OS CHOICE BETWEEN EXPENDITURE TAX AND TAXES ON CONSUMPTION AND CAPITAL GOODS

Similar documents
Ramsey taxation and the (non?)optimality of uniform commodity taxation. Jason Lim and Sam Hinds

Module 10. Lecture 37

The Neoclassical Growth Model

A NEW MEASURE OP FISCAL PRIVILEGE

Lecture 2: The Neoclassical Growth Model

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DIRECT OR INDIRECT TAX INSTRUMENTS FOR REDISTRIBUTION: SHORT-RUN VERSUS LONG-RUN. Emmanuel Saez

New Trade Theory I. Part A: Simple monopolistic competition model. Robert Stehrer. The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies - wiiw

Public Good Provision Rules and Income Distribution: Some General Equilibrium Calculations

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 7: Externalities, the Marginal Cost of Public Funds, and Imperfect Competition

LIBRARY OF THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY

A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities

The transformation of public economics research: q

Introductory Economics of Taxation. Lecture 1: The definition of taxes, types of taxes and tax rules, types of progressivity of taxes

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing

Financing Government Expenditures: Some Basics

Principle of targeting in environmental taxation

ECO-G-CC-1-1-TH/ ECO--GE-1-1-TH /ECO-G-GE-1-1-TH

Anthony B. Atkinson. Joseph E. Stiglitz

Principles of Optimal Taxation

Arindam Das Gupta Independent. Abstract

ECONOMICS QUALIFYING EXAMINATION IN ELEMENTARY MATHEMATICS

Using the Relation between GINI Coefficient and Social Benefits as a Measure of the Optimality of Tax Policy

The Transformation of Public Economics Research:

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

Suggested Solutions for Problem Set #2

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market.

Introductory Mathematics for Economics MSc s: Course Outline. Huw David Dixon. Cardiff Business School. September 2008.

Urban unemployment, privatization policy, and a differentiated mixed oligopoly

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #7 - Competitive Markets

Discussion Papers in Economics. No. 12/03. Nonlinear Income Tax Reforms. Alan Krause

Can We Infer External Effects from a Study of the Irish Indirect Tax System?

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

Helmuth Cremer Winter 2018 M2, TSE Public Economics

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

The Lifetime Incidence Of Consumption Sales Taxes

ECON 5402:F Public Economics: Taxation Carleton University, 2012 Fall

Week 5. Remainder of chapter 9: the complete real model Chapter 10: money Copyright 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

The Irrelevance of Detail in a Computable General Equilibrium Model

ON UNANIMITY AND MONOPOLY POWER

Subject Index. Bankruptcy costs, See also Leverage-related

Modern Public Economics

Environmental Levies and Distortionary Taxation: Pigou, Taxation, and Pollution

PRODUCTION COSTS. Econ 311 Microeconomics 1 Lecture Material Prepared by Dr. Emmanuel Codjoe

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Public Economics. Level / Semester - Niveau /semestre

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

The theory of taxation/3 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.15 Rosen) Desirable characteristics of tax systems (optimal taxation)

Modeling the Estate Tax Proposals of 2016

1%(5:25.,1*3$3(56(5,(6 (19,5210(17$//(9,(6$1'',67257,21$5<7$;$7,21 3,*287$;$7,21$1'32//87,21 *LOEHUW(0HW DOI :RUNLQJ3DSHU KWWSZZZQEHURUJSDSHUVZ

Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001)

2. Optimal taxation with any CRS technology: the Ramsey Rule again

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

CONSUMER OPTIMISATION

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Optimal Capital Income Taxation

UNIT 1 THEORY OF COSUMER BEHAVIOUR: BASIC THEMES

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

y = f(n) Production function (1) c = c(y) Consumption function (5) i = i(r) Investment function (6) = L(y, r) Money demand function (7)

Spring 2013 Econ 567 Project #2 Wei Zhang & Qing Tian. The study of the welfare effect of the income tax and the excise tax

Module 2 THEORETICAL TOOLS & APPLICATION. Lectures (3-7) Topics

Keywords: Profit-maximization pricing, Ramsey pricing, Ramsey taxation

3. The Deadweight Loss of Taxation

The optimal allocation of pension risks in employment contracts. David McCarthy

ECONOMICS 100A: MICROECONOMICS

Eastern Mediterranean University Faculty of Business and Economics Department of Economics Spring Semester

Dynamic Macroeconomics

CHAPTER 4. The Theory of Individual Behavior

A SECOND-BEST POLLUTION SOLUTION WITH SEPARATE TAXATION OF COMMODITIES AND EMISSIONS

Green tax reform in Belgium: Combining regional general equilibrium and microsimulation

Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Public Schemes for Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets

Taxation and deadweight loss in a system of intergovernmental transfers

THE INDIVIDUAL TAXPAYER UTILITY FUNCTION WITH TAX OPTIMIZATION AND FISCAL FRAUD ENVIRONMENT

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

Ninth ARTNeT Capacity Building Workshop for Trade Research "Trade Flows and Trade Policy Analysis"

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

The Economics of State Taxation. George R. Zodrow Professor of Economics Rice Scholar, Baker Institute for Public Policy Rice University

Chapter 2 Equilibrium and Efficiency

SUMMER TERM 2017 ECON1604: ECONOMICS I (Combined Studies)

3. If the price of a British pound increases from $1.50 per pound to $1.80 per pound, we say that:

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap

Volume Author/Editor: Charles L. Ballard, Don Fullerton, John B. Shoven, and John Whalley. Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press

HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTION AND WELFARE EVALUATION WITH NON-CONSTANT RETURNS TO SCALE. DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS CALIFORNIA STATE UNIVERSITY, LONG BEACH

Lecture Demand Functions

Syllabus for Admission to M. Phil/ Ph.D / 3 Year Integrated Ph.D programme in Economics Part-2 nd

A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 7: Optimal Top Income Taxation

The Marginal Cost of Public Funds in Closed and Small Open Economies

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS INTERPRETING AND USING EMPIRICAL ESTIMATES OF THE MCF

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts

ECON 5402-W Public Economics: Taxation Carleton University, 2018 Winter

Consumption and Savings (Continued)

Optimum taxation and the allocation of time

Transcription:

OS CHOICE BETWEEN EXPENDITURE TAX AND TAXES ON CONSUMPTION AND CAPITAL GOODS M N MURTHY WD. 10/8 8 NOVEMBER 1988 SATIOMAL INSTITUTE OF PUBLIC FINANCE AND POLICY 1 8 /2, SATSANG VIHAR MARG SPECIAL INSTITUTIONAL AREA HEW DELHI - 110 067

Abstrac t Using a two-period, two-commodity model, formulae for optimal rates of taxes under two revenue-neutral tax regimes - (a) Expenditure tax and ( b) Taxes on capital and consumption goods - are derived. Under the two tax regimes considered, Lt is found that at optimum the implicit rate of ta-: on the capital good is higher than that on the consumption good. Also, the implicit rate of tax on the capital good under one tax regime is different from that under the other regime.

On Choice Between Expenditure Tax and Taxes on Consumption and Capital Goods M N Murty 1. Introduction The problem of substituting a direct tax on consumption expenditure (or an expenditure tax, as originally conceived by Kaldor, 1957 with commodity taxes (indirect taxes) is as important a problem in m.'3 / developing countries today as is the problem of substituting expenditure tax with income ta>ces (direct taxes) in the developed world. Ever since the pioneering work of Kaidor (1957) there has been a lot of lively debate (!JS Treasury, 1977; Feldsteln, 1978; Bradford, 1980; Fullerton, Shoven and Whalley, 1983) about the relative effects of expenditure and income taxes on various fiscal objectives like resource mobilisation, growth and equity. In contrast, little attention has been paid to the problem of substituting an expenditure tax with commodity taxes in spite of its importance in the current developing world. For instance, expressing his view on memoranda on tax reforms submitted to the Royal Commission on Taxation of Profits and Income (appointed in 1950) by Commission's Sub-Committee of Economists, Lord Butler, the then Chancellor of Exchequer said, "With the level of indirect taxation which we have now reached, and the extent to which the expenditure of those whose expenditure is not confined to necessaries include a large element of payment of tax, it seems to me that it would be impossible to carry through. the exam Lna t o n of a scheme of taxation on expenditure without also examining on fairly fundamental lines the scope and purposes of indirect taxation. (Kaldor, 1957, p.7) Lord Butler's view on the expenditure tax vis-a-vls indirect taxation in Britain during the early fifties seems to be more relevant for designing ta< reforms in many developing economies (Murty, 1987). For example, in a developing country like India 80 per cent of tax revenue comes from commodity taxation while direct taxes are major sources of revenue to government in many developed countries. The problem of having a uniform tax on all consumption goods (which can be interpreted as proportional tax on consumption expenditure) in relation

to differential commodity taxation is examined in detail with the help of static optimal commodity tax models.^ It is established that for certain types of utility functions for households (especially with weak separability between leisure and consumption goods), uniform commodity taxation is optimum. However, in most of these models indirect taxes on capital goods are not considered. Households may save part of their income and spend it in acquiring capital goods in the current period which guarantee them certain amounts of consumption goods in future even if they do not earn any type of income in future, including wage income. In this case, a uniform tax on con sumption goods means a uniform tax on current and future consumption expenditures while differential commodity taxation implies different rates of taxes on consumption goods and capital goods. In this paper, we consider two alternative revenue-neutral tax regimes: (a) A direct tax on present and future consumption expenditures and ( b) Taxes on consumption and capital goods using a simple two period - two commodity model. Ve derive formulae for optimal rates of taxes and comment on the relative rates of taxes on consumption and capital goods. The plan of the remaining paper is as follows: Section 2 presents a model of expenditure tax while Section 3 deals with the problem of taxes on capital and consumption goods- Conclusions are indicated in Section 4. 2. The Model of Expenditure Tax Let us consider a representative individual in the economy who earns wage income and spends it in acquiring a consumption good and a capital good in the current period. The individual has no wage income in the future. The consumption good he purchases in future depends upon the amount of capital good he purchases in the current period as explained by the production functional relationship X11 = F (X20> F' (X2Q) = 5 F > 0, F" (X2Q) = q2f < 0 where 6 x2 o 5 x 2 0 X2q : Capital good purchased by the individual in the current

3 period, and : Consumption good purchased by the individual in the future. The individual has the following utility function U (X10, Xn, L) (2) where X-j^q : Consumption good purchased by the individual in the current period. L : Current period labour supply of the individual. 5 U 6 U 6U <$Xn ou Ux = 2 > u2 = = >, UL = > 0 6 X11 ix 20 6 X11 x20 6L If Pj and P are respectively producer prices of consumption and capital goods, the consumer's budget without the tax situation is defined as ^ 1 X1 0 + ^ 2 X20 = where w is the wage rate. Taking consumption good as numeraire if there is a tax on consumption expenditure at the rate ' e ', the individual's budget constraint becomes (1+e) X1Q + (1+e) Xn = wl (4) 1+r where r is the rate of time preference. The government's revenue constraint is defined as e X10 + e X11 = R 1+r (5)

4 Using (4) we can alternatively write (j) as T y _ v R wl ~ X10 ^ l L = 1+r C.-'ven ( I s:, (2) and (4), the first order conditions for the individual s utilitv maximi sa ti on are giver as 1 i o = 3. (l + e) F (X-7, L where ^ is the marginal utility of money incone. The individual's budget constraint (4) can be alternatively written as (1+e) X-.Q + (1+e) Y' Xtq = (7 ) (1+ rj (1 + r) 'here - is the elasticity of average productivity of capital good' wit espect to capital good itself. Using (6), (7) can be written as ui x] 0 + v2 X20 + Ut L = 0 (8) i he pi obi em now is to find out the rate of tax on consumption expenditures X^q and X that, maximises U subject to the constraints defined by ( j ) and (8). This can be accomplished by maximising the following Lagrangian with respect to X1Q, X2q and L. = U + X [wl-x10-xn -R] + 1+r rit lul ' 10 2 1+ r; 4-TT!0 L L] (9 )

Assuming that n is constant, the first order conditions for the maximum of <J> are Ux - X + y[uu X1Q + \Jl + U21 X2Q + UL1 L] = 0 (10) 1 + n U2 ~ X F _i_ y [Uj2 xio + ^22 X20 + ^2 + ^L2 ( H ) 1+r 1+ ^ 1+ n Wri ting UL + A w + u [U1L X1Q + U2L X2q + ULL L + UL] = 0 (12) 1 + n U11 X10 + U21 X20 + UL1 L 1 +- n H1 = - U1 U12 X10 + U22 X2Q 1 + n + UL2 L H2 = - u2 U1L X10 + U2L X20 1 + n + ULL L HL = - UL and substituting (6) in (10), (11) and (12) we have e = (>. - a)(l-hl ) - a - ood-h1) ( 13) a (1-HL ) + (\ - a ) (1-H1) or equivalently

( X- a)(l-hl) ~ Q - a )(1-H2- nh2 ) 1 + ri (14) e = --------------------------- a (1 -HL) + C ct) (1 -li2- nil2) 1 + n Therefore at optimum, the expenditure tax should be such that 0? l-ir - M r l-h1 = --------- (15) 1 + " A1ternatively H1 - H2 1-(H1-H2 ) ( 1 5 ') 1 2 J Equations (13) and (14) are implicit functions since H1, H and H also depend upon e. Also, the optimum rate of expenditure tax should be such 1 9 that H and H satisfy the equation (15). Proposition 1 A direct tax on present and future consumption expenditures implies at optimum a tax on capital good which is higher than the uniform rate of tax on present and future consumption expenditures. Proof: At optimum, the producer price of the capital good is 1+r = s > 1 with the assumption F' _> 1 + r. With the tax on present and future consumption expenditures, the implicit consumer price of the capital good at optimum is P = (1 + e) s (16)

7 Therefore the implicit tax on the capital good at optimum is t2 = (1 + e) s - s = e s (17) Given s > 1 we have t2 > e (18) Q E D 3. Taxes on Consumption and Capital Goods Let there be equal revenue raising commodity taxes as compared to an expenditure tax at the rates tj and t2 respectively on consumption and capital goods. Then the consumer's budget constraint becomes (l + t i) X 10 + t2 X20 + (l+ ti )_ X 11 ul (1 9 ) 1 + r and the government's revenue constraint is tl X10 + t2 X20 + tl X11 = R (20) 1 + r From (19) we can alternatively write (20) as wl - X1Q - X1X _ R (20') 1+r Utility maximising conditions for the consumer are U, = a(l + tx) (21) U2 = a(t2 + (1 + tl) F') 1 + r - aw

8 Using (21) we can write (19)^ as U2 + ctri 1 2 U1 X10 + ------- X20 + UL L = 0 (22) (1 + n) The optimal rates of taxes on consumption and capital goods are determined by maximising the following Lagrangian with respect to fl, and x 2 0 * = U + 5 [wl-x10-xn -R] + y[ux X10+U2+ an t2 X20+UL L 3 (23) 1+r Ux - a + y [Un X10+UL + U21 1 + k20 + ulll] = 0 (2 4 ) 12 X10 + U22 X 11 20 + u2 + UL2 L] = 0 (2 5 ) lit + ). w+ 1L Xin + U 2L X20 1 +n + U LL L + L\ = 0 (2 6 ) Wri ting U11 X10 + U21 X20 + UL 1 L 1 + r)

9 U12 X10 + u22 x20 + UL2 F ' L 1 + n H2 = - ----------------- U2 U1L X10 + U2L X20 + ULL L 1 + hl = _ ----------- we have (A - a) (1 - HL) ( ' of; (1 ~H1 ) t]_ = --- --------------------- (27) ot(l-hl ) - (A - a) (1-H1) s {a (1-HL) - (1+tj) [ a (1-HL) - (>.-3) (l-(l+n)h)] } t2 = - (1 + *l) a (1-11 ), 1 -(1+rO H2 v (28) (l + n> 1 2 Equations (27) and (28) are implicit functions in t-^ and for H, H and HL also depend on t^ and t2 * Nevertheless, they describe the relationship between taxes and the demand system parameters for consumption and capital goods at optimum. Proposition 2 Differential taxes on consumption and capital goods imply at optimum a tax on capital good higher than that on consumption good. Proof: At optimum, the producer price of capital good is F' -- = s > 1 1+r

1 0 With the taxes on consumption and capital goods, the implicit purchaser price of capital good at optimum is given by (20) as P2 = t2 + (l+t1) s (29) Therefore, the implicit tax on capital good is given as t2 ~ P2_s = t2 + tl s (30) Also given s > 1, we have t^ s > Therefore we have t-2 = ^2 + tl s - tl Q E D. (31) Proposition 3 At optimum, the implicit rate of tax on the capital good with respect to differential commodity taxation can be different from the implicit rate with respect to a direct tax on present and future consumption expenditures. Proof: From (17) and (30) we have implicit rates of taxes on capital good with respect to expenditure and commodity taxes as e s and t2 + 1 s * From the equations (13), (14), (27) and (28) we can write e s > t2 + t^ s <~ (32) Q E D

11 Proposition 4 If supply of labour is completely inelastic, the optimal tax on capital good is zero. Proof: If supply of labour is completely inelastic (H^-*oo ) we have from (27) and (28) t] - (33) s( A- (l+tx) a). to = a (3 4 ) substituting (33) in (34) we have t2 ~ 0 QED. This result in turn implies that optimal tax on savings out of current income that are used to buy a capital good is zero. The optimal tax is a proportional tax on consumption expenditure (current and future). A similar result is obtained by Atkinson and Stiglitz (1972) using a model in which an individual lives for n periods, consume s in period i and supplies labour L in period 1. They found that sufficient condition for the consumption tax to be optimal is that there be weak separability between consumption and leisure. Our result is comparable to their result because the assumption of completely inelastic supply of labour implies the separability between leisure and other consumption goods. Proposition 5 If supply of labour is perfectly elastic we have inverse elasticity rule for optimal commodity taxation.! 11 >c-l Ii >2 * *

12 Proof: If cross price effects are zero, we have U11 XjQ U22 X20 H1 = - ------- and H2 = ------- U2 (36) vl 1 + n From (21) we have 6 X 1q 6 X2 Un = ot, U2 2 = a (37) 6 t1 5 t2 Using (37) in (36) we have H1 = - -- and H2 = - --- (38) ell e22 where e ^ and e22 are own price elasticities of demands for X^q and X2q. In addition, if supply of labour is perfectly elastic (H^1 0), we can write (27) and (28) as 1 lieni 1 a/ ( X_ a) + (i - 1/^ u ) (39) s{ (1+n ) X (X-a) - ( l + ^ M (1 + n )/(A-a ) - (1-11 e22 )] } t2 = -------------------------------------------- (40) a(l+n) I (X - a) + (1-1 / e22 )

13 4. Conclusions We have derived the formulae for optimal tax rates under the two tax regimes considered. These formulae are implicit functional relationships in tax rates, and demand and production -function parameters that should hold good at optimum. We have shown that (a) A direct tax on present and future consumption expenditures implies at optimum a tax on capital good which is higher than the uniform rate on consumption expenditures. (b) Differential taxes on consumption and capital goods also imply at optimum a tax on capital good higher than the tax on consumption good and (c) At optimum, the implicit rate of tax on the capital good with respect to differential commodity taxation can be different froo the implicit rate with respect to a direct tax on consumpiton expendi ture. (d) If the supply of labour is completely inelastic, the optimal rate of tax on capital good is zero. We have or^y tax on consumption good purchased in present and future.

14 Notes 1. Stern (1987) for example provides a review of literature on this subject. See also Atkinson and Stiglitz (1977). We have and therefore ^ 1+r) X2 0 l + r 20 3. n is assumed to be constant for the sake of simplifying derivations. 4. We have (i+tx) x n (i+tx) r t2 X20 + -------- = t2 X20 + --- ---- x20 1 + r ( 1+r ) (i+ ' ) r l2 + (l+t) F + "t2 i Xo0 t 1 + 1 1 + r J Uo + cm t. '2 (1 + -

15 REFERENCES Atkinson, A.B. and J.E. Stiglitz (1972). "The Stucture of Indirect Taxation and Economic Efficiency", Journalof Public Economics, 01, 97-119. Atkinson, A.B. and J.E. Stiglitz (1980). Lectures on Public Economics, McGrav Hill, New York. Bradford, D. (1980;. 'The Case for Personal Consumption Tax" in J.A. Pechman, ed., What Should be Taxed: Income or Expenditure? Brookings Institutions, Washington, DC. Feldstein, M. (1978). "The Welfare Cost of Capital Income Taxation", Journal of Political Economy, 86, 529-551. Fullerton, D., J.B. Shoven and J. Whalley (1983). 'Replacing the US Income Tax with a Progressive Consumption Tax: A Sequential General Equilibrium Approach", Journal of Public Economics, 20, 3-23. Kaldor, N. (1957). An Expenditure Tax, Allen and Unwin, London. Murty, M.N. (1987). 'Horizontal Equity and Choice between Income and Expenditure Taxes", Economic and Political Weekly, 12, March 21, 1987, 501-506. Stern, N.H. (1987). "Uniformity Versus Selectivity in Tax Structure: Lesson from Theory and Policy", Working Paper No. 9, Department of Economics Research Programme, London School of Economics, UK. U.S. Treasury (1977). Blueprints for Basic Tax Reform, Office of Tax Analysis, US Treasury, Washington, DC.

N IP F P WORKING PAPER S E R IE S : 1988 Working paper Title Author's name 1/88 2/88 Recent Initiatives in Enforcement and Trends in Income Tax Revenue: An Appr ai s al Rationing, Dual Pricing and Ramsey Commodity Taxation: Theory and An Illustration using Indian Budget Data Amaresh Bagchi (January) Raghbendra Jha M N Murty and Ranjan Ray (Apr i l ) 3/88 Economic Evaluation of People's Participation in the Management of Common Property Resources Kanchan Chopra G.K. Kadekodi and M N Murty ( May) 4/88 New Series on National Accounts Statistics: Some Comments Uma Datta Roy Choudhury ( Sept ember) 5/88 On the Measurement of Unemploymen t Sa tya Paul (September) 6/88 Private Corporate Investment and Effective Tax Rates: A Re-examination of a Feldstein-Chirinko Controversy Raghbendra Jha Ni sha Wad hwa (Oc tober) 7/88 Growth of Capital Goods Sector after the Mid- Sixties: Some Observations Gopinath Pradhan 8/88 cations of the Indian Capital Gains Tax Subhayu Bandopadhvay and Arindam Das-Gupta (October) 9/88 10/88 Export Demand and Supply Elasticities for Selected Industrial Countries, 1970-1983 On Choice between Expenditure and Taxes on Consumption and Capital Goods A V L Narayana and Arvind Panagariya M N Murty