Should China Revalue? Domingo Cavallo and Joaquín Cottani

Similar documents
Good Bye Undervaluation, Hello Stagflation

Period 3 MBA Program January February MACROECONOMICS IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY Core Course. Professor Ilian Mihov

THE ROLE OF THE RENMINBI IN CHINA S EXTERNAL ADJUSTMENT

University of Toronto January 25, 2007 ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2 L0101 L0201 L0401 L5101 MW MW 1-2 MW 2-3 W 6-8

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 4

The global context and its implications for Latin America. Dani Rodrik May 17, 2010

Chapter 19 (8) International Monetary Systems: An Historical Overview

Economics, 6th ed., 2016, Prof. Dr. P. Zamaros. presentation 29 policy dilemmas & stablization

dr Bartłomiej Rokicki Chair of Macroeconomics and International Trade Theory Faculty of Economic Sciences, University of Warsaw

Economic Interaction

Econ 340. Recall Macro from Econ 102. Recall Macro from Econ 102. Recall Macro from Econ 102. Recall Macro from Econ 102

12 ECB GLOBAL IMBALANCES: RECENT DEVELOPMENTS AND POLICY REQUIREMENTS

3/9/2010. Topics PP542. Macroeconomic Goals (cont.) Macroeconomic Goals. Gold Standard. Macroeconomic Goals (cont.) International Monetary History

CRS Report for Congress

(V) SMALL OPEN ECONOMIES LECTURES 14 & 15

The Case for Chinese Capital Controls. Global Economics Monthly February 2016

Appendix: Analysis of Exchange Rates Pursuant to the Act

International Trade. International Trade, Exchange Rates, and Macroeconomic Policy. International Trade. International Trade. International Trade

Topic 7: The Mundell-Fleming Model

Chapter 4 Monetary and Fiscal. Framework

Slides for International Finance Macroeconomic Policy (KOM Chapter 19)

CRS Report for Congress

The Impact of an Increase In The Money Supply and Government Spending In The UK Economy

Chapter 5. Saving and Investment in the Open Economy. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

The fiscal adjustment after the crisis in Argentina

Trade led Growth in Times of Crisis Asia Pacific Trade Economists Conference 2 3 November 2009, Bangkok. Session 1

China s Currency: A Summary of the Economic Issues

Simultaneous Equilibrium in Output and Financial Markets: The Short Run Determination of Output, the Exchange Rate and the Current Account

TWO PRINCIPLES OF DEBT AND NATIONAL INCOME DYNAMICS IN A PURE CREDIT ECONOMY. Jan Toporowski

Objectives of the lecture

Econ 340. Forms of Exchange Rates. Forms of Exchange Rates. Forms of Exchange Rates. Forms of Exchange Rates. Outline: Exchange Rates

An Introduction to Basic Macroeconomic Markets

The Balance of Payments

EC 205 Lecture 20 04/05/15

Macroeconomics in an Open Economy

Economy at Risk: The Growing U.S. Trade Deficit

The Professional Forecasters

How Important Are U.S. Capital Flows into Mexico?

Closed vs. Open Economies

Chapter 13 The Open Economy Revisited: the Mundell-Fleming Model and the Exchange-Rate Regime

A Macroeconomic Theory of the Open Economy

Investment Insights. How important is China to the world? Introduction. China s spillover effects

UGBA 101B Macroeconomic Analysis Professor Steven Wood. Exam #2 ANSWERS

China s Exchange Rate and Monetary Policy. Bennett T. McCallum. Shadow Open Market Committee. May 2, 2004

International Linkages and Domestic Policy

PubPol 201. Module 1: International Trade Policy. Class 3 Outline. Definitions. Class 3 Outline. Definitions. Definitions. Class 3

The US Imbalancing Act: Can the Current Account Deficit Continue?

LECTURES 7-9: POLICY INSTRUMENTS, including MONEY. L7: Goals and Instruments Policy goals: Internal balance & External balance Policy instruments

Is China the New France?

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

Chapter 19 International Monetary Systems: An Historical Overview

A Map to the Revived Bretton Woods End Game. Peter Garber Global Risk Strategist June 18, 2004

Econ 100B: Macroeconomic Analysis Fall 2008

International Finance

file:///c:/users/moha/desktop/mac8e/new folder (13)/CourseComp...

Chapter 24 CRISES IN EMERGING MARKETS

University of Toronto December 3, 2010 ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY. Term Test #2 L0101 L0301 L0401 M 2-4 W 2-4 R 2-4

10 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapt er. Key Concepts. Aggregate Supply1

6 The Open Economy. This chapter:

The Economics of the European Union

PubPol 201. Module 1: International Trade Policy. Class 3 Trade Deficits; Currency Manipulation

Table 1 below is from Sharmila Devadas & Norman Loayza (2018) When is a current account Deficit bad? World Bank Malaysia Hub, No, 17, October

Rebalancing Growth in China: A Three-Handed Approach

Supply and Demand over the Business Cycle

6. The Aggregate Demand and Supply Model

Movements of goods and services across borders are often thought of as

The Mundell-Fleming model

Balance of Payments, Debt, Financial Crises, and Stabilization Policies

Lecture #8: How Scary is the US Trade Deficit?

Answers to Questions: Chapter 7

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

Chapter 6. The Open Economy

The Balance of Payments. Balance of Payments. Balance of Payments Accounts. Balance of Payments Accounts. They are composed of the following:

The Open Economy Revisited: the Exchange-Rate Regime

Lecture 5: Flexible prices - the monetary model of the exchange rate. Lecture 6: Fixed-prices - the Mundell- Fleming model

China s macroeconomic imbalances: causes and consequences. John Knight and Wang Wei

Macroeconomics and the Global Economic Environment (FNCE 613) SAMPLE EXAM 1

Chapter 18 Exchange Rate Theories (modified version)

7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapter. Key Concepts

Georgetown University. From the SelectedWorks of Robert C. Shelburne. Robert C. Shelburne, United Nations Economic Commission for Europe.

POST-CRISIS GLOBAL REBALANCING CONFERENCE ON GLOBALIZATION AND THE LAW OF THE SEA WASHINGTON DC, DEC 1-3, Barry Bosworth

Prices and Output in an Open Economy: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

A SIMPLE SOLUTION TO CHINA S PENSION CRISIS David D. Li and Ling Li

MACROECONOMICS. The Open Economy Revisited: the Mundell-Fleming Model and the Exchange-Rate Regime MANKIW N. GREGORY

Model Question Paper Economics - II (MSF1A4)

The Impact of the Global Crisis on China and its Reaction (ARI)

Global Financial Crisis and China s Countermeasures

Macroeconomic Theory and Policy (2nd Edition)

"The Continuing Problem of China's Currency Management Policy"

TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES

The IS-LM-BP=0 Model (aka Mundell-Fleming ) under Fixed Rates

EXAM 3: Version A. Econ 2203 Fall Instructions:

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY LECTURE 7: INTRODUCTION TO THE OPEN ECONOMY

Against the Consensus Reflections on the Great Recession. Justin Yifu Lin National School of Development Peking University

UNIVERSITY OF TORONTO Faculty of Arts and Science. August Examination 2017 ECO 209Y. Duration: 2 hours

Question 5 : Franco Modigliani's answer to Simon Kuznets's puzzle regarding long-term constancy of the average propensity to consume is that : the ave

Macro for SCS Nov. 29, International Trade & Finance

EC202 Macroeconomics

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY. Term Test #2. December 13, 2017

5. Openness in Goods and Financial Markets: The Current Account, Exchange Rates and the International Monetary System

Transcription:

Should China Revalue? Domingo Cavallo and Joaquín Cottani According to many G7 analysts the solution to China s macroeconomic imbalance, which manifests itself in the form of a large balance of payments surplus and a negative output gap (overheating of the economy) is to revalue the renminbi (RMB). As Morris Goldstein (2004) puts it, this is nothing but the classic solution prosed by James Meade in 1951. hus, in the view of these (mostly Western) observers the problem in China is her decision to peg the RMB to the dollar rather than letting it appreciate. In this note, we argue that this emphasis on China s exchange rate licy is excessive and may even be counterproductive. Understanding the Nature of China s Macroeconomic Imbalance Assume a country in which domestic prices are flexible, capital is freely mobile, and gross national saving is typically (structurally?) lower than gross domestic investment, he US and most countries in Latin America fit this description. Figure 1 shows what macroeconomic equilibrium would look like in this case, using a conventional Swan diagram representing the markets of tradable () and nontradable (N) goods and services, whereby the supply and demand schedules are drawn as functions of the real exchange rate (p), defined as the relative price of nontradables with respect to tradables. Since p is flexible, supply of N equals demand at the equilibrium price p=p 0. However, since investment is higher than national saving, there is excess demand for, hence a deficit in the current account (CAD). 1 his deficit is, in turn, is financed by a net capital inflow (KAS) of the same dollar magnitude. he balance of payments is, therefore, in equilibrium. Production levels are N 0 and 0 for nontradables and tradables, respectively, and absorption levels are N 0 for nontradables and A 0 > 0 for tradables. Full employment prevails. Moreover, since P N (the nominal price of N) is flexible, full employment holds independently of whether the exchange rate is fixed or flexible. 2 Now, supse that net capital inflows fall to zero. Absorption declines (D N and D shift to the left). But, since p is flexible, equilibrium is quickly restored. At the new equilibrium, the RER is p 1 <p 0, resulting in lower production of N (N 1 ) and higher production of ( 1 ). Full employment is preserved. If, instead, p were inflexible downwards (which would require a combination of fixed exchange rate and sticky nontradable prices), the result would be unemployment, as shown in Figure 2. he economy produces the same amount of as before ( 0 ), but a lower amount of N (N 2 <N 0, where N 2 is effective demand at p=p 0 ). N 2 N 2 is a measure of the output gap. Mexico in 1994-95 is a good example of this situation. 1 echnically, the excess demand for tradable goods equals the trade account deficit. For the horizontal distance between D and S to equal CAD, net factor income and transfers have to be added to S or subtracted from D. 2 his macroeconomic equilibrium is not stationary, however. Over time, the current account deficit reduces the country s financial wealth while sitive net investment increases the capital stock. ationary equilibrium requires not only that national wealth be constant as a share of GDP, but also that the actual comsition between net foreign assets and capital be constant and equal to the desired comsition.

How does China compare to this? On the one hand, China has a capital account surplus, just as in the previous case. On the other, unlike the previous situation, China also has a current account surplus. According to Goldstein, the underlying current account surplus for 2004 is 2.5% of GDP and the normal capital account surplus is 1.5%, hence yielding a sustainable balance of payments surplus equal to 4% of GDP. 3 Figure 3 shows how these two surpluses can occur simultaneously assuming, for simplicity, that KAS is exogenous. In equilibrium, a sitive KAS would lead to a current account deficit of the same size, just as in Figure 1. his, however, does not need to be true if there is disequilibrium. At a price such as p 3, there is both a capital account surplus ( 0 A 0 ) and a current account surplus (A 3 3 ). he latter implies there is excess supply of. In the N market, on the other hand, effective demand (N 3 ) exceeds notional supply (N 3 ). Since N 3 is the amount that suffices to reach full employment given = 3, N 3 N 3 is a measure of the overheating in the economy. Because p is below equilibrium, producers of N goods face a higher demand than they would willingly supply. In trying to meet this demand, they overstretch. Inevitably, scarcities and black markets arise. Currency Revaluation Clearly, one way to eliminate China s disequilibrium would be to revalue the RMB. his would allow p to rise up to the int where demand for N equals supply (from p 3 to p 0 in Figure 3). Goldstein, for example, argues if the current undervaluation of the Chinese currency (which he estimates as something between 15 and 30%) were totally eliminated the underlying current account balance would shift from a 2.5% of GDP surplus to a 1.5% deficit in line with the normal KAS, at which int persistent or systematic reserve accumulation would stop. his solution, however, implies that P, the price of tradable goods, would have to fall by 13 to 23%. As noted by Robert Mundell (2004), the ensuing deflation would hurt many Chinese borrowers, particularly those that produce tradable goods, by increasing the real value of their liabilities at a time when, already, there are serious concerns about the solvency of many Chinese institutions, including the banking sector. A Better Solution In a predominantly market economy, such as Mexico, pegging the exchange rate to the US dollar in the context of a substantial accumulation of foreign reserves would lead to excessive money creation, hence high domestic inflation. 4 hus, even if the nominal exchange rate does not appreciate vis-à-vis the dollar, the real exchange rate would. 5 What prevents this type of adjustment from taking place in China? he main explanation, in our view, is that many domestic prices, including of labor, are controlled by the government (as is output in many economic activities, such as food processing, transrt, 3 he actual current account surplus will be lower this year due to the overheating of the economy. 4 Unless (a) there is a gradual process of monetization underway, whereby nominal money demand grows faster than nominal income; or (b) the central bank engages in monetary sterilization. In China, (a) is ssible and (b) is true. However, (a) + (b) is unlikely to fully absorb the annual increase in money supply created by the monetization of China s massive balance of payments surplus. 5 his is, in fact, what happened in Mexico in 1992-94 at a time when net capital inflows were very strong.

and energy distribution). In such conditions, the growth in aggregate demand, which is fueled by monetary expansion continually pushes real output beyond its tential level creating persistent overheating in the economy, but without the associated increase in (observed) inflation. In Mexico, excessive liquidity stemming from the balance of payments would also pressure individuals, banks, and corrations to buy foreign exchange. Here, too, administrative controls stand in the way of market adjustment in China, a country in which the capital account is notoriously repressed, particularly the outflows. Were these controls eliminated, or even reduced, the surplus in the capital account would fall dramatically. So, China s fundamental problem is not that it manipulates the exchange rate system but that it relies too heavily on price and capital controls. If China s price and capital market distortions are taken as given, introducing exchange rate flexibility can be justified as a second best. 6 he first best, however, is for China to liberalize domestic markets and the capital account. Figure 4 shows why. Supse that the capital account is liberalized up to the int where the surplus disappears (KAS=0). Clearing the N market would take a smaller increase in p than before (from p 3 to p 1 ), which can be achieved via a once and for all increase in P N. his type of adjustment has the additional advantage that the real value of private and public sector liabilities would be reduced, hence improving loan performance. rengthening Investment Efficiency While China s gross domestic investment is huge by international standards (over 40% of GDP in recent years) its quality is not so great. It takes approximately $4 of net new capital to increase GDP by $1. By contrast, in the US it takes only $2. 7 his implies investment efficiency is 50% lower in China than in the US. his is not surprising given relative price distortions, including real exchange rate undervaluation, and a lack of market-based mechanisms determining investment in China. What is remarkable, however, is the magnitude of the relative inefficiency gap. Should China invest as efficiently as the US, it could grow at 10% per year without overheating the economy while investing only 30% of GDP (20% in net terms). Assuming, more realistically, that China s investment efficiency improves to 2/3 of that of the US, the required gross ratio is 40%. By today s Chinese saving standards, this would still leave room for a current account surplus. However, as economic liberalization progressed and financial markets deepened, it would be natural to expect a reduction in the national saving rate, hence the current account surplus. 6 It is not surprising that Meade s classic recommendation, formulated at a time when prices were assumed to be institutionally inflexible and capital mobility was low, is found to be valid today in China. 7 hese are back-of-the-envelope calculations based on the following assumptions: (a) full-employment growth is 7% in China and 3% in the US; (b) normal net investment is 28% of GDP in China (38% gross minus 10% depreciation) versus 6% in the US.

Conclusion Pronents of revaluation in China take market distortions as given. wo such distortions are domestic price controls (particularly in the nontradables sector) and capital controls (particularly on capital outflows). Given China s history of reform gradualism, assuming that these distortions will be maintained for a long time may be realistic. Yet, an alternative solution would be for China to liberalize domestic prices and the capital account more rapidly. Allowing prices and the capital account to adjust in resnse to excessive reserve accumulation would reduce the need for the nominal exchange rate to take the brunt of the adjustment. Market distortions are at the root of another, perhaps more fundamental, problem in China that Western analysts often ignore: the low quality of its investment. If China invested more efficiently, it could grow even faster than it is growing while investing the same or less. While the current account surplus would not necessarily decline in the short or medium run, high growth would be ssible without overheating in the economy, thereby averting the risk of a hard landing. Just as lower distortions at home would improve capital productivity, a freer capital account would result in more efficient investments abroad. Instead of the Central Bank of China accumulating US reasuries, there would be private Chinese investors accumulating a broader diversity of global assets, including those of other emerging markets, hence facilitating a more efficient global rebalancing of external surpluses. Eventually, as China becomes a more prosperous nation, the current account surplus would disappear. he bottom line is, thus, very simple: China would be better advised by Western analysts to embrace the market economy more forcefully and rapidly than to simply revalue its currency. References Goldstein, Morris (2004), Adjusting China s Exchange Rate Policies. Paper presented at the IMF seminar on he Foreign Exchange System, Dalian, China, May 26-27. Meade, James (1951), he Balance of Payments, Oxford University Press, London. Mundell, Robert (2004), China s Exchange Rate: he Case for the atus Quo. Paper presented at the IMF seminar on he Foreign Exchange System, Dalian, China, May 26-27.

Figure 1 p=pn/pt CAD=KAS p1 N1 No N o 1 Ao Figure 2 CAD N2 N0 N o Ao

Figure 3 KAS p3 CAS N3 No N3' N o A3 Ao 3 Figure 4 p1 p3 N3 N1 N3' N 1 3