Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007

Similar documents
The Equity Premium in. Brock s Asset Pricing Model

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Review of the Equity Premium Puzzle

A Continuous-Time Asset Pricing Model with Habits and Durability

Asset Returns in an Endogenous Growth Model with Incomplete Markets *

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

The Fisher Equation and Output Growth

Market Survival in the Economies with Heterogeneous Beliefs

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Applying the Basic Model

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk

The Bond Premium in a DSGE Model with Long-Run Real and Nominal Risks

Interest Rates and Asset Prices

Economics 8106 Macroeconomic Theory Recitation 2

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

Assets with possibly negative dividends

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules

The Return to Capital and the Business Cycle

Money in an RBC framework

Intertemporally Dependent Preferences and the Volatility of Consumption and Wealth

Topic 3: International Risk Sharing and Portfolio Diversification

Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles. Abstract

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

Appendix: Net Exports, Consumption Volatility and International Business Cycle Models.

Research Summary and Statement of Research Agenda

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

The Return to Capital and the Business Cycle

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Portfolio Investment

The Return to Capital and the Business Cycle

Stock Price, Risk-free Rate and Learning

The Japanese Saving Rate

Money in a Neoclassical Framework

A simple wealth model

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

Dynamic Asset Pricing Model

A note on testing for tax-smoothing in general equilibrium

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

14.05 Lecture Notes. Labor Supply

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Evaluating Asset Pricing Models with Limited Commitment using Household Consumption Data 1

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles

Oil Monopoly and the Climate

EU i (x i ) = p(s)u i (x i (s)),

Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability

Lecture 2. (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis. (2) Precautionary Savings. Erick Sager. September 21, 2015

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

Macroeconomics and finance

A numerical analysis of the monetary aspects of the Japanese economy: the cash-in-advance approach

Log-Normal Approximation of the Equity Premium in the Production Model

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130

Discussion of Heaton and Lucas Can heterogeneity, undiversified risk, and trading frictions solve the equity premium puzzle?

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Over the latter half of the 1990s, the U.S. economy experienced both

1 No-arbitrage pricing

CAN CAPITAL INCOME TAX IMPROVE WELFARE IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET ECONOMY WITH A LABOR-LEISURE DECISION?

Asset Prices and Business Cycles with. Financial Frictions

Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS)

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Econ 210C: Macroeconomic Theory

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis

Problem set Fall 2012.

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Topic 7: Asset Pricing and the Macroeconomy

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010

Feb. 20th, Recursive, Stochastic Growth Model

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

Transcription:

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert February 15, 2007 Abstract In this paper we use a simple model with a single Cobb Douglas firm and a consumer with a CRRA utility function to show the difference in the equity premia in the production based Brock model and the consumption based Lucas model. With this simple example we show that the equity premium in the production based model exceeds that of the consumption based model by roughly β 1 1. 1 Introduction As was reported by Mehra and Prescott (1985), the equity premium puzzle arises because for no reasonable parameterizations of the Lucas (1978) asset pricing model is the theoretical equity premium as large as the empirically observed one. In a review of the literature on both the equity premium and the risk free rate puzzles, Kocherlakota (1996) states... there is now a vast literature that seeks to resolve these two puzzles. A number of alternate models have been developed to explain the equity premium puzzle. Among these are models on habit formation, such as Constantinides (1990), Campbell and Cochrane (1999), Boldrin, Christiano, and Fisher (2001), Campbell (2001) and the references cited there. McGrattan and Prescott (June 2001) find that taxes can be a significant determinant of the equity premium. Brock and Turnovsky (1981) show how government policy can have an impact on asset values. In a paper that goes well beyond the equity premium puzzle, Weitzman (September 2004) argues that the modeling should be forward looking, stating... the correct interpretation requires not frequentist objective estimates of the past mean and variance, but rather Bayesian subjective estimates of the future mean and variance. (Emphasis in the original.) These models all capture various aspects of human behavior that have an effect on the level of equity premium. However, those that are explicitly designed to explain the equity premium puzzle do not include production. There is a folk theorem that there is an equivalence between production and endowment models, but as expected, the set of objects that are equivalent to each other are not explicitly spelled out. Mehra and Prescott (1985) write, With our structure, the process on the endowment is exogenous We thank W. A. Brock for many very helpful conversations and suggestions on the subject of this paper. For all errors of omission and commission we alone are culpable. Faculty of Business Administration, Bilkent University. Department of Economics, University of Wisconsin. 1

and there is neither capital accumulation nor production. Modifying the technologo admit these opportunities cannot overturn our conclusion, because expanding the set of technologies in this way does not increase the set of joint equilibrium processes on consumption and asset prices. Geweke (June 1999) raises the point that The benefits of an analytically rigorous economic theory will be realized only when harnessed to the same high standards for measurement. He found that The posterior distribution for the mean of the risk free rate and the equity premium supports values consistent with... dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models designed to address this question. Campbell (2001) comments that Models with production also help one to move away from the common assumption that stock market dividends equal consumption... and he goes on to conclude that... it will ultimately be more satisfactoro derive both dividends and consumption within a general equilibrium model. This is, of course, what Brock does in his asset pricing model. Akdeniz and Dechert (2006) show that there are parameterizations of the Brock (1982) that give much higher equity premia than the consumption based model. In referring to Brock s asset pricing model, Black (1995) remarked, If we add non-separable utility, adjustment costs for moving capital from one sector to another, human capital, and a few other features, we will have a model of the kind I favor. This kind of model would indeed include many useful components that would make the results more realistic. Nevertheless, as was shown by Akdeniz and Dechert, including production alone substantially increases the equity premium. Jermann (1998) shows that in a model with habit formation and production (he uses a capital adjustment cost model) the equity premium can reach 6.16% when the relative risk aversion parameter is 5. This is higher than for models with only habit persistence as the determinant of the equity premium. Dunbar (2006) uses a production model with idiosyncratic shocks that also has a high equity premium. Angeletos and Calvet (2006) use a model with idiosyncratic shocks and incomplete markets to show that values of the equity premium around 4.5% are possible. In all of this research, the production process is an essential element in achieving these results. In this paper we perform the following thought experiment: use the Brock (1982) model to generate the sequences of consumption, investment and output. Then price the consumption sequence as in Lucas (1978) and compare the equity premia from both models. As we show in section 4 there is a direct analytical link between these two prices, with which we can derive a formula for the equity premia difference. In section 5 we use the standard model with a logarithmic utility function and Cobb Douglas production function to show that the equity premium in the Brock model is strictly larger than it is in the Lucas model. 2 Consumption Based Asset Prices In the Lucas (1978) model a consumption stream {c t } is priced using the first order condition of dynamic optimization, u (c t ) P ( ) t = βe t u (c t+1 ) Pt+1 + c t+1 (2.1) It is notationally useful to define the discounted intertemporal marginal rate of substi- 2

tution by Γ t+1 = βu (c t+1 ) u (c t ) (2.2) and to write the pricing equation (2.1) as P t = E t Γ t+1 ( Pt+1 + c t+1 ) (2.3) Any asset that is in zero net supply can similarly be priced. A one period bond that pays one unit of the consumption good at date t + 1 will have a price at date t of B t = E t Γ t+1 (2.4) With equations (2.3) and (2.4) we can compute the consumption based equity premium, Pt+1 E t 1 (2.5) P t B t 3 The One Firm Model Consider the Brock and Mirman (1972) growth model: E β t u(c t ) max {x t} t=0 subject to: c t + x t = +1 = f(x t, ξ t+1 ) where c t and x t are the consumption and investment at time t, and ξ t+1 is the production shock that affects output, +1, at date t + 1. Following the method of Brock (1982), we can also use this growth model as an asset pricing model. The consumer s budget constraint is c t + x t + P t S t (π t + P t )S t 1 + r t x t 1 where P t S t r t π t Share price at date t Number of shares held at date t Rental on capital received at date t Profits paid as dividends at date t 3

The consumer treats profits (in this model all profits are paid out as dividends) and rents, π t and r t, as exogenous to his/her consumption, rental and share purchase decisions, c t, x t and S t. In a rational expectations equilibrium the following hold: π t = f(x t 1, ξ t ) f (x t 1, ξ t )x t 1 r t = f (x t 1, ξ t ) S t = 1 c t + x t = The first order equations with respect to x t and S t for this model are 1 = E t Γ t+1 r t+1 (3.1) P t = E t Γt+1 ( Pt+1 + π t+1 ) (3.2) and the equity premium is Pt+1 + π t+1 E t 1 (3.3) P t B t 4 The Comparison of Equity Premia The difference in the equity premium from equations (2.5) and (3.3) is P t+1 + π t+1 E t P t+1 P t P t (4.1) In order to complete the analysis to see if there is, in fact, a difference in the equity premia in the two models, we need to solve for the relationship between P t and P t. Let the optimal solution in a Brock production model have {c t } as the consumption sequence. Price this sequence with the Lucas model. Its price sequence will be P t. Let {P t } be the price sequence from the Brock model. We can get a direct comparison of these two price sequences by expanding equation (3.2) and using equation (3.1) and the REE conditions: P t = E t Γ t+1 (P t+1 + π t+1 ) = E t Γ t+1 (P t+1 + +1 r t+1 ) = E t Γ t+1 (P t+1 + x t+1 + c t+1 ) E t Γ t+1 r t+1 x t = E t Γ t+1 (P t+1 + x t+1 + c t+1 ) x t Rewrite this last equation as: (P t + x t ) = E t Γ t+1 (P t+1 + x t+1 + c t+1 ) (4.2) Now subtract equation (4.2) from equation (2.3): 4

( Pt P t x t ) = E t Γ t+1 ( Pt+1 P t+1 x t+1 ) Bhe transversality condition, the terms in parentheses are zero, so P t = P t + x t (4.3) This is the relationship between the asset prices in the two models. The difference in the returns on these two types of assets is P t+1 + π t+1 E t P t+1 Pt+1 + π t+1 = E t P t+1 + x t+1 P t P t P t P t + x t (4.4) We can use this equation to measure the difference in the equity premia in the two models. 5 An Example Consider the well analyzed case of a logarithmic utility function with a Cobb Douglas production function: u(c) = ln(c) f(x, ξ) = ξx α where 0 < α < 1 and ξ > 0 wp1. The solution (which is well known) can be found in Brock (1982): x t = αβ π t = (1 α) P t = β(1 α) 1 β With these equations we can solve for the consumption based asset price: P t = P t + x t = β(1 αβ) 1 β Next, compute the difference in the asset returns from equation (4.4): 5

P t+1 + π t+1 E t P t+1 P t P t P t+1 = E t + π t+1 P t+1 P t P t P t = E t yt+1 + 1 β β = (β 1 1)E t yt+1 y t+1 +1 (5.1) Notice that this difference is positive wp1. Therefore, the equity premia in the production based asset model is strictly larger than it is in the consumption based model. In this example we can compute the conditional expected equity premia difference: (β 1 yt+1 1)E t = (β 1 1) (αβ)α ξ y 1 α t where ξ = E ξ t. This difference is larger in the trough of a business cycle than it is at the peak. 6 Numerical Results In order to calculate the value of the mean difference in the equity premium in the two models over the business cycle, we need to compute the expected value of equation (5.1): (β 1 yt+1 1)E (6.2) We simulated the model for values of α = 0.4, β = 0.97 and for the CRRA parameter in the range of 1 4. The simulations were for 100,000 time periods and the value of E +1 / was in the range of 1.002 1.003. Thus, for this example the mean value of the difference in the equity premium in the two models is (β 1 yt+1 1)E = 0.031 7 Conclusion This example should lao rest the notion that production in and of itself does not add anything to the analysis of asset prices. In this example, there is only one firm with 100% depreciation. In Akdeniz and Dechert (2006) it was shown that for a model with 4 firms, with partial depreciation and for which the technology parameters are state dependent the equity premium can easily be twice the value of β 1 1. This is due, in part, to the fact that such a model also can include idiosyncratic risk which is also a determinant of the equity premium. 6

A point that should not be lost on the reader, is that any research on asset prices that uses a representative consumer model can include a comparison of the consumption based prices with the asset prices in the model. As our equations (2.2) (2.3) show, one only needs onlhe consumption stream generated bhe model to compute the Lucas asset prices. Comparisons, such as equation (3.3) with (2.5) can be readily made and reported. References Akdeniz, L., and W. D. Dechert (2006): The Equity Premium in Brock s Asset Pricing Model, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control. Angeletos, G. M., and L. Calvet (2006): Idiosyncratic Investment Risk and Aggregate Savings, MIT Working Paper. Black, F. (1995): Exploring General Equilibrium. The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts. Boldrin, M., L. J. Christiano, and J. D. M. Fisher (2001): Habit Persistence, Asset Returns and the Business Cycle, American Economic Review, 91, 149 166. Brock, W. A. (1982): Asset Prices in a Production Economy, in The Economics of Information and Uncertainty, ed. by J. J. McCall, pp. 1 46. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Brock, W. A., and L. Mirman (1972): Optimal Economic Growth and Uncertainty: The Discounted Case, Journal of Economic Theory, 4, 479 513. Brock, W. A., and S. J. Turnovsky (1981): The Analysis of Macroeconomic Policies in Perfect Foresight Equilibrium, International Economic Review, 22(1), 179 209. Campbell, J. Y. (2001): Consumption-Based Asset Pricing, Forthcoming, Handbook of the Economics of Finance, G. Constantinides, M. Harris and R. Stulz, eds. Campbell, J. Y., and J. H. Cochrane (1999): By Force of Habit: A Consumption- Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior, Journal of Political Economy, 107, 205 251. Constantinides, G. (1990): Habit Formation: A Resolution of the Equity Premium Puzzle, Journal of Political Economy, 98, 519 543. Dunbar, G. (2006): Collateral, Production Risk and Asset-Pricing Puzzles,. Geweke, J. (June 1999): Computational Experiments and Reality, University of Iowa URL: http://www.biz.uiowa.edu/faculty/jgeweke/papers/papere/cer.pdf. Jermann, J. U. (1998): Asset Pricing in Production Economies, Journal of Monetary Economics. Kocherlakota, N. R. (1996): The Equity Premium: It s Still a Puzzle, Journal of Economic Literature, XXXIV, 42 71. Lucas, R. E. (1978): Asset Prices in an Exchange Economy, Econometrica, 46, 1429 1445. 7

McGrattan, E. R., and E. Prescott (June 2001): Taxes, Regulations, and Asset Prices, Working Paper 610, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Mehra, R., and E. C. Prescott (1985): The Equity Premium: A Puzzle, Journal of Monetary Economics, 15, 145 161. Weitzman, M. L. (September 2004): The Bayesian Family of Equity Non Puzzles, Harvard University. 8