristics on Financial Market Phenomena

M. R. Grasselli. ORFE - Princeton University, April 4, 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

GRANULARITY ADJUSTMENT FOR DYNAMIC MULTIPLE FACTOR MODELS : SYSTEMATIC VS UNSYSTEMATIC RISKS

The Effect of Speculative Monitoring on Shareholder Activism

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 8 May 2001

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 5: Mean-variance portfolio theory

D.1 Sufficient conditions for the modified FV model

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Macroeconomics of Financial Markets

Combining Real Options and game theory in incomplete markets.

The Impact of Macroeconomic Uncertainty on Commercial Bank Lending Behavior in Barbados. Ryan Bynoe. Draft. Abstract

ASSET PRICING AND WEALTH DYNAMICS AN ADAPTIVE MODEL WITH HETEROGENEOUS AGENTS

Price Drift as an Outcome of Differences in Higher-Order Beliefs

Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser.

FE570 Financial Markets and Trading. Stevens Institute of Technology

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II

Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models. Preliminary Lecture Notes

Influence of Real Interest Rate Volatilities on Long-term Asset Allocation

The investment game in incomplete markets

Andreas Wagener University of Vienna. Abstract

Markets Do Not Select For a Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards Risk

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 23 Nov 2017

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

The investment game in incomplete markets.

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

COMBINING FAIR PRICING AND CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS

Slides III - Complete Markets

Fund Flows and Asset Prices: A Baseline Model

Liquidity and Risk Management

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

M. R. Grasselli. Imperial College London, March 09, Mathematics and Statistics - McMaster University Joint work with O. Ismail and B.

Asian Economic and Financial Review EMPIRICAL TESTING OF EXCHANGE RATE AND INTEREST RATE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS IN CHINA

Why Do Agency Theorists Misinterpret Market Monitoring?

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms

Working Paper October Book Review of

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem

Risk Tolerance. Presented to the International Forum of Sovereign Wealth Funds

Strategic Trading of Informed Trader with Monopoly on Shortand Long-Lived Information

Relationship between Stock Market Return and Investor Sentiments: A Review Article

Overlapping Correlation Coefficient

Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles

Key Moments in the Rouwenhorst Method

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Optimal Hedge Ratio and Hedging Effectiveness of Stock Index Futures Evidence from India

Mean-Variance Optimal Portfolios in the Presence of a Benchmark with Applications to Fraud Detection

Risk Management and Time Series

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix

Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell. Midterm 2014 Suggested Solutions. TA: B. B. Deng

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

EFFICIENT MARKETS HYPOTHESIS

Market Size Matters: A Model of Excess Volatility in Large Markets

A NEW NOTION OF TRANSITIVE RELATIVE RETURN RATE AND ITS APPLICATIONS USING STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Burhaneddin İZGİ

Advanced Financial Economics Homework 2 Due on April 14th before class

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

Transcription:

Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure Yosuke Kimura Graduate School of Economics, The University of Tokyo March 20, 2017 Abstract This paper considers the relationship between stock return processes and stock ownership structures. We employ two types investors: Longhorizon investors and short-horizon investors. We characterize the shorthorizon investors as the investors who face the volatile exogenous fund flows. Therefore, they trade stocks by non-fundamental reason. This flow-driven trading influence the stock return process. Our result shows that the rises in the proportion of short-term investors and in the correlation between fund flows across short-term investors increase stock return volatility. Keywords: Structure Fund Flow; Short-term Investors; Volatility; Ownership JEL Classification Numbers: This paper is a revised version of a chapter of my Ph.D thesis. e-mail: y.kimura1009@gmail.com 1

1 Introduction Investment horizon is heterogeneous among investors: From seconds to several years. Also, the ownership structure of financial assets is different from each other. For example, some assets are held by mostly short-term investors, other assets are held by long-term investors. Topics on investment horizons have attracted attention because the heterogeneity has large impact on asset price dynamics. This paper considers the relationship between stock return processes and stock ownership structures. Some empirical studies examine the relationship between investors horizon and asset price dynamics. Cella et al. (2013) shows that during the recent episodes of market turmoils, institutional investors with short trading horizons sell their stock-holdings to a larger amount than institutional investors with longer trading horizons. This create price pressure for stocks held mostly by short-term investors, which induce larger price decline, and subsequent reversals, than stocks held mostly by long-term investors. Greenwood and Thesmar (2011) investigate the relationship between the share-holders structure and non-fundamental risk. They define an asset to be fragile if it is susceptible to non-fundamental shifts in demand. An asset can be fragile because of concentrated ownership, or because its owners face correlated or volatile liquidity shocks.(greenwood and Thesmar, 2011, p.471) Bushee and Noe (2000) investigate the relationship between firm s disclosure practices, the ownership composition of its institutional investor and its stock return volatility. Some empirical studies on asset return volatility also suggest that het- 2

erogeneous investment horizons have influence of the volatility dynamics. Heterogeneous Market Hypothesis states that market participants have different investment horizons (see, Müller et al., 1997; Lynch et al., 2003; Corsi, 2009). Corsi (2009) introduces the autoregressive model of realized volatility with three different time horizons: day, week and month. The model can reproduce empirically observed regularity, for example, fat-tails of return distributions and volatility clustering, and have a superior forecasting power of future volatility. The model presumes that investors have expectations about volatility which is calculated by using past return data in different time intervals. The interaction of heterogeneous expectations about volatility create long-memory processes of realized volatility. What determines the composition of investment horizons? Amihud and Mendelson (1986) explain the allocation of assets which have different transaction costs (i.e., liquidity) to investors portfolios. Investors who have long holding periods tend to hold illiquid assets. Moreover, short-term investors trade assets based on the non-fundamental component such as the expectations about actions of other traders. Bernardo and Welch (2004) explain a run on a financial market. In their model, investors may suffer from a liquidity shock and thus conjectures that other investor intend to sell assets cause a market run. Morris and Shin (2004) introduce the model with short and long-term traders and selling asset by short-term traders with loss limit increases the other traders incentives to sell. In addition, some researchers investigate theoretical models that shorthorizon investors have several impacts on asset prices(for example, Froot et al., 1992; Allen et al., 2006; Banerjee et al., 2009). If the holding period 3

is shorter, the beliefs of others rather than long-term fundamentals become more central to investment decisions. The difference between long-term and short-term investors exists in formation of expectations. Keynes (1936) introduce the metaphor Beauty Contest for explaining the nature of asset markets. Keynes explains the importance of higher-order expectations: Investors attempt to expect how the crowd will behave. Some theoretical models study the implications of higherorder expectations Allen et al. (2006) and Banerjee et al. (2009). The other source of heterogeneous investment horizons is investors funding structures. If investors rely on the relatively volatile funds, they have more possibility to trade by non-fundamental fund-flow. It is important to analyze the price impact of flow-driven trading because it generates the other risk of stocks (see Greenwood and Thesmar (2011) for empirical findings). Our analysis is related to the literature of limits to arbitrage to originate with Shleifer and Vishny (1997), which demonstrates the importance of demand shocks on asset prices and returns. In the traditional finance paradigm, demand shocks are absorbed by arbitrageurs, who can use sophisticated trading strategies to ensure that assets remain at their correct price. Shleifer (2000) states that [w]hen, in contrast, the arbitrageur manages other people s money, and his investors do not know or understand exactly what he is doing, they only observe him losing money when prices move further out of line. They may infer from this loss that the arbitrageur is not as competent as they previously thought, refuse to provide him with more capital, and even withdraw some of the capital although the expected return from the trade has increased. 4

In the next section, we model the economy with two assets and two types of investors. One of the investors is short-term investors. They form the optimal portfolios by investing wealth but they face the risk of exogenous fund flows. Another type is long term-investors. Unlike the short-term investors, we assume that they have stable funding structures. In summary, short-term investors rely on relatively volatile and short-term funding although longterm investors have stable and long-term funding. Under this condition, we find that the return variance become larger than the absence of the fund flows. 2 The Model We construct a discrete time model in which investors trade two assets at time t = 0, 1, 2. We assume that there exist two assets: a risky asset in finite supply with a random terminal price P 2 and a risk-free asset in infinitely elastic supply with a payoff of r f. Stock trades occur at time period t = 0 and t = 1. There are N investors in this economy and they are grouped into two types of investors: Short-term investors and long-term investors. Short-term investors face the risk of redemption of their capital. They can suffer a wealth shock at time 1. In contrast to short-term traders, long-term investors face no funding risks. This means that their funds are stable. We denote N S as the number of short-term investors and N L as one of long-term investors. 5

In this economy, the stock return is defined as R t = P t P t 1 P t 1 for t = 1, 2. (1) Each investor has the mean-variance utility function for portfolio return. 1 E t [U i ] = E t [R p t+1] γ 2 V ar t[r p t+1] (2) where R p t+1 = α i,t R t+1 + (1 α i,t )r f. (3) In Eq.(3), α i,t is the proportion of the stock holding. At each time period t, each investor optimize their expected utility E[U i (R p t+1)]. max α i,t E t [U i (R p t+1)] = E t [R p t+1] γ 2 V ar t[r p t+1] (4) where E t [R p t+1] = αe t [R t+1 ] + (1 α)r f, V ar t [R p t+1] = α 2 V ar(r t ). (5) From Eq.(4) and (5), we obtain the proportion of the optimal stock holding: α i,t = E t[r t+1 ] r f γv ar t (R t+1 ). (6) Eq. (6) says that an investor allocates the proportion α of his wealth to stocks. Defining h i,t as an investor i s demand for a risky asset, by using Eq. 1 This specification approximates the maximization problem of the power-type utility with terminal wealth. 6

(6), h i,t = α t W i,t P t. (7) We assume that the supply of risky asset is fixed and normalized to 1. By using Eq.(6), the market clearing condition implies N h i,t = N α t W i,t P t = 1 (8) Therefore, we can obtain the market clearing price function: P t = N αt W i,t for t = 0, 1. (9) Eq. (9) suggests that the market clearing price P t and the wealth of investors {W 1,t,..., W N,t } are determined simultaneously. The homogeneous expectations assumption implies the identical optimal proportion of stock holding αt. We also assume that beliefs of investors are stationary or time-invariant. Assumption 1. Investors form the expectation and variance of stock return as follows: E t [R t+1 ] = µ and V ar t (R t+1 ) = σ 2. (10) This assumption implies that the optimal proportion of risky asset is fixed, that is, α t = α = µ r γσ 2 (11) At time t, short-term traders may face the exogenous fund flows and they may be forced to liquidate (or expand) their portfolios. The wealth of 7

investor i evolves from time 0 to 1 as the following: W i,1 = W i,0 (1 + R p 1 + X i ), (12) where X i is the exogenous fund flows into short term investor i. We assume that exogenous fund flows are correlated across investors. Assumption 2 (Correlated Fund Flows). We assume that short-term investors face the exogenous fund flows X i at time t and fund flows are correlated across all short-term investors. Furthermore, we assume that fund flows X i are specified as the following stochastic process: X i = ρy + 1 ρz i (13) where Y and Z i for all i are mutually independent normal random variables with mean zero and variance σ 2 X. Eq.(13) implies that E[X i ] = 0 and V ar(x i ) = σ 2 X for all i. The correlation coefficient of fund flows is obtained as follows: Cov(X i, X j ) = Cov( ρy + 1 ρz i, ρy + 1 ρz j ) = E[( ρy + 1 ρz i )( ρy t + 1 ρz j )] (14) = ρσ 2 X and then Corr(X i, X j ) = Cov(X i, X j ) V ar(xi )V ar(x j ) = ρ. (15) Y is a systematic factor that affect all short-horizon investors and Z i is an 8

idiosyncratic factor. Let define total wealth in the economy as W t N W i,t and the investor i s proportion of wealth as Hence, the total wealth evolves as w i,t W i,t W t. (16) W 1 W 0 = = N S +N L N W S i,1 +N L = W 0 N S +N L w i,0 [1 + R1] p + w i,0 X i w i,0 [1 + R p 1 + X i ] = 1 + R p 1 + w i,0 X i (17) Let define the weighted sum of fund flow shocks as follows: X S w i,0 X i. Given the proportions of wealth of short-term investors {w i,0 } N S, X S is a random variable that has normal distribution with zero mean and variance V ar 0 (X S ) = σ 2 X[ρφ 2 0 + (1 ρ)λ 0 ] where φ 0 = N S w i,0 and λ 0 = N S w2 i,0 By Eq. (9) and the definition W t, for time t = 0 and t = 1, we obtain α W 0 = P 0 (18) 9

and α W 1 = P 1. (19) According to these expressions, we obtain W 1 W 0 = P 1 P 0. (20) One can obtain from Eq. (17) and (20), P 1 P 0 = 1 + R 1 = 1 + R p 1 + N w i,0 X i (21) Replacing the portfolio return R p t by (3), we obtain 1 + R 1 = 1 + α R 1 + (1 α )r f + N w i,0 X i. (22) Solving for R t from (22) and the assumption of X i,t gives R 1 = r f + 1 1 α = r f + 1 1 α w i,0 X i w i,0 [ ρy + 1 ρz i ] = r f + 1 1 α [ ρ w i,0 Y + 1 ρ w i,0 Z i ] By assumption of correlated fund flows, we can get the following specification of stock returns. Proposition 1. The stock return from time 0 to 1 is characterized by the 10

following equation: R 1 = r f + 1 1 α [ ρỹ + 1 ρ Z] (23) where Ỹ = w i,0 Y t and Zt = w i,0 Z i. (24) Ỹ is a normal random variable with mean zero and variance φ 2 0 and Z is a normal random variables with zero mean and variance λ 0, that is, Ỹ N(0, φ 2 0), Z N(0, λ0 ), φ 0 = w i,0, λ 0 = w 2 i,0. Proposition 1 suggests that the fund-flow shocks influence the stock return through the wealth of investors. induced by the systematic factor Y t Moreover, we obtain the following result about the expected return and volatility. Proposition 2. The expected return and variance of the stock return are given as follows: E 0 [R 1 ] = r f, and V ar 0 (R 1 ) = ( ) 2 1 σ 1 α X[ρφ 2 2 0 + (1 ρ)λ 0 ]. Proposition 3. The stock return variance is an increasing function of the 11

correlation of fund flows and the proportion of wealth of short-term investors: V ar 0 (R 1 ) ρ V ar(r t ) φ 0 = 2 ( ) 2 1 = σ 1 α X[φ 2 2 0 λ 0 ] > 0, ( ) 2 1 σ 1 α Xφ 2 0 > 0. This result shows that the rises in the proportion of short-term investors and in the correlation between fund flows across short-term investors increase stock return volatility. This results are consistent with the empirical findings such as Greenwood and Thesmar (2011) and Chichernea et al. (2015). Flowdriven trading generates the additional risk for the stock returns. 3 Conclusion In this analysis, we study the relationship between the stock return process and ownership structure. We employ two types investors: Long-horizon investors and short-horizon investors. We characterize the short-horizon investors as the investors who face the exogenous fund flows. Investors who have fragile funding structures tend to purchase or liquidate their stock holding in order to form the optimal portfolio. The exogenous fund flows induce the portfolio adjustments and non-fundamental trading. This flow-driven trading influence the stock return process. In reality, non-fundamental behavior of investors who face the fund flows such as hedge funds and its impact on asset prices has been observed. This paper aims to explain the impact of 12

fund flows on stock volatility. Our result shows that the rises in the proportion of short-term investors and in the correlation between fund flows across short-term investors increase stock return volatility. This results are consistent with the empirical findings such as Greenwood and Thesmar (2011) and Chichernea et al. (2015). Traditional asset pricing models have not focus on the ownership structures and non-fundamental trading like flow-driven trading by hedge funds. Price impact by flow-driven trading can cause the different type of risks. It is difficult to estimate this type of risk because we cannot capture perfectly the fund-flows of investors and their correlation. Therefore, we need farther research on this topic. References Allen, F., Morris, S., Shin, H. S., 2006. Beauty contests and iterated expectations in asset markets. Review of financial Studies 19 (3), 719 752. Amihud, Y., Mendelson, H., 1986. Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread. Journal of financial Economics 17 (2), 223 249. Banerjee, S., Kaniel, R., Kremer, I., 2009. Price drift as an outcome of differences in higher-order beliefs. Review of Financial Studies 22 (9), 3707 3734. Bernardo, A. E., Welch, I., 2004. Liquidity and financial market runs. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 135 158. Bushee, B. J., Noe, C. F., 2000. Corporate disclosure practices, institutional investors, and stock return volatility. Journal of accounting research, 171 202. Cella, C., Ellul, A., Giannetti, M., 2013. Investors horizons and the amplification of market shocks. Review of Financial Studies, hht023. 13

Chichernea, D. C., Petkevich, A., Zykaj, B. B., 2015. Idiosyncratic volatility, institutional ownership, and investment horizon. European Financial Management 21 (4), 613 645. Corsi, F., 2009. A simple approximate long-memory model of realized volatility. Journal of Financial Econometrics, nbp001. Froot, K. A., Scharfstein, D. S., Stein, J. C., 1992. Herd on the street: Informational inefficiencies in a market with short-term speculation. The Journal of Finance 47 (4), 1461 1484. Greenwood, R., Thesmar, D., 2011. Stock price fragility. Journal of Financial Economics 102 (3), 471 490. Keynes, J. M., 1936. General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. Macmillan & Co., Ltd. Lynch, P. E., Zumbach, G. O., et al., 2003. Market heterogeneities and the causal structure of volatility. Quantitative Finance 3 (4), 320 331. Morris, S., Shin, H. S., 2004. Liquidity black holes. Review of Finance 8 (1), 1 18. Müller, U. A., Dacorogna, M. M., Davé, R. D., Olsen, R. B., Pictet, O. V., von Weizsäcker, J. E., 1997. Volatilities of different time resolutions?analyzing the dynamics of market components. Journal of Empirical Finance 4 (2), 213 239. Shleifer, A., 2000. Inefficient Markets: An introduction to behavioural finance. OUP Oxford. Shleifer, A., Vishny, R. W., 1997. The limits of arbitrage. The Journal of Finance 52 (1), 35 55. 14