Money in a Neoclassical Framework

Similar documents
Money in an RBC framework

Transactions and Money Demand Walsh Chapter 3

Cash-in-Advance Model

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Topic 6. Introducing money

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Lecture 15 Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Lecture 17 Real Business Cycles Money. Noah Williams

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. Fiscal Policy. Ramsey Taxation. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University

Monetary/Fiscal Interactions: Cash in Advance

Monetary Economics. Money in Utility. Seyed Ali Madanizadeh. February Sharif University of Technology

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Slides III - Complete Markets

GOVERNMENT AND FISCAL POLICY IN JUNE 16, 2010 THE CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL (CONTINUED) ADYNAMIC MODEL OF THE GOVERNMENT

Overlapping Generations Model: Dynamic Efficiency and Social Security

The Neoclassical Growth Model

Chapter 10 Money, Interest and Prices

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

Topic 4. Introducing investment (and saving) decisions

14.05 Lecture Notes. Labor Supply

Lecture 12 Ricardian Equivalence Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

Cash in Advance Models

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic. 3. Capital, labor account for small fraction of output drop,

Imperfect Information and Market Segmentation Walsh Chapter 5

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Problem set Fall 2012.

The New Keynesian Model

1 Dynamic programming

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Introducing money. Olivier Blanchard. April Spring Topic 6.

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 15 Problem 3 / 15 Problem 4 / 20 Problem 5 / 25 TOTAL / 100

Lecture 2: The Neoclassical Growth Model

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont)

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

Money Demand. ECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

Discussion: The Optimal Rate of Inflation by Stephanie Schmitt- Grohé and Martin Uribe

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3)

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

Inflation & Welfare 1

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

The Fisher Equation and Output Growth

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

MONETARY AND FINANCIAL MACRO BUDGET CONSTRAINTS

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Final Exam Solutions

Public budget accounting and seigniorage. 1. Public budget accounting, inflation and debt. 2. Equilibrium seigniorage

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

Consumption and Asset Pricing

An Entrepreneur s Problem Under Perfect Foresight

Solutions to Problem Set 1

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

Midterm Exam. Monday, March hour, 30 minutes. Name:

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

1 Two Period Production Economy

Econ 3029 Advanced Macro. Lecture 2: The Liquidity Trap

The Real Business Cycle Model

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Optimal Capital Income Taxation

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Money, Output, and the Nominal National Debt. Bruce Champ and Scott Freeman (AER 1990)

Monetary Theory and Policy. Fourth Edition. Carl E. Walsh. The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Fluctuations in the economy s output. 1. Three Components of Investment

Econ 219 Spring Lecture #11

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6

1. Introduction of another instrument of savings, namely, capital

Monetary Economics Basic Flexible Price Models

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Assets with possibly negative dividends

Real Business Cycles (Solution)

6. Deficits and inflation: seignorage as a source of public sector revenue

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics

Macro (8701) & Micro (8703) option

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. A Neo-Classical Benchmark Economy. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University

1 No capital mobility

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 7: Externalities, the Marginal Cost of Public Funds, and Imperfect Competition

Lecture Notes in Macroeconomics. Christian Groth

B r i e f T a b l e o f C o n t e n t s

Macroeconomic Implications of Size-Dependent Policies

1. Borrowing Constraints on Firms The Financial Accelerator

Transcription:

Money in a Neoclassical Framework Noah Williams University of Wisconsin-Madison Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 1 / 21

Money Two basic questions: 1 Modern economies use money. Why? 2 How/why do changes in the amount of money affect nominal and real variables in the economy? Uses/functions of money: (1) Unit of account: contracts are usually denominated in terms of money. (2) Store of value: money allows consumers to trade current goods for future goods. (3) Medium of exchange: facilitates transactions. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 2 / 21

Money in Exchange Non-monetary transactions require barter: one good or service is exchanged directly for another. Requires a double coincidence of wants: each party must want what other has. Other objects, like stocks and bonds, can be store of value and medium of exchange. Can dominate as store of value since they give a positive rate of return. But stocks and bonds are not efficient in exchange: 1 Agents not well-informed about the exact value of stocks. 2 It is not always easy to sell these assets. (Liquidity) Money very efficient in exchange. Facilitates specialization. In absence of regular money, other objects appear as media of exchange (cigarettes in POW camps). Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 3 / 21

Incorporating money To employ the neoclassical framework to analyze monetary issues, a role for money must be specified so that the agents will wish to hold positive quantities of money. Money dominated as an asset. Three general approaches to incorporating money into general equilibrium models have been followed: 1 Assume that money yields direct utility by incorporating money balances directly into the utility functions of the agents of the model (Sidrauski 1967, Brock 1974). 2 Impose transactions costs 1 Make asset exchanges costly (Baumol 1952, Tobin 1956) 2 Require that money be used for certain types of transactions (Clower 1967, Lucas 1982) 3 Assume time and money can be combined to produce transaction services that are necessary for obtaining consumption goods 4 Assume decentralized markets where direct barter or credit not feasible (Kiyotaki and Wright 1989). 3 Treat money like any other asset used to transfer resources intertemporally (Samuelson 1958). Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 4 / 21

A basic MIU model First approach: MIU Real money balances enter directly in the utility function. Given suitable restrictions on the utility function, such an approach can guarantee that, in equilibrium, agents choose to hold positive amounts of money so that money will be positively valued. Representative household takes prices as given and maximizes E t i=0 β i U (C t+i, m t+i, L t+i ) subject to a budget constraint. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 5 / 21

A basic MIU model Budget constraint, in nominal terms: W t (1 L t ) + (r t + 1 δ) P t K t 1 +(1 + i t 1 )B t 1 + M t 1 + P t τ t = P t C t + P t K t + B t + M t where τ are real, lump-sum transfers to the household (can be negative). In real terms: or w t (1 L t ) + (r t + 1 δ) K t 1 +(1 + i t 1 ) B t 1 P t + M t 1 = C P t + τ t + K t + B t + M t t P t P t w t (1 L t ) + (r t + 1 δ) K t 1 +(1 + i t 1 ) P t 1 P t b t 1 + P t 1 = C P t m t 1 + τ t + K t + b t + m t t Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 6 / 21

A basic MIU model First order conditions: U C λ t = 0 U L w t λ t = 0 U L U C = w t λ t + βe t (r t+1 + 1 δ) λ t+1 = 0 ( ) Pt λ t + β(1 + i t )E t λ t+1 = 0 P t+1 ( ) Pt U m λ t + βe t λ t+1 = 0 P t+1 First three look just as before (except U C and U L may depend on m). Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 7 / 21

A basic MIU model The FOC for money can be written Solve forward to yield λ t = U m + βe t P t P t ( ) 1 1 = E t P t λ t i=0 ( λt+1 P t+1 ) [ ] β i Um (C t+i, m t+i, L t+i ) P t+i Value of money equals expected present value of discounted utility return. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 8 / 21

A basic MIU model Combining the first and third conditions yields the Euler condition: U C (C t, m t, L t ) = βe t (r t+1 + 1 δ) U C (C t+1, m t+1, L t+1 ) Similarly, ( ) Pt U C (C t, m t, L t ) = β(1 + i t )E t U C (C t+1, m t+1, L t+1 ) P t+1 From fourth and fifth, But so U m U C U m U C = βi t E t ( Pt P t+1 1 = β(1 + i t )E t ( Pt = βi t E t ( Pt P t+1 P t+1 ) UC (C t+1, m t+1, L t+1 ) U C (C t, m t, L t ) ) UC (C t+1, m t+1, L t+1 ) U C (C t, m t, L t ) ) UC (C t+1, m t+1, L t+1 ) U C (C t, m t, L t ) = i t 1 + i t. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 9 / 21

Monetary Neutrality Firm side of model is same as in basic RBC model. If U L and U C independent of m, real side identical to basic RBC model. (Steady state and dynamics) Neutrality: One time changes in the nominal quantity of money affect only the price level. Superneutrality: Changes in growth rate of money do not affect real variables. Changes in the rate of growth of money affect only the inflation rate, the nominal interest rate, and real money balances. Basic intuition: the private opportunity cost of holding money depends on the nominal rate of interest. The social marginal cost of producing money is essentially zero. Friedman Rule: This inefficiency would be eliminated if the nominal rate of interest were zero. So the optimal rate of inflation is a rate of deflation approximately equal to the real return on capital. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 10 / 21

Cash-in-advance models Clower (1967): goods buy money and money buys goods, but goods don t buy goods. And because goods don t buy goods, a medium of exchange that serves to aid the process of transacting will have value. The demand for money is then determined by the nature of the economy s transactions technology. Rather than allowing substitutability between time and money in carrying out transactions, cash-in-advance (CIA) models simply require that money balances be held to finance certain types of purchases; without money, these purchases cannot be made. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 11 / 21

Household Problem: Timing At the start of the period, the household has three assets: Money M t 1, nominal bonds B t 1, and capital K t 1. Household consists of two members, a worker and a shopper. Worker supplies labor to firm, earns wage. Shopper takes M t 1 to store and purchases consumption goods At the end of the period household members pool resources, rebalance portfolio of assets. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 12 / 21

Cash-in-advance models The representative agent Maximizes present discounted value of expected utility subject to a sequence of new constraints. If the goods markets open first and the agent enters the period with money holdings M t 1 and receives a lump-sum transfer T t (in nominal terms), the CIA constraint takes the form P t c t M t 1 + T t, where c is real consumption, P is the aggregate price level, and T is the nominal lump-sum transfer. In real terms, c t M t 1 + T t = m t 1 + τ t, P t P t Π t where m t 1 = M t 1 /P t 1, Π t = P t /P t 1 is 1 plus the inflation rate, and τ t = T t /P t. Income from production during period t will not be available for consumption purchases during period t. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 13 / 21

Cash-in-advance models Budget constraint in real terms, ω t c t + m t + b t + k t where ω t f (k t 1 ) + (1 δ)k t 1 + τ t + m t 1 + (1 + i t 1 )b t 1 Π t, and m and b are real cash and bond holdings. Let a t = b t + m t. Then budget constraint implies ω t+1 = f (k t ) + (1 δ)k t + τ t+1 + R t a t ( it Π t+1 ) m t. This form highlights that there is a cost to holding money when the nominal interest rate is positive. This cost is (1 + i t )/Π t+1. This is the same expression for the opportunity cost of money in an MIU model. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 14 / 21

Cash-in-advance models The decision problem Define the value function V (ω t, m t 1 ) = max{u(c t ) + βv (ω t+1, m t )}, where the maximization is subject to the budget constraint ω t c t + m t + b t + k t, the CIA constraint, and the definition of ω t+1. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 15 / 21

Cash-in-advance models The decision problem Letting λ t (µ t ) denote the Lagrange multiplier associated with the budget constraint (the CIA constraint), the first order conditions for the agent s choice of consumption, capital, bond, and money holdings take the form [ β R t u c (c t ) λ t µ t = 0 β [f k (k t ) + 1 δ] V ω (ω t+1, m t ) λ t = 0 i t Π t+1 βr t V ω (ω t+1, m t ) λ t = 0 ] V ω (ω t+1, m t ) + βv m (ω t+1, m t ) λ t = 0. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 16 / 21

Cash-in-advance models From the envelope theorem, V ω (ω t, m t 1 ) = λ t ( ) 1 V m (ω t, m t 1 ) = µ t. Π t λ t is equal to the marginal utility of wealth. The marginal utility of consumption exceeds the marginal utility of wealth by the value of liquidity services, µ t. The individual must hold money in order to purchase consumption, so the cost, to which the marginal utility of consumption is set equal, is the marginal utility of wealth plus the cost of the liquidity services needed to finance the transaction. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 17 / 21

Cash-in-advance models The first order conditions imply ( ) λt+1 + µ λ t = β t+1 1 ( 1 = P t Π t+1 λ t ) β ( λt+1 + µ t+1 P t+1 This equation can also be interpreted as an asset pricing equation for money. The price of a unit of money in terms of goods is just 1/P t at time t; its value in utility terms is λ t /P t. Solving this equation forward implies that ( ) 1 1 ( ) = β i µt+i. P t λ t i=1 P t+i Value of money related to present discounted value of Lagrangian multipliers on CIA constraint. ). Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 18 / 21

Cash-in-advance models The nominal rate of interest Since λ t = βr t λ t+1 = β ( ) λ t+1 + µ t+1 /Πt+1, or R t Π t+1 λ t+1 = ( ) λ t+1 + µ t+1 and 1 + it = R t Π t+1, the nominal interest rate is given by ( ) λt+1 + µ i t = t+1 1 = µ t+1. λ t+1 λ t+1 The nominal rate of interest is positive if and only if money yields liquidity services (µ t+1 > 0). In particular, if the nominal interest rate is positive, the CIA constraint is binding (µ > 0). Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 19 / 21

Cash-in-advance models Marginal utility of consumption We can use the relationship between the nominal rate of interest and the Lagrangian multipliers to rewrite the expression for the marginal utility of consumption as u c = λ(1 + µ/λ) = λ(1 + i) λ. Since λ represents the marginal value of income, the marginal utility of consumption exceeds that of income whenever the nominal interest rate is positive. Even though the economy s technology allows output to be directly transformed into consumption, the price of consumption is not equal to 1; it is 1 + i since the household must hold money to finance consumption. Thus, in this CIA model, a positive nominal interest rate acts as a tax on consumption; it raises the price of consumption above its production cost. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 20 / 21

Welfare costs of inflation In CIA models, inflation acts as a tax on goods or activities whose purchase requires cash. This tax then introduces a distortion by creating a wedge between the marginal rates of transformation implied by the economy s technology and the marginal rates of substitution faced by consumers. Since the CIA model, like the MIU model, offers no reason for such a distortion to be introduced (there is no inefficiency that calls for Pigovian taxes or subsidies on particular activities, and the government s revenue needs can be met through lump-sum taxation), optimality calls for setting the inflation tax equal to zero. The inflation tax is directly related to the nominal rate of interest; a zero inflation tax is achieved when the nominal rate of interest is equal to zero. Noah Williams (UW Madison) Macroeconomic Theory 21 / 21