Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains

Similar documents
VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract

A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition. Markus Reisinger & Monika Schnitzer University of Munich University of Munich

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Noncooperative Market Games in Normal Form

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

Sheffield Economic Research Paper Series. SERP Number:

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

2014/2015, week 6 The Ramsey model. Romer, Chapter 2.1 to 2.6

Noncooperative Oligopoly

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach

STRATEGIC VERTICAL CONTRACTING WITH ENDOGENOUS NUMBER OF DOWNSTREAM DIVISIONS

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

Environmental Tax Burden in a Vertical Relationship with Pollution-Abatement R&D

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Land competition and monopsonistic monopoly: the role of the narco-insurgency in the colombian cocaine market

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

Answers to Problem Set 4

Lecture Note 3. Oligopoly

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets

Indirect Taxation of Monopolists: A Tax on Price

Bias in Reduced-Form Estimates of Pass-through

Exercise 1. Jan Abrell Centre for Energy Policy and Economics (CEPE) D-MTEC, ETH Zurich. Exercise

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Competition and risk taking in a differentiated banking sector

MKTG 555: Marketing Models

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

Comparative statics of monopoly pricing

Switching Costs and Equilibrium Prices

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. International Trade, Crowding Out, and Market Structure: Cournot Approach. James P.

What Industry Should We Privatize?: Mixed Oligopoly and Externality

FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION

Final Term Papers. Fall 2009 ECO401. (Group is not responsible for any solved content) Subscribe to VU SMS Alert Service

Discrete models in microeconomics and difference equations

Social Optimality in the Two-Party Case

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

1 Maximizing profits when marginal costs are increasing

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions

The Farrell and Shapiro condition revisited

Advertisement Competition in a Differentiated Mixed Duopoly: Bertrand vs. Cournot

Public Schemes for Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets

ECON 4415: International Economics. Autumn Karen Helene Ulltveit-Moe. Lecture 8: TRADE AND OLIGOPOLY

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

Optimal Strategies for Preferential Trade Agreement considering Rules of Origin against Global Outsourcing

Emissions Trading in Forward and Spot Markets of Electricity

What affects bank market power in the euro area?

Price Theory of Two-Sided Markets

Chapter 1: Monopoly II

Export subsidies, countervailing duties, and welfare

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key

Lecture: Mergers. Some facts about mergers from Andrade, Mitchell, and Stafford (2001) Often occur in waves, concentrated by industry

Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location. This Version: 9 May 2006 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE DO NOT CITE

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

PRISONER S DILEMMA. Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

ECO401 Quiz # 5 February 15, 2010 Total questions: 15

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index

Lecture 6 Dynamic games with imperfect information

Labor Economics: The Economics of Imperfect Labor Markets

SHORTER PAPERS. Tariffs versus Quotas under Market Price Uncertainty. Hung-Yi Chen and Hong Hwang. 1 Introduction

The Timing of Endogenous Wage Setting under Bertrand Competition in a Unionized Mixed Duopoly

Exact microeconomic foundation for the Phillips curve under complete markets: A Keynesian view

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Price discrimination in asymmetric Cournot oligopoly

Part 2: Monopoly and Oligopoly Investment

Monopolistic competition models

Dual Currency Circulation and Monetary Policy

Quota bonuses in a principle-agent setting

Solutions to Homework 3

Eco AS , J. Sandford, spring 2019 March 9, Midterm answers

Profit Share and Partner Choice in International Joint Ventures

G.C.E. (A.L.) Support Seminar- 2016

Optimal Strategies for Preferential Trade Agreement considering Rules of Origin against Global Outsourcing

Welfare in a Unionized Bertrand Duopoly. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay* and Sudeshna C. Bandyopadhyay

The Effects of Specific Commodity Taxes on Output and Location of Free Entry Oligopoly

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

Strategic Trade Policy under Isoelastic Demand and Asymmetric Production Costs

CEMARE Research Paper 166. Market power and compliance with output quotas. A Hatcher CEMARE

Transcription:

Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains Maria-Augusta Miceli University of Rome Sapienza Claudia Nardone University of Rome Sapienza October 8, 06 Abstract We here want to analyze how the imperfect competition mark-up and pass-through are transmitted through the production chain and how they change, as a function of the number of firms existing at each production stage. In order to have an analytical closed form solution, we use the standard linear oligopoly framework. Without loss of generality and as first approximation, we assume an homogeneous good and constant returns to scale. The exercise, by using the well known standard results of Nash equilibrium with n firms and the monopoly double marginalization, obtains the mark-up solution parametric in the number of firms in S production stages. Results are mainly the followings, where the firsttwoarejustaconfirmation of the two-stage results, the third is original: (i) Mark-up vanishes in the increasing number of firms, at any production stage. (ii) Pass-through increases in the number of firms, existing at each production stage, because competition tranfers cost increases. (iii) Results are indifferent to the stage at which the larger number of firms happen. In other words, results do not discount the position in the sequence. Classical comparisons between integrated and decentralized chain have been computed with computed consequences on welfare results. PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE. DO NOT QUOTE. KEYWORDS: pass-through, pass-on, mark-up, vertical control, production chain, bottleneck, Cournot Nash equilibrium, cartels, demand elasticity. JEL: C63, D, D40, D4, D43, D6, D85, E7, H, L, L, L3, L4, L4, L43, L50, L5. We do thank Paolo Buccirossi for the question. Department of Economics and Law, University of Rome "Sapienza" - 9 via del Castro Laurenziano - 006 Roma - Italy. Correspondance: augusta.miceli@uniroma.it.

Motivation We here want to analyze how the imperfect competition mark-up is transmitted through the production chain and how it changes, as a function of the number of firms existing at each production stage. In order to have an analytical closed form solution, we use the standard linear oligopoly framework. Without loss of generality and as first approximation, we assume an homogeneous good and constant returns to scale. The exercise, by using the well known standard results of Nash-Cournot equilibrium with n firms, and the monopoly double marginalization, obtains the mark-up solution parametric in the number of firms in the (two) production stages. In order to facilitate and to promote effective private enforcement of the EU antitrust rules, the European Commission has approved the Directive on Antitrust Damages Action (04/04). Victims of the infringements to the EU Antitrust rules are entitled to the full compensation right. The Damages Directive specifically established that compensation for harm could be claimed by anyone who suffered it, irrespective of whether they are direct or indirect purchasers on an infringement. In fact, antitrust law infringements causing an overcharge can harm not only the direct purchasers of the affected good: an injured part may indeed reduce its actual loss by passing the overcharge on, entirely or in part, to its own purchasers at the next level of the supply chain. In this case, the total overcharge harm is spread among the direct purchaser and a number of indirect purchasers of the cartel, at different levels in the supply chain, including final consumers. Furthermore, in line with the compensatory principle, the Directive specifically grants to the defendant the right to invoke a "passing-on defence" against a claim concerning compensation for overcharge harm. This defence is based on the argument that the claimant has been able to pass (fully or partially) the overcharge on to his own customers, so the defendant can be able to reduce the amount due to the claimant: compensation for that amount is due to indirect customers, who in the end suffered from the price increase. Here, in order to analyze how the cartel overcharge is transmitted through the production chain, we need to establish the elements creating it, parameterize them and describing the pass-on difference between a contestable oligopolistic market and a cartel. The definition of the pass-through rate depends, at each stage of the production chain, on: the market structure, namely the distribution of firm market shares; the length of the chain; the cost structure and the economies of scales; the demand elasticities, the relative market power of the counterparts at each chain exchange. All these parameters may of course change over time, depending on the duration of cartels, as soon as we consider product differentiation and whether the cartel includes or excludes differentiation. The aim of this work is to present a first linear model, leading to simple analytic solutions, where parameters can be easily changed to understand the computational magnitudes of the setting changes. In the analytic solution section we establish the simplest oligopoly production chain benchmark with a parametric number of production stages, a parametric number of firms at each stage, linear demand functions and linear variable cost functions to be added to fixed costs.in this setting we are able to get closed form results depending on parameters.

Notation and Assumptions We consider a production chain with a number production stages, where at each stage there is a number :of firms. Number of production stages Number of firms at each stage: where the downstream stage is Each firm in the network is indexed by { } where is the position of the firm in that stage. Linear consumer aggregated demand [ ( )] ( + + + ) Linear intermediate aggregated demand [ ( )] ( + + + ) Cost functions: ( ) + where we initially assume unit constant costs and fixed costs 0 Each downstream firm will buy the single input from one of the upstream firms and has no other fixed costs. Production function: at each stage unit of the intermediate product will produce unit of subsequent product, therefore quantities are determined only at the final stage, when the final firms meet consumer demands. 3 Model I 3. Assumptions We want to analyze how both, the imperfect competition mark-up and cost increases are transmitted through the production chain and how they change as a function of the number of firms existing at each production stage. In order to have an analytical closed form solution, we use the standard linear oligopoly framework. Without loss of generality and as first approximation, we assume an homogeneous good and constant returns to scale. Many details can complicate the matter, so we start from the most parsimonious solution by assuming:. Goods at each stage of production are homogeneous, so that every firm can buy from any firm at the previous stage.. Price at each stage depends on the Nash equilibrium played at that stage. Since quantities are determined downstream, the only optimization is the price at that stage. 3. Equilibrium solution is by backward induction, as in standard vertical control theory. The exercise, by using the well known standard results of Nash equilibria with n firms at each stage, obtains the mark-up solution parametric in the number of firms and in the number production stages. By changing the number of firms at each stage, we automatically control for the market regime at each bargaining stage. In vertical chain control we have two elements to be considered in pricing: the mark-up added at each step, the possibility to pass" downstream the cost increase, which is proportional to the derivative of the mark-up with respect to cost variations. 3

3. Definition of Mark-Up In the following we like to precise what do we define as "mark-up" and "pass-through" in the general monopoly setting and in the linear model of it. Given the most classic form of monopolistic profits () () () and the first order condition for a monopolistic firm: Ã! () : () 0 () 0 the difference between the monopolistic price and the marginal cost is where Definition Mark-up or where () 0 () () : () () 0 () : µ ³ () () 0 () 3.3 Definition of Mark-Up and Pass-Through Now, we want to know how much of the price increase is due to changes in the costs: while costs may increase because of two reasons:. quantity increase; 0 (). marginal cost function shift, due to parameters change in the above cost function. 4

3.3. Price changes due to quantity increase. Let s measure the change in price due to the quantity increase. Given () µ 0 () 0 ³ 0 ()+ + 0 ()+ + ³ + 00 () ³ 00 () + + 0 ()+ + 00 () () The price variation due to the quantity increase is due to two effects: (i) a decreasing price effect due to the downward sloping demand curve, (ii) a price variation due to the behaviour of the cost function: increasing, constant, decreasing. 3.3. Example with linear demand and parametric cost functions Let () () () where the inverse demand function is () and the cost function is parametric in returns to scale () + We have () [ ] Retrieving the direct demand function () () The mark-up is represented by ( ) () : 0 () 0 () ( ) ( ) () Ã +! 0 0 ()+ 5 ³ + 00 ()

Using the explicit functions Ã! 0! () ()+Ã 0 00 () ( ) 0 ()+ () () ( ) ( ) + ( ) ( ) (3) Now: I. if () + i.e. : () ( ) 0 because there is only the downward sloping demand effect. The marginal cost is constant. II. if () + i.e. : Ex. () () ( ) + ( )+(+) 0 ( ) ( ) + ( ) ( ) + ( ) dp/dq 0 0 0 0 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 00 q -0-0 -30 The example shows that an initial positive sign due to the sum of positive marginal costs, then a dominating role of downward sloping demand and marginal costs not too increasing, but after a quantity threshold, the increasing is soon dominated by decreasing demand curve. III. if () + i.e. : () ( ) ( ) + ( ) ( ) ( ) + ( ) ( )+( ) 0 6

decreasing, where the first term is due to decreasing demand curve and the second term due to decreasing costs, oscillating in the dominance of the different parameters. Ex. 05 : () ( ) 05 (05 ) + 05(05 ) (05 ) ( ) 05 5(05 ) + 05(05 ) 5(05 ) dp/dq 0 0-0 0 0 30 q -0-30 3.3.3 Pass-through due to cost function variations Following the standard maximizing procedure, the monopoly price is a mark-up over the marginal cost () ³ 0 () + () We define Definition The "Pass-through" represents how much the final price changes following a marginal cost change (Note. Not the quantity change, discussed above). We look for ³ while the term + 0 () 0 () ³ 00 () T 0 + is constant, because the quantity is constant. Using the explicit parametric functions, we have that 0 () ³ ( ) ( ) + (4) Defining 0 () as (), the pass-on 0 () is non decreasing, constant or not decreasing in as T The paper explores the results for the only "constant marginal cost" assumption. 7

4 Integrated Production Chain Cournot Equilibrium with firms Let s recall the Cournot Equilibrium results for symmetric firms and one integrated production chain. We define the profit function of the integrated firm, as max () ( ( ) ) ( ) () : ( ) 0 (5) ( ) To avoid to solve a system of first order conditions, using the symmetric output assumption, we use the fact that and write ( +) 0 so that () ( +) In computing the () we want to explicit the marginal cost alone (6) ( ()) ( ) ( +) + + + + + Inserting solutions in the profit function + + ( ()) + () [() ] ( ) ( +) ( +) + + + + ( ) + µ ( ) + + ( +) (7) ( ) () ( +) (8) By considering the limit for we obtain the perfect competition solution, where the optimal quantity produced by a single firm is infinitesimal in comparison with the total industry lim () 0 the optimal price tend to the marginal cost lim ( ()) and profits tend to zero and unable to support fixed costs. lim () 0 8

5 Vertical Control: upstream firm, downstream firm Let s recall now the other classical result: the double marginalization. The first step is to consider firm at each production stage, so and double monopoly. The integrated firm results that produces within itself both productions stages are the ones above, (6) (7) and (8) just using 5. Decentralized solution: 5.. Downstream solution The downstream results are again the (6) (7) and (8) where the cost is not but the still unknown intermediate price Equilibrium quantities have subscript () (9) ( ()) + (0) 5.. Upstream solution () ( ) () News are that in the production chain, the upstream firm cannot independently decide the output quantity, because both quantity and final price are determined at downstream level, as a function of the gross (intermediate) price The industry profit, determined by downstream quantity and price as a function of the upstream cost, here marginal cost is shared by the upstream and downstream firms as a function of the market regime in the two segments. The more competitive a market segment is, the more the price tends to the cost. We start here by assuming double monopoly. In the next paragraph we will enlarge the result to any number of firms upstream () and downstream () The upstream firm maximizes his monopoly profits to increase his profit share in the full production chain, by searching the optimal intermediate price while bearing linear costs in the quantity max () : ( ) () µ ( ) + () : + 0 + µ ( ) µ Ã! + + () ( ) 8 9 (3)

Reinserting the solution, we can determine and therefore + + + + 4 3 + 4 + ( ) ( ) (6) Remark 3 Final quantity in a double monopoly production chain and linear function is reduced by half, implying a higher price and halved profits. 5. Welfare results: (4) (5) Integrated Solution: Decentralized Solution: ( ) 4 + ( ) 8 + ( ) 6 ( + ) 3 6 ( ) ( + ) where profits sum is smaller than in the integrated solution, and so is for the Producer Surplus : 3 6 ( ) 4 6 ( ) The ratio is assuming ( + ) 3( ) 6 ( ) 4 3 4 Remark 4 In the double marginalization, when there is monopoly in both production segments, Total ProducerSurplusisreducedby/4. Consumer Surplus: µ + 4 µ Decentralized Solution: µ 3 + µ 4 4 4 Remark 5 In the double marginalization, when there is monopoly in both production segments, Consumer Surplus is halved. 6 Vertical Control: upstream firm, downstream firm 6. Integrated Solution ( 0) The integrated firm producing within itself both productions stages obtains the following equilibrium results, parametric in the number of firms, are the ones above, (6) (7) and (8). 0 4

6. Decentralized solution ( ) 6.. Downstream with firms The downstream results are again the (6) (7) and (8) where the cost is not but the still unknown intermediate price Equilibrium results have subscript (; ) ( +) (; ) + ( +) (7) (8) 6.. Upstream with firms (; ) ( ) ( +) (9) There are firms on the upstream market and firms on the downstream market. results have subscript Equilibrium max () : ( ) () µ ( ) ( +) + The Nash equilibrium on the upstream market shared by firms, directly following from (7) determines a gross/intermediate price of ( ) + + + ( ) + and lim ( ) Definition 6 The "mark-up" on the upstream output price is ( ) + and it s inversely proportional to the number of firms and it disappears, when the segment tends to perfect competition ( ) By inserting it in the downstream Nash equilibrium quantity with firms ( ) ( +) + + ( +) + µ + Remark 7 ( ) + ( ) Downstream quantity decreases in the number of the downstream firms and it is almost insensitive to the number of the upstream firms when "many" (when ' +) (0) ()

( ) µ ( ) ( +)( +) ( + + + ) ( +)( +) ( + +) + + + ++ ( ) + where the second term is the "pass-through". Result 8 The "mark-up" on the downstream output price ( + +) + ++ ( + +) + ++ ( + +) ( ) () ( +)( +) ( + +) ( ) ( +)( +) depends on the relative number of the upstream and downstream firms and it survives, unless both segments have the number of firms increasing to infinity,i.e. and Result 9 The downstream "pass-on" is larger, the larger and/or. lim ( ) ' +( ) The mark-up in each segment is higher the smaller the number of firms in the segment, and therefore the effect on the retail price is higher the smaller the number of firms, i.e. the market power, at each segment. On the contrary, the possibility to pass-through the cost increase is higher the larger the number of firms. We are generalizing the well known result that cost increases, under competitive regimes, are completely transferred downstream. Using the results (0) () and () we compute equilibrium downstream profits ( ) ( ( ) ()) ( ) µ ( + +) ( ) + ( ) + ++ + µ µ + + µ ( ) ( +)( +) Remark 0 ( ) µ ( ) + Downstream profits grow in the number of upstream firms because this means a lower input price. Upstream profits ( ) ( ) ( ) µ ( ) + + + µ + µ ( ) ( +)( +)

Remark ( ) + () When upstream profits are smaller than normal oligopoly profits. In the benchmark case of ( ) () () Fig.. P(m,n) In fig.. prices as functions of and areshown.aswesawintheformulatheiso-contoursare hyperbolas, meaning that the price is due to the products no matter the position of the number in the sequence. 3

7 Welfare Results ( ) 7. Producer Surplus ( ) 7.. Integrated Solution so ( ) () ( +) Ã! ( ) ( ) ( +) 7.. Decentralized Solution à + + µ! à µ + + + µ! + ( ) ( +) ( +) ( +) Neglecting fixed costs ( ) ( ) ( +) ( +) ( +) ( +) The ratio is Assuming as before. (+) (+) (+) (+) ( ) ( ) + +( +) +(+) + 3 4 +(+) + Remark In the double marginalization, when there is monopoly in both production segments, total producer surplus is reduced by /4. 7..3 Consumer Surplus ( ) Integrated Solution Decentralized Solution µ ( ) + ( ( )) µ µ ( + +) + ( +)( +) ( +) ( ) ( +) ( ) ( +) ( +) ( ) Remark 3 In the decentralized solution, consumer surplus is decreased by the ratio ( +)with respect to the integrated solution and this ratio is maximized for i.e. having one single monopoly in the upstream segment. 4

8 Generalized solution to S segments Generalizing to stages of production ³ P + Q ( ( ) +) where Number of segments: Number of firms for each segment: highest willingness to pay, constant unit cost marginal cost, : Q Q ( +) Given the different numbers,for, the "markup" size decreases much faster than the pass-on coefficient, because it has a sum and not a product in the numerator. As expected, in perfect competition, the pass-through rate is 00%. 9 Vertical Control: The General Case - n per segment Number of production stages Number of firms at each stage: where the downstream stage is Each firm in the network is indexed by { } where is the position of the firm in that stage 9. Backward Solution 9.. Stage with firms ( ) ( ) ( +) ( ) ( +) + + + ( + )+ + + + + ( ) µ + ( + ) ( +) ( ) ( +) 5

9.. Stage From which ( ) + + ³ ( ) ( ) + ( +) + ( +) ( ) ( +) ( +) ( ) ( ) ( +) ( +) ( +)( +) ( + + + ) (( + +) + ) + ++ ( +)( +) ( +)( +) + ( + +) ( +)( +) ( ) ( + +) + ( ) + ++ Remark 4 The price is a weighted average of the highest willigness to pay and the initial unit cost. The third line shows that the component is more important the smaller I.e. the mark-upislesspowerfulthelargerthenumberoffirms in the production chain, confirming the "doublemonopoly" problem. ( ) µ ( + +) + ( ) + + ++ + µ ( ) + ( +) 9..3 Stage S- ( ) ( ) µ + ( ) + ( +) ( +) ( ) +( +) ( ) ( +) ( +) Cournot Price max ( 3 ) ( ) ( 3 ) ( +) ( +) ( 3 ) + 3 ( +) 6

( 3 ) ( ) ( +)( +) ( 3 ) ( +)( +)( +) ³ + 3 ( +) ( +)( +) ( 3 ) ( 3 ) ( +)( +)( +) ( +)( +)( +) ( 3 + + + + + + + ) ( + + + + + +) + 3 ( +)( +)( +) 3 + ( + + + + + +) ( 3 ) ( +)( +)( +) ( 3 ) ( 3 ) ( 3 ) µ + 3 ( 3 ) 3 ( +) ( +)( +)( +) ( + + + + + +) ( +) ( +) ( +) ( 3 ) 9. Sequence 9.. Quantities ( +)( +) ( 3 ) ( +) ( ) ( ) ( +) ( ) ( ) ( +) ( +) ( ) ( +) ( +) ( +) ( ) ( 3 ) ( 3 ) ( +)( +) ( +) ( +)( +) ( 3) ( +) ( +)( +) ( 3 ) 9.. Prices Q ( +) ( ) ( +) Q ( +) + ( ) ( ) + + + + + + + + ( +)( +) ( + + + ) 7

( ) + + ( 3 ) + 3 ( +) + ( 3 ) + + 3 ( +) + + ( + + + + + + + 3 ) ( +)( +)( +) ( + + + + + + ) + 3 ( +)( +)( +) 7 + 8 ( + 300 + 3 00 00) 0 + 00 3 0 3 ( ) + + + + 3 ( +) + ( + + ) +( ) 3 ( +)( +) 3 + ( + + ) ( +)( +) ( 3) ( 3 ) + 3 ( +) Proposition 5 If all firms are symmetric and the initial cost is the same for them all, the final price is not affected by the "position of the market power" along the production chain. The effect is symmetric. 9..3 Profits ( ) ³ Q 0 ( +) Q 0 Q 0 ( +) + Q 0 ( 3 ) ( ) ( +) 3 + ( +)( +) ( ) Q Q 0 ( +) ( ) ( 3 ) [ ( 3 ) 3 ] ( 3 ) ( 3 ) ( +) ( +) ( +) ( + + + + + +) Ã! Y Y Q ( ) ( +) Q 0 ( +) ( ) 0 (3) 8

0 Conclusions In this paper, in a production chain producing a homogeneous good with homogeneous inputs at each stage of production, we have computed the mark-up and the pass-through component that upstream and downstream firms apply on their costs to determine their output price and generalized it to any number of firms existing at any number of production stages. Results are mainly the following, where the first two are just a confirmation of the two stages results, the third is original:. Mark-up vanishes in the increasing number of firms, at any production stage.. Pass-through increases in the number of firms, existing at each production stage, because competition tranfers cost increases. 3. Results are indifferent to the stage at which the larger number of firms happen. In other words, results do not discount the position in the sequence. Equation (3) is the algorithm able to generate any price sequence in a production chain starting from the initial cost an pricing the evolution of it. It is therefore able to generate the price differential generated by each stage of production, due to the number of existing firms at that stage. The Classical comparisons between integrated and decentralized chain have been computed with computed consequences on welfare results. References [] Bonnet, C., Dubois, P., Villas Boas, S. B., & Klapper, D. (03). Empirical evidence on the role of nonlinear wholesale pricing and vertical restraints on cost pass-through. Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(), 500-55. [] Fabinger, Michal and Weyl, E. Glen, (05) A Tractable Approach to Pass-Through Patterns (March 0), http://dx.doi.org/0.39/ssrn.94855. [3] Taylor, J. B. (000). Low inflation, pass-through, and the pricing power of firms. European economic review, 44(7), 389-408. [4] Van Dijk, T., & Verboven, F. (00). Implementing the passing-on defence in cartel damages actions. Global Competition Litigation Review, 3(3), 98-06. [5] Van Dijk, T., & Verboven, F. (005). Quantification of damages. Draft Version, 4-7. [6] Verboven, F. (009) Cartel Damages Claims and the Passing-On Defense, Journal of Industrial Economics, 57(3), 457-49. [7] Weyl, E. G., & Fabinger, M. (03). Pass-through as an Economic Tool: Principles of Incidence under Imperfect Competition. Journal of Political Economy, (3), 58-583. [8] Weyl, E. G., & Tirole, J. (0). Market Power screens Willingness-to-pay. Quarterly Journal of Economics, Forthcoming. 9