Do high interest rates stem capital outflows?

Similar documents
Review of. Financial Crises, Liquidity, and the International Monetary System by Jean Tirole. Published by Princeton University Press in 2002

Brazil s public finances appeared to have been in a shambles prior to the election. A Brazilian-Type Debt Crisis: Simple Analytics

Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware

Chapter 24 CRISES IN EMERGING MARKETS

Jacek Prokop a, *, Ewa Baranowska-Prokop b

Leandro Conte UniSi, Department of Economics and Statistics. Money, Macroeconomic Theory and Historical evidence. SSF_ aa

The fiscal adjustment after the crisis in Argentina

ABSTRACT. Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Policy with Income-sensitive Capital Flows. J.O.N. Perkins, University of Melbourne

The papers and comments presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of

Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries

A folk theorem for one-shot Bertrand games

INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL FLOWS: DISCUSSION

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

IMF Stabilisation and Structural Adjustment Programmes Colette Murphy Junior Sophister

Debt Sustainability and Exchange Stabilisation: Towards a New Theory

Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model)

Learning objectives. Macroeconomics I International Group Course Topic 8: AGGREGATE DEMAND IN AN OPEN ECONOMY

Determinants of foreign direct investment in Malaysia

Perfect competition and intra-industry trade

POLICY PRESCRIPTIONS FOR EAST ASIA

Macroeconomics Sixth Edition

TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover

Factors that Affect Fiscal Externalities in an Economic Union

: Monetary Economics and the European Union. Lecture 8. Instructor: Prof Robert Hill. The Costs and Benefits of Monetary Union II

Chapter 19 Prices and Output in an Open Economy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A BRAZILIAN DEBT-CRISIS MODEL. Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka. Working Paper

Global Imbalances and Latin America: A Comment on Eichengreen and Park

dr Bartłomiej Rokicki Chair of Macroeconomics and International Trade Theory Faculty of Economic Sciences, University of Warsaw

LEARNING OBJECTIVES 4. Debt and

Chilean Unremunerated Reserve Requirement Capital Controls as a Screening Mechanism. Abstract

Banks can also borrow reserves from the Fed at the (Click to select) at the. References

Managing Sudden Stops. Barry Eichengreen and Poonam Gupta

Goals of Topic 8. NX back!! What is the link between the exchange rate and net exports? How do different policies affect the trade deficit?

QUEEN S UNIVERSITY FACULTY OF ARTS AND SCIENCE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Economics 222 A&B Macroeconomic Theory I. Final Examination 20 April 2009

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

Effects of monetary policy shocks on the trade balance in small open European countries

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno

Environmental Levies and Distortionary Taxation: Pigou, Taxation, and Pollution

Our Textbooks are Wrong: How An Increase in the Currency-Deposit Ratio Can Increase the Money Multiplier

Chapter 16. Fiscal Policy and the Government Budget

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

Chapter 18: Output and the Exchange Rate in the Short Run

Trade Reform and Macroeconomic Policy in Vietnam. Rod Tyers and Lucy Rees Australian National University

A SIMULTANEOUS-EQUATION MODEL OF THE DETERMINANTS OF THE THAI BAHT/U.S. DOLLAR EXCHANGE RATE

University of Toronto July 27, 2012 ECO 209Y L0101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #3

EconS 327 Test 2 Spring 2010

University of Toronto July 15, 2016 ECO 209Y L0101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2

L-3: BALANCE OF PAYMENT CRISES IRINA BUNDA MACROECONOMIC POLICIES IN TIMES OF HIGH CAPITAL MOBILITY VIENNA, MARCH 21 25, 2016

9 Right Prices for Interest and Exchange Rates

Bank Flows and Basel III Determinants and Regional Differences in Emerging Markets

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY. Term Test #2. December 13, 2017

SHOULD YOU CARRY A MORTGAGE INTO RETIREMENT?

IMF-Related Announcements, Fundamentals, and Creditor Moral Hazard: A Case Study of Indonesia. Ayşe Y. Evrensel Portland State University.

Escaping from a Liquidity Trap and Deflation (Svensson, JEP, 2003)

Oxford Energy Comment March 2009

OVERVIEW. 1. This chapter presents a graphical approach to the determination of income. Two different graphical approaches are provided.

Suggested Answers. Department of Economics Economics 115 University of California. Berkeley, CA Spring *SAS = See Answer Sheet

Midterm Exam I: Answer Sheet

A Test of Two Open-Economy Theories: The Case of Oil Price Rise and Italy

19.2 Exchange Rates in the Long Run Introduction 1/24/2013. Exchange Rates and International Finance. The Nominal Exchange Rate

Figure: EUR-USD Exchange Rate

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Lecture 5: Flexible prices - the monetary model of the exchange rate. Lecture 6: Fixed-prices - the Mundell- Fleming model

Initiative for Policy Dialogue Task Force on Macroeconomic Policy. Why is Macroeconomics Different in Developing Countries?

Notes Unless otherwise indicated, the years referred to in describing budget numbers are fiscal years, which run from October 1 to September 30 and ar

The International Financial System

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

Lecture 6: Intermediate macroeconomics, autumn Lars Calmfors

FETP/MPP8/Macroeconomics/Riedel. General Equilibrium in the Short Run II The IS-LM model

A Test of Two Open-Economy Theories: Oil Price Rise and Italy

Macroeconomics Mankiw 6th Edition

file:///c:/users/moha/desktop/mac8e/new folder (13)/CourseComp...

Training costs. More production eventually demands hiring more workers, who in general should be trained to be able to operate efficiently.

In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions

Quantal Response Equilibrium with Non-Monotone Probabilities: A Dynamic Approach

Chapter 21 - Exchange Rate Regimes

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries

University of Toronto July 21, 2010 ECO 209Y L0101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2

4. SOME KEYNESIAN ANALYSIS

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CAN AN INCREASED BUDGET DEFICIT BE CONTRACTIONARY? Martin Feldstein. Working Paper No. l43)4

The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand P R I N C I P L E S O F. N. Gregory Mankiw. Introduction

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

Some Simple Analytics of the Taxation of Banks as Corporations

14.02 Quiz 3. Time Allowed: 90 minutes. Fall 2012

Econ 102/Lecture 100 Final Exam Form 1 April 27, 2005

Chapter 22 THE MUNDELL-FLEMING MODEL WITH PARTIAL INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL MOBILITY

Chapter 4 Monetary and Fiscal. Framework

working paper Fiscal Policy, Government Institutions, and Sovereign Creditworthiness By Bernardin Akitoby and Thomas Stratmann No.

Chapter 6. Government Influence on Exchange Rates. Lecture Outline

Mr Thiessen converses on the conduct of monetary policy in Canada under a floating exchange rate system

Challenges of financial globalisation and dollarisation for monetary policy: the case of Peru

Working Papers in Economics. Analyzing the Present Sustainability of Turkey s Current Account Position

Commodity price movements and monetary policy in Asia

Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains

Chapter 10: International Trade and the Developing Countries

Benjamin Miranda Tabak,1

Date of Speculative Attack-Crises of Exchange Rates

I don't understand the argument that even though inflation is not accelerating, the world nevertheless suffers from "global excess liquidity":

Measuring the Degree of Currency misalignment Using Offshore Forward Exchange Rates: The Case of the Korean Financial Crisis

Transcription:

Economics Letters 67 (2000) 187 192 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase q Do high interest rates stem capital outflows? Michael R. Pakko* Senior Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 411 Locust Street, St. Louis, MO 63102, USA Received 25 February 1999; accepted 23 September 1999 Abstract Conventional wisdom posits that high interest rates stem capital flight. But if higher interest rates increase the probability of debt default, they might have anti-orthodox effects. This note develops a framework for evaluating conditions under which this might occur. 2000 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. Keywords: Capital flight; Default risk; Laffer curve; Interest rates JEL classification: F32; F3 1. Introduction In recent financial crises around the world, episodes of capital flight and currency depreciation have created difficult policy choices for the governments of affected nations. The standard policy prescription includes fiscal restraint and the maintenance of high domestic interest rates to stem capital outflows. Although countries which follow this advice are rewarded by the international community with financial assistance intended to further buttress investor confidence, the contractionary effects of these policy prescriptions can be bitter medicine. In light of the continuing difficulties that many countries have faced following the implementation of such policies, some have argued that the standard prescription exacerbates problems associated with capital flight. For example, Sachs (1998) contends that by following the conventional wisdom to raise interest rates to stratospheric levels, countries experience a perverse outcome: Investors do not gain confidence when short-term rates are pushed to dozens of percent... The more these economies tried to defend their currencies, the more they incited panic. The implication of this q The views expressed in this paper are those of the author, and do not necessarily represent official positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis or the Federal Reserve System. *Tel.: 11-314-444-8564; fax: 11-314-444-8731. E-mail address: pakko@stls.frb.org (M.R. Pakko) 0165-1765/ 00/ $ see front matter 2000 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. PII: S0165-1765(99)00260-8

188 M.R. Pakko / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 187 192 argument is that higher rates can exacerbate problems associated with currency depreciation and capital outflows. Others are more skeptical of this contention: I have heard some people propose what amounts to a sort of foreign exchange-interest rate Laffer curve: if you cut interest rates this will strengthen the economy, and the currency will actually rise. This is as silly as it sounds. (Krugman, 1998). In this note, I set out a framework for evaluating the conditions under which an increase in domestic interest rates fails to reverse capital outflows and support a country s exchange rate. That is, when might a Laffer curve type of effect be relevant? I examine this issue in a simple model in which capital flows depend on an interest arbitrage condition that incorporates a default risk. The possibility that high domestic interest rates might have unorthodox effects on capital flows enters through the risk premium: If raising interest rates increases the probability associated with a default on outstanding debt, the result can be a worsening of the country s capital account position. Because the Laffer curve nature of the model admits the possibility of multiple equilibria, an exogenous event that increases the perceived risk of investing in a country can result in a jump from an equilibrium in which raising interest rates will reverse capital outflows, to one in which the reverse is true. A country facing capital flight due to a crisis of confidence might therefore be plunged into a situation in which reducing interest rates might be the appropriate policy. 2. The model The model consists of a small open economy in a world of free capital mobility. To simplify the analysis, assume that the country s net indebtedness is consolidated on the accounts of its government and denominated in terms of a single fixed-return bond. The nominal interest rate on the bond is the government s single policy instrument. Investors consider both the explicit interest rate on the bond, R, and the probability that the country continues to service its debt, p. The expected real return on the bond is therefore r 5 pr 1 e (1) where e is the expected rate of currency appreciation. Returns are assumed to be zero in the default state. An interest arbitrage condition determines the direction of capital flows; i.e., an investor withdraws w capital if the expected real return on the country s bonds falls below the world real interest rate, r.if we assume that there is a distribution of beliefs about the default probability, the relationship between capital flows and changes in the return spread can be expressed as depending on changes in the expectations of the median investor. The possibility of an anti-orthodox effect for high interest rate policies occurs when the probability of a debt default is increasing in the country s expected fiscal deficit. Higher interest rates can increase prospective deficits in a number of ways. Most directly, higher interest rates raise the burden of debt service obligations (particularly when outstanding debt is already large). Higher rates also dampen investment and overall economic activity, and can debilitate a weak financial sector. A full accounting of all the possible effects set aside, let us assume that the fundamental impact of high interest rate policies is to raise the probability that a country will be unable to service its debt.

M.R. Pakko / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 187 192 189 The probability of default might also be indirectly affected by exchange rate depreciation especially to the extent that the county s debt is denominated in foreign currency. Consequently, the probability that the country will not default can be expressed as p 5 r(r, eux) (2) with r( )/ R, 0 and r( )/ e. 0. The vector X summarizes the exogenous fundamentals affecting investors risk assessments. To the extent that a policy succeeds in raising expected real returns and attracting capital, the currency will also appreciate. Moreover, high interest rates have the beneficial effect of dampening inflation expectations and, hence, appreciating the currency. So, e 5 (R, rux), (3) with ( )/ R. 0 and ( )/ r. 0. 3. Implications for interest rate policies A policy of raising interest rates will attract capital and appreciate a country s currency to the extent that expected real returns rise. The possibility of an anti-orthodox outcome arises if the reverse is true; that is, if r( )/ R, 0. Combining Eqs. (1), (2) and (3) and differentiating, this condition is: r p 2 rrr 1 R(1 1 rer) ] 5 ]]]]]]],0 (4) R 1 2 (1 1 r R) r e where subscripted terms denote absolute values of partial elasticities. The denominator of the expression in (4) captures the commonly-cited vicious/ virtuous circle of 1 feedback between exchange rates and capital flows. For example a policy that lowers expected real returns and results in capital flight depreciates a country s currency, further increasing the prospect of default and, hence, lowering expected real returns. Assuming that this multiplier-effect is positive, inequality (4) is satisfied and the anti-orthodox outcome occurs if: p 1 R R.]]] r 2 r R e R (5) An interest rate increase will be more likely to have the anti-orthodox effect of encouraging further capital outflows and currency depreciation if: (a) the perceived default probability at the time of the policy change, 12p, is already high; (b) the sensitivity of expected currency depreciation to interest rate changes, R, is low; (c) the sensitivity of the default probability to currency depreciation, r e,is low; and (d) interest rate increases have a substantial direct impact on the probability of future default (r large). Factors (a), (b), and (c) can be thought of as facilitating conditions for the possibility that R (d) will dominate the effect of changes in the nominal interest rate on expected real returns. 1 See, for example, Corsetti et al. (1998).

190 M.R. Pakko / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 187 192 Fig. 1. A risky-return Laffer curve. Inequality (5) shows that it is feasible for the expected real return on a country s debt to be decreasing in the nominal interest rate over some ranges. Fig. 1 illustrates an example of the relationship between the explicit interest rate and expected real returns a risky-return Laffer L curve. For interest rates lower than R, the expected real return lies below the world real interest rate. The country experiences capital outflows, but these can be eliminated by the conventional policy of raising interest rates. Further increases in the interest rate above R result in positive net capital M flows. Beyond the critical point R, however, higher interest rates tend to decrease capital inflows. If H interest rates are raised beyond R, the country will experience capital outflows, and efforts to reverse those flows by raising interest rates further will only exacerbate the problem. The existence of two points associated with zero net capital flows in Fig. 1 suggests a possible sequence of events which could result in a country moving from one equilibrium to another following 0 an exogenous disturbance. Consider the situation illustrated in Fig. 2. Initially, the interest rate is R, which is associated with expected real returns equal to the world real interest rate and zero net capital flows. Suppose that an exogenous event causes investors to reassess their evaluation of the country s 2 default risk, lowering expected returns and causing a capital outflow. The appropriate policy is to raise interest rates to R9, reestablishing equality of expected returns. Lacking precise knowledge of the appropriate size of a rate increase, however, the government might take more forceful action, raising the interest rate above R9. If the government raises the interest as high as R99, the capital outflow will be unaffected and an even more aggressive interest rate increase worsens the capital outflow. For a country with interest rate R0, the appropriate policy is to reduce the rate. Fig. 3 depicts a situation that might be even more relevant for describing recent incidents of large capital-flow reversals. In Fig. 3, a high interest rate policy is initially associated with capital inflows. The decline in risk-adjusted returns in this case results in a capital outflow that would be exacerbated by any increase in interest rates. Because the new equilibrium is on the downward-sloping portion of 2 The analysis of an increase in the world interest rate requires only slight modification. L

M.R. Pakko / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 187 192 191 Fig. 2. Responses to an increase in risk. the risky-return Laffer curve, the appropriate policy for halting capital outflows in this case is to lower interest rates. 4. Discussion and conclusions The fundamental feature of the model which makes the anti-orthodox result possible is the hypothesized relationship between high interest rates and a greater probability of default. It is not at all surprising that for higher rates to worsen capital outflows, this relationship must be relatively strong. In countries that are experiencing capital flight and currency depreciation, it is likely that Fig. 3. Another possible scenario.

192 M.R. Pakko / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 187 192 investors subjective beliefs about the probability of default would, in fact, be quite sensitive to changes in macroeconomic conditions. Some of the other features of condition (5) which make the anti-orthodox outcome more likely are similarly more likely to occur in countries experiencing financial crisis. For example, the effect of higher interest rates on expected inflation and exchange rate depreciation is likely to be small in countries like Brazil, where the exchange rate regime was credited with eliminating hyperinflation and where fears of renewed inflation are unlikely to be calmed even by the tightest monetary policies. As a Laffer curve type of relationship, the mechanism described in this note has features in common with other similar analyses. Examples include models of seigniorage like that of Bruno and Fischer (1990), and the debt relief Laffer curve of Krugman (1989). Like any such analysis, a theoretical framework highlights only the feasibility of anti-orthodox outcomes, the question of whether or not such outcomes are plausible is a measurement issue. While it is possible to speculate that some of the conditions implied by (5) are more likely to occur in countries experiencing fiscal or balance of payments crises, an evaluation of the likelihood of unconventional policy outcomes depends crucially on measuring the fundamental opposing forces near the critical point of the Laffer curve. Hence, while the framework described here is suggestive for thinking about the plausibility of anti-orthodox outcomes, more definitive measurement of the relevant effects is left for future research. References Corsetti, G., Pesenti, P., Roubini, N., 1998. What caused the Asian currency and financial crisis? Part II: The policy debate. In: National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. W6834. Bruno, M., Fischer, S., 1990. Seigniorage, operating rules and the high inflation trap. Quarterly Journal of Economics 105, 353 374. Krugman, P., 1998. Will Asia bounce back? speech for Credit Suisse First Boston, Hong Kong. Krugman, P., 1989. Market based debt reduction schemes. In: Frenkel, J.A., Dooley, M.P., Wickam, P. (Eds.), Analytical Issues in Debt, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Sachs, J., 1998. Making it work. Economist, September 12.