Volume 38, Issue 1. The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy

Similar documents
The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock

E-322 Muhammad Rahman CHAPTER-3

How do stock prices respond to fundamental shocks?

Asian Economic and Financial Review SOURCES OF EXCHANGE RATE FLUCTUATION IN VIETNAM: AN APPLICATION OF THE SVAR MODEL

Global and National Macroeconometric Modelling: A Long-run Structural Approach Overview on Macroeconometric Modelling Yongcheol Shin Leeds University

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus)

Workshop on resilience

Asian Economic and Financial Review EMPIRICAL TESTING OF EXCHANGE RATE AND INTEREST RATE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS IN CHINA

PRIVATE AND GOVERNMENT INVESTMENT: A STUDY OF THREE OECD COUNTRIES. MEHDI S. MONADJEMI AND HYEONSEUNG HUH* University of New South Wales

UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES

Money-Income Causality: VAR Estimation 1

Testing the Stability of Demand for Money in Tonga

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

The Effects of Oil Shocks on Turkish Macroeconomic Aggregates

Information Technology, Productivity, Value Added, and Inflation: An Empirical Study on the U.S. Economy,

Financial Econometrics

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

MONEY, PRICES AND THE EXCHANGE RATE: EVIDENCE FROM FOUR OECD COUNTRIES

Monetary Policy Shock Analysis Using Structural Vector Autoregression

Identifying Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Components of Inflation Rate: A Structural Vector Autoregression Analysis for Japan

MONEY AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: SOME INTERNATIONAL EVIDENCE. Abstract

ON THE LONG-TERM MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SOCIAL SPENDING IN THE UNITED STATES (*) Alfredo Marvão Pereira The College of William and Mary

Okun s law revisited. Is there structural unemployment in developed countries?

MFE Macroeconomics Week 3 Exercise

Volume 29, Issue 2. Measuring the external risk in the United Kingdom. Estela Sáenz University of Zaragoza

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

Is the Exchange Rate a Shock Absorber or Source of Shocks? New Empirical Evidence

Macro Notes: Introduction to the Short Run

The Dynamic Effects of Personal and Corporate Income Tax Changes in the United States

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

Assessing the Importance of Global Shocks versus Country-specific Shocks

Inequality and GDP per capita: The Role of Initial Income

Optimal fiscal policy

The Price Puzzle and Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism in Pakistan: Structural Vector Autoregressive Approach

slides chapter 6 Interest Rate Shocks

Long Run Money Neutrality: The Case of Guatemala

Monetary and Fiscal Policy Switching with Time-Varying Volatilities

THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON EMERGING ECONOMIES. A TVP-VAR APPROACH

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

Quantity versus Price Rationing of Credit: An Empirical Test

Iranian Economic Review, Vol.15, No.28, Winter Business Cycle Features in the Iranian Economy. Asghar Shahmoradi Ali Tayebnia Hossein Kavand

5. STRUCTURAL VAR: APPLICATIONS

AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF THE PUBLIC DEBT RELEVANCE TO THE ECONOMIC GROWTH OF THE USA

Government Spending Shocks in Quarterly and Annual Time Series

The Effects of Fiscal Policy in New Zealand: Evidence from a VAR Model with Debt Constraints

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults

Financial Econometrics Notes. Kevin Sheppard University of Oxford

Government Spending Multipliers in Good Times and in Bad: Evidence from U.S. Historical Data

The Fisher Effect and The Long Run Phillips Curve --in the case of Japan, Sweden and Italy --

Web Appendix. Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? Olivier Coibion

Bank Lending Shocks and the Euro Area Business Cycle

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility

What Drives Commodity Price Booms and Busts?

MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies

Supplementary Appendix. July 22, 2016

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU

The Relationship between Inflation, Inflation Uncertainty and Output Growth in India

EC910 Econometrics B. Exchange Rate Pass-Through and Inflation Dynamics in. the United Kingdom: VAR analysis of Exchange Rate.

Relationship between Inflation and Unemployment in India: Vector Error Correction Model Approach

Thi-Thanh Phan, Int. Eco. Res, 2016, v7i6, 39 48

Part III. Cycles and Growth:

Performance of Statistical Arbitrage in Future Markets

Practical Issues in Monetary Policy Targeting

Working Paper IIMK/WPS/252/EA/2017/36. June 2017

Monetary Policy and Medium-Term Fiscal Planning

The Effects of Japanese Monetary Policy Shocks on Exchange Rates: A Structural Vector Error Correction Model Approach

Identifying of the fiscal policy shocks

Foreign direct investment and profit outflows: a causality analysis for the Brazilian economy. Abstract

Determinants of Stock Prices in Ghana

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

Estimation of Volatility of Cross Sectional Data: a Kalman filter approach

Models of the Minimum Wage Impact upon Employment, Wages and Prices: The Romanian Case

Empirical Analysis of the US Swap Curve Gough, O., Juneja, J.A., Nowman, K.B. and Van Dellen, S.

User Guide of GARCH-MIDAS and DCC-MIDAS MATLAB Programs

IMPACT OF MACROECONOMIC VARIABLE ON STOCK MARKET RETURN AND ITS VOLATILITY

The Time-Varying Effects of Monetary Aggregates on Inflation and Unemployment

The Impact of Oil Price Volatility on the Real Exchange Rate in Nigeria: An Error Correction Model

An Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between Macroeconomic Variables and Stock Prices in Bangladesh

An Empirical Study on the Relationship between Money Supply, Economic Growth and Inflation

Analysis of monetary policy variables with stock returns using var frame work

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s

Government Spending Shocks in Quarterly and Annual Time Series

WAS FISCAL STIMULUS IN USA IN RECENT CRISES REASONABLE? EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION OF DISCRETIONAL FISCAL POLICY ON OUTPUT IN A SVEC FRAMEWORK

The Reaction of Stock Prices to Monetary Policy Shocks in Malaysia: A Structural Vector Autoregressive Model

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Introductory Econometrics for Finance

Business cycle. Giovanni Di Bartolomeo Sapienza University of Rome Department of economics and law

Reassessing Exchange Rate Overshooting in a Monetary Framework

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

ESTIMATING OUTPUT GAP AND POTENTIAL OUTPUT FOR RUSSIA AND ITS USEFULNESS BY FORECASTING INFLATION

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality. June 19, 2017

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Transcription:

Volume 38, Issue 1 The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy Ivan Mendieta-Muñoz Department of Economics, University of Utah Abstract This paper studies if the supply shock derived from the Blanchard-Quah methodology contains a demand driven component in the Mexican economy during the period 1981Q1-2016Q2. We find that supply shocks are not contemporaneously correlated with demand shocks, so that 1) the anomaly in the inflation dynamics to a supply shock is not present if the standard Blanchard-Quah restrictions are employed; and 2) supply (demand) shocks represent the primary source of the long-run variation in output (inflation). The results show that it is possible to identify uncorrelated supply and demand shocks for the Mexican economy using the standard restrictions imposed by the Blanchard-Quah approach. I would like to thank Miguel León-Ledesma and one anonymous referee for helpful suggestions and conversations on a previous version of this paper. All remaining errors are my own. Citation: Ivan Mendieta-Muñoz, (2018) ''The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy'', Economics Bulletin, Volume 38, Issue 1, pages 41-51 Contact: Ivan Mendieta-Muñoz - ivan.mendietamunoz@utah.edu. Submitted: August 17, 2017. Published: January 21, 2018.

1 Introduction Applications of the Blanchard and Quah (1989) (BQ) methodology often find that aggregate supply (AS) shocks are the primary source of variations in real economic activity and that aggregate demand (AD) shocks are the primary source of variations in inflation. These findings have been uestioned by Cover et al. (2006), who showed that AS and AD shocks are highly correlated in the USA. If it is assumed that supply shocks are affected by demand shocks, Cover et al. (2006) demonstrated that AD shocks are now the primary source of variations in real economic activity and that AS shocks represent the primary source of variations in inflation. Similar results have been obtained by other empirical studies for the G-7 and ASEAN countries. Bashar (2011; 2012) found that, if the standard BQ restrictions are employed and the correlation between AS and AD shocks is ignored, a positive supply shock causes the inflation rate to increase in the long-run (which is hard to justify by any macro theory). In the same vein, he also found that the anomaly in the inflation dynamics disappears if supply and demand shocks are allowed to be correlated with causality running from the latter to the former. The results obtained by Cover et al. (2006) and Bashar (2011; 2012) show that it may not possible to identify uncorrelated shocks using the BQ methodology since the AS shock derived from the latter can potentially contain a demand driven component. Therefore, if the possible correlation between AS and AD shocks is ignored, the BQ approach may downplay the role of AD shocks in explaining fluctuations in real economic activity and may lead to anomalies in the inflation dynamics. The current paper studies if the supply shock identified by the BQ methodology contains a demand driven component in the Mexican economy during the period 1981Q1-2016Q2 by considering the sensitivity of AS shocks with respect to AD shocks. Previous studies for the Mexican economy have employed only the standard BQ model to identify the permanent and transitory components of GDP and unemployment rates (Estefan-Dávila, 2014) or modifications of the BQ methodology in order to study other macroeconomic phenomena, such as monetary policy and stagnation (Loría and Ramírez, 2011), the significance and potential dual-nature of oil-price shocks (pure technology and pure expenditure shocks) (Méndez-Marcano, 2014), and structural VAR (SVAR) models identified by sign restrictions to develop new indicators for monetary policy interventions (Pagliacci, 2016). Thus, our paper is the first research that explicitly considers the potential correlation between AS and AD shocks in the Mexican economy. As mentioned before, if such correlation is significant then role of AD and AS shocks discussed in previous studies can be highly misleading. Contrary to the evidence reported in studies for the USA, G-7, and ASEAN countries, we find that AS shocks are not sensitive to AD shocks in the Mexican economy, so that the supply shock identified by the BQ methodology does not contain a demand driven component. Specifically, we find that: 1) the anomaly in the inflation dynamics to a supply shock is not present if the standard BQ restrictions are employed; 2) AS shocks are the primary source of the long-run variation in output; and 3) AD shocks are the primary source of the long-run variation in inflation. Two main conclusions can be derived from our results. First, it is possible to identify uncorrelated AS and AD shocks for the Mexican economy using the standard restrictions imposed by the BQ methodology. In this regard, our findings are in line with Estefan-Dávila (2014), who found that demand shocks explain the majority of fluctuations in unemployment and that supply shocks explain the majority of fluctuations in GDP without considering the possible

correlation between shocks. Second, the findings that AS (AD) shocks are the primary source of the long-run variation in output (inflation) correspond to the viewpoint that negative fluctuations in production are caused by severe economic crises that impact the long-run performance of the economy and that fluctuations in inflation are a conseuence of economic phenomena with transitory effects that do not represent structural changes in the goods and labour markets. The structure of the Mexican economy is different from that of industrialized economies and developing Southeast Asian countries in terms of the goods and services produced, the degree of oligopoly power in different industries, labour market flexibility, and levels of informal employment. Future research should try to implement new models in order to identify the relevant market structures that play a role in explaining the differences between the G-7 and ASEAN countries and Mexico. The next section presents a description of the SVAR models, Section 3 reports the results obtained, and Section 4 concludes. 2 Methodologies Consider a SVAR model that incorporates measures of real output (y t ) and the price level (p t ) that have been differenced sufficiently to achieve stationarity. Since the structural shocks are not directly observable, the usual practice is to retrieve the latter from the estimation of a reduced-form VAR: y t = p t = c i 11 y t i+ c i 21 y t i+ c i 12 p t i+ e y t (1) c i 22 p t i+ e p t (2) where e y t and e p t are the residuals series. The relation between the structural shocks and the reduced-form residuals can be expressed as: e t = G 0 ε t (3) where e t =(et,e y t p ) ; ε t =(εt,ε s t d ), where ε ( t s and εt d are one-standard deviation supply and demand shocks, respectively; and G 0 = A 1 g 0 B = 0 11 g 0 ) 12 g 0 21 g 0 represents the contemporaneous effects of 22 the one-standard deviation shocks on each variable, where A 0 is a 2X2 matrix of coefficients and B is the variance-covariance matrix of structural shocks. The BQ methodology imposes two critical assumptions: 1. The long-run AS is vertical: the AD shock has no long-run effect on y t and a shift in the AD curve will only increase p t proportionately. This long-run restriction implies that g 0 12 = ci 12 1 g 0 ci 22. 22 2. The B matrix is diagonal: the structural shocks are contemporaneously uncorrelated.

Following a simple AS-AD model, Cover et al. (2006) and Bashar (2011; 2012) have employed a Modified SVAR model in which it is possible to relax the assumption that supply and demand shocks are uncorrelated 1 : y t = α p t + φ yi y t i + p t = y t + φ pi p t i + γb 22 ε d + b 11 ε s (4) θ yi y t i + θ pi p t i + b 22 ε d (5) where ε s and ε d are the unit variance structural supply and demand shocks, respectively; b 11 and b 22 represent the standard deviations of both shocks; and the supply shock in euation (4) has two components: b 11 ε s, which represents the independent AS shock; and b 22 ε d, which represents the AS shock induced by an independent AD shock. The coefficient γ measures the extent to which the AS shock is affected by the AD shock. 2 Given the Modified SVAR in euations (4) and (5) and the reduced-form VAR in euations (1) and (2), we have the following relationship between the residuals from the latter and the structural shocks: [ e y] [ ] 1 [ ][ ] t 1 α b11 γb = 22 ε s 1 1 0 b 22 ε d (6) e p t so that the variance-covariance matrix of the reduced-form VAR residuals is defined as: [ var(e y t ) cov(et,e y t p ] [ ][ ] ) b11 (α+γ)b 22 b11 b 11 cov(et p,et) y var(et p = 1+α 1+α 1+α 1+α ) b 11 1+α (1 γ)b 22 1+α (α+γ)b 22 1+α (1 γ)b 22 1+α The final additional restriction reuired to provide exact identification of the system follows the BQ long-run restriction: α = ci 12 1, which implies that the structural AD shock does not ci 22 have any long-run effect on the output level as long as this does not induce the long-run AS to shift. Hence, α yields an estimate of the slope of the short-run AS curve; 1/(1+α) represents an estimate of the immediate effect on output of a 1% structural supply shock; and α/(1+α) represents an estimate of the immediate effect on output of a 1% structural demand shock. 3 Results Data on real GDP and the Consumer Price Index (CPI) for the period 1981Q1-2016Q2 were obtained from the Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC) 1 The supply curve in this specification corresponds to a Lucas-type supply function (Lucas, 1972), where the AS function depends on its expected value, unanticipated inflation and a random supply shock. On the other hand, the demand curve corresponds to a nominal AD function, which is eual to its expected value plus a random demand disturbance (see Cover et al. (2006) for the derivation). 2 We considered only the case in which supply shocks are affected by demand disturbances so that the demand shock is causally prior to the supply shock since, following Cover et al. (2006), the other alternative specification which consists in assuming that demand shocks can be affected by supply disturbances, so that the supply shock is causally prior to the demand shock is mathematically euivalent to the standard BQ model (up to a scalar). (7)

database. 3 We first tested the order of integration of the logarithms of both series using different unit root tests, finding that real GDP was difference stationary and that the CPI had to differenced twice to become stationary. We then tested for cointegration between the log of real GDP and the log-first difference of the CPI using the Johansen methodology, finding no evidence of cointegration between the variables. 4 The VAR model included the annualised growth rate of real GDP, calculated as g t = 100 [ln (GDP) t ln (GDP) t 4 ]; and the first difference of the annualised inflation rate, calculated as π t = π t π t 1, where π t = 100 [ln (CPI) t ln (CPI) t 4 ]. 5 The Likelihood Ratio test indicated that the optimal lag length for the VAR model was 8; however, the latter presented serial correlation problems at the 5% according to the Lagrange Multiplier tests. Thus, we considered a VAR model with 9 lags, which did not present problems of autocorrelation. Table 1 reports the estimated coefficients obtained from the Modified SVAR model. Since α is less than one (0.21), it is possible to conclude that the AS in the Mexican economy is not very sensitive to changes in the inflation rate; the immediate effect of a 1% supply shock on output (1/(1+α)=0.83) is greater than the respective effect of a 1% demand shock (α/(1+α)=0.17); and γ = 0.14 is statistically non-significant, which suggests that AS shocks are not sensitive to AD shocks. Table 1. Estimated coefficients using the Modified model α 0.210 1/(1+α) 0.827 α/(1+α) 0.173 γ a 0.139 (0.984) b a 11 1.958 (0.122) b a 22 2.841 (0.178) Notes: a Standard errors are shown in parenthesis. 3 To the best of our knowledge, the ECLAC database is the most comprehensive source of uarterly data for Mexico. Both time series start in 1981Q1, so that the estimation sample was selected according to this constraint. Moreover, the GDP series for Mexico extracted from the ECLAC database uses two different base years: 1993 (for the period 1981Q1-1998Q4) and 2008 (for the period 1993Q1-2016Q2). The series were spliced together using 2008 as the base year. We used the CPI (2008=100) in order to consider the most common measure of inflation (Bashar, 2011; 2012). The CPI measures the change in cost on a bundle of households representative basket of goods and services, so that we assume that changes in the latter reflect demand fluctuations more accurately than changes in the GDP deflator which measures changes in the level of prices of all new, domestically produced, final goods and services in the economy. Both the real GDP and the CPI series for the Mexican economy are shown in Figure A.1 in Appendix A. Finally, as a robustness check we also estimated the models using the GDP deflator (2008=100) as the measure of inflation, finding fairly similar results (the latter are available from the author on reuest). 4 The results for the different unit root tests and the Johansen tests for cointegration are available from the author upon reuest. 5 We also considered the log-first difference of real GDP and the log-second difference of the CPI. The results obtained remained ualitatively the same.

From Figure 1 it is possible to observe that the impulse response functions (IRFs) for the structural AS and AD shocks as identified by the BQ decomposition and by the Modified model are fairly similar 6 : 1. The responses of g t to a 1% supply shock and of π t to a 1% demand shock are (on average) 1.71% and 2.16%, respectively. 2. The responses of g t to a 1% demand shock and of π t to a 1% supply shock are (on average) 0.65% and -1.40%, respectively. 3. According to the BQ decomposition, the response of g t to a 1% demand shock is statistically non-significant for all periods and the response of π t to a 1% supply shock is significant only for the impact period. On the other hand, according to the Modified model the response of g t to a 1% demand shock is statistically significant one uarter after the initial shock and the response of π t to a 1% supply shock is significant three uarters after the initial shock. The long-run effects on the aggregate output level and on the inflation rate of the AS and AD shocks are presented in Figure 2. Both the BQ and the Modified models show that a positive supply shock has a permanent effect on output and that a positive demand shock has a permanent effect on the inflation rate. Both methodologies also show that there is a negative response of the inflation rate to a positive supply shock, which is significant over a longer time horizon when the Modified model was employed. As expected, a positive demand shock has no permanent effects on output using the BQ model; and the Modified model shows evidence of a slight, permanent increase in the output level, although the effect is statistically significant only for two uarters after the initial shock. 7 Finally, the variance decomposition analyses are presented in Table 2. The BQ model shows that around 93% (79%) of the short-run variation in output (inflation) and around 95% (76%) of the long-run variation in output (inflation) have been the result of structural supply (demand) shocks. According to the Modified model, the supply (demand) shock accounts for approximately 80% (61%) of the short-run variation in output (inflation) and for approximately 89% (62%) of the long-run variation in output (inflation). 4 Conclusions Previous studies for the USA, G-7, and ASEAN countries have shown that the Blanchard-Quah approach can lead to anomalies in the inflation dynamics and can downplay the role of demand shocks in explaining fluctuations in real economic activity if the potential correlation between supply and demand shocks is ignored. The latter means that it may not be possible to derive independent supply and demand shocks using the Blanchard-Quah methodology since both can be contemporaneously correlated. 6 In Figures 1 and 2 the horizontal axis shows the time horizon (uarters); and we plot the responses up to 40 uarters. Bootstrapped standard errors were generated via 2000 replications. 7 The estimated structural AS and AD shocks derived from both models are presented in Figure B.1 in Appendix B. The correlation between the AS shocks derived from the BQ decomposition and from the Modified model is 0.97; whereas the respective correlation between the AD shocks is 0.89. This also shows that the AS and AD shocks obtained from both specifications were fairly similar.

-1.500 2.500 1.500 1.500 0.500 0.500-0.500-0.500 (a) Response of g t to a 1% supply shock (b) Response of g t to a 1% demand shock 4.000 1.500 3.000 0.500-0.500-1.500 - - -2.500-3.000 (c) Response of π t to a 1% supply shock (d) Response of π t to a 1% demand shock Figure 1. Dynamic responses of g t (output growth rate) and π t (first difference of the inflation rate) to a 1% supply and demand shocks, with bootstrapped 95% confidence intervals (shown by dotted lines). Impulse responses were obtained from the SVAR models based on the Blanchard-Quah decomposition (shown in black) and on the Modified model (shown in blue)

-1 2 15.000 15.000 1 1 5.000 5.000-1 -15.000 (a) Accumulated response of output to a 1% supply shock (b) Accumulated response of output to a 1% demand shock 25.000 3 2 25.000 15.000 2 1 15.000 5.000 1 5.000-1 -15.000-2 -1-25.000-15.000-3 -2 (c) Accumulated response of inflation to a 1% supply shock (d) Accumulated response of inflation to a 1% demand shock Figure 2. Responses of aggregate output level and inflation rate to a 1% supply and demand shocks, with bootstrapped 95% confidence intervals (shown by dotted lines). These figures are the cumulative impulse responses of the figures presented in Figure 1, obtained from the SVAR models based on the Blanchard-Quah decomposition (shown in black) and on the Modified model (shown in blue)

Table 2. Variance decompositions for the Blanchard-Quah and the Modified models Horizon (uarters) Variance in the output growth Variance in the change in the rate due to inflation rate due to Blanchard-Quah model Supply shock Demand shock Supply shock Demand shock (%) (%) (%) (%) 1 92.91 7.09 21.03 78.97 2 95.58 4.42 18.47 81.54 10 95.48 4.52 18.77 81.23 40 94.86 5.14 23.67 76.33 Modified model Supply shock Demand shock Supply shock Demand shock (%) (%) (%) (%) 1 79.65 20.35 39.03 60.97 2 84.84 15.16 35.85 64.15 10 89.02 10.98 34.05 65.96 40 88.78 11.22 38.15 61.85 The present paper has explored if the supply shock identified by the Blanchard-Quah methodology contains a demand driven component in the Mexican economy during the period 1981Q1-2016Q2. We do not find evidence that supply shocks are correlated with demand shocks in Mexico, so that: 1) the inflation rate decreases when there is a positive supply shock if the standard Blanchard-Quah restrictions are employed; 2) supply shocks account for approximately 95% of the long-run variation in output; and 3) demand shocks account for approximately 76% of the long-run variation in inflation. The results show that it is possible derive uncorrelated supply and demand shocks for the Mexican economy using the standard restrictions imposed by the Blanchard-Quah methodology. Given that the structure of the Mexican economy is different from that of industrialized economies and developing Southeast Asian countries, future research should try to implement new models in order to identify the relevant market structures that play a role in explaining the differences between the G-7 and ASEAN countries and Mexico.

References Bashar, O. (2011) On the permanent effects of an aggregate demand shock: Evidence from the G-7 countries Economic Modelling 28, 1374 1382. Bashar, O. (2012) The dynamics of aggregate demand and supply shocks in ASEAN countries Journal of Asian Economics 23, 507 518. Blanchard, O. and Quah, D. (1989) The dynamic effects of aggregate demand and supply disturbances American Economic Review 79, 655-673. Cover, J., Enders, W. and Hueng, J. (2006) Using the aggregate demand-aggregate supply model to identify structural demand-side and supply-side shocks: Results using a bivariate VAR Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 38, 777-790. Estefan-Dávila, M. (2014) Supply and demand shocks in Mexico Gaceta de Economía 20, 59-76. Loría, E. and Ramírez, J. (2011) Inflation, monetary policy and economic growth in Mexico. An inverse causation, 1970-2009 Modern Economy 2, 834-845. Lucas, R. (1972) Expectations and the neutrality of money Journal of Economic Theory 4, 103-124. Méndez-Marcano, R. (2014) Technology, employment, and the oil-countries business cycle BBVA research working paper number 14/05. Pagliacci, C. (2016) Are we ignoring supply shocks? fluctuations CEMLA research paper number 21. A proposal for monitoring cyclical

Figure A.1. Mexico: Natural log of real GDP and of CPI; uarterly, 1981Q1-2016Q2 (base year: 2008). Shaded areas indicate OECD based recession indicators from the period following the peak through the trough (extracted from the FRED database, series: MEXRECD). (a) Natural log of real GDP (b) Natural log of CPI 1981Q1 1981Q4 1982Q3 1983Q2 1984Q1 1984Q4 1985Q3 1986Q2 1987Q1 1987Q4 1988Q3 1989Q2 1990Q1 1990Q4 1991Q3 1992Q2 1993Q1 1993Q4 1994Q3 1995Q2 1996Q1 1996Q4 1997Q3 1998Q2 1999Q1 1999Q4 2000Q3 2001Q2 2002Q1 2002Q4 2003Q3 2004Q2 2005Q1 2005Q4 2006Q3 2007Q2 2008Q1 2008Q4 2009Q3 2010Q2 2011Q1 2011Q4 2012Q3 2013Q2 2014Q1 2014Q4 2015Q3 2016Q2-3.00 15.20-2.00 15.40-1.00 1981Q1 1981Q4 1982Q3 1983Q2 1984Q1 1984Q4 1985Q3 1986Q2 1987Q1 1987Q4 1988Q3 1989Q2 1990Q1 1990Q4 1991Q3 1992Q2 1993Q1 1993Q4 1994Q3 1995Q2 1996Q1 1996Q4 1997Q3 1998Q2 1999Q1 1999Q4 2000Q3 2001Q2 2002Q1 2002Q4 2003Q3 2004Q2 2005Q1 2005Q4 2006Q3 2007Q2 2008Q1 2008Q4 2009Q3 2010Q2 2011Q1 2011Q4 2012Q3 2013Q2 2014Q1 2014Q4 15.60 0.00 1.00 15.80 2.00 16.00 3.00 16.20 4.00 16.40 5.00 16.60 6.00 A Data 2015Q3 2016Q2

Figure B.1. Structural shocks obtained from the SVAR models based on the Blanchard-Quah decomposition and on the Modified model; uarterly, 1984Q3-2016Q2. Shaded areas indicate OECD based recession indicators from the period following the peak through the trough (extracted from the FRED database, series: MEXRECD). (c) Aggregate supply shock derived from the Modified model (d) Aggregate demand shock derived from the Modified model -1-4.000-8.000-3.000-6.000 - -4.000-1984Q3 1985Q2 1986Q1 1986Q4 1987Q3 1988Q2 1989Q1 1989Q4 1990Q3 1991Q2 1992Q1 1992Q4 1993Q3 1994Q2 1995Q1 1995Q4 1996Q3 1997Q2 1998Q1 1998Q4 1999Q3 2000Q2 2001Q1 2001Q4 2002Q3 2003Q2 2004Q1 2004Q4 2005Q3 2006Q2 2007Q1 2007Q4 2008Q3 2009Q2 2010Q1 2010Q4 2011Q3 2012Q2 2013Q1 2013Q4 2014Q3 2015Q2 2016Q1 1984Q3 1985Q2 1986Q1 1986Q4 1987Q3 1988Q2 1989Q1 1989Q4 1990Q3 1991Q2 1992Q1 1992Q4 1993Q3 1994Q2 1995Q1 1995Q4 1996Q3 1997Q2 1998Q1 1998Q4 1999Q3 2000Q2 2001Q1 2001Q4 2002Q3 2003Q2 2004Q1 2004Q4 2005Q3 2006Q2 2007Q1 2007Q4 2008Q3 2009Q2 2010Q1 2010Q4 2011Q3 2012Q2 2013Q1 2013Q4 2014Q3 2015Q2 2016Q1 4.000 3.000 6.000 4.000 (a) Aggregate supply shock derived from the Blanchard-Quah decomposition (b) Aggregate demand shock derived from the Blanchard-Quah decomposition -6.000-4.000-4.000-3.000-3.000 - - 1984Q3 1985Q2 1986Q1 1986Q4 1987Q3 1988Q2 1989Q1 1989Q4 1990Q3 1991Q2 1992Q1 1992Q4 1993Q3 1994Q2 1995Q1 1995Q4 1996Q3 1997Q2 1998Q1 1998Q4 1999Q3 2000Q2 2001Q1 2001Q4 2002Q3 2003Q2 2004Q1 2004Q4 2005Q3 2006Q2 2007Q1 2007Q4 2008Q3 2009Q2 2010Q1 2010Q4 2011Q3 2012Q2 2013Q1 2013Q4 2014Q3 2015Q2 2016Q1 1984Q3 1985Q2 1986Q1 1986Q4 1987Q3 1988Q2 1989Q1 1989Q4 1990Q3 1991Q2 1992Q1 1992Q4 1993Q3 1994Q2 1995Q1 1995Q4 1996Q3 1997Q2 1998Q1 1998Q4 1999Q3 2000Q2 2001Q1 2001Q4 2002Q3 2003Q2 2004Q1 2004Q4 2005Q3 2006Q2 2007Q1 2007Q4 2008Q3 2009Q2 2010Q1 2010Q4 2011Q3 2012Q2 2013Q1 2013Q4 2014Q3 2015Q2 2016Q1 3.000 3.000 4.000 4.000 B Estimated structural shocks