July 17, Summary

Similar documents
Revised January 6, 2006

Revised November 21, 2008

Revised December 7, 2006

WOULD RAISING IRA CONTRIBUTION LIMITS BOLSTER RETIREMENT SECURITY FOR LOWER AND MIDDLE-INCOME FAMILIES? by Peter Orszag and Jonathan Orszag 1

WHAT WOULD IT SAY ABOUT CONGRESS S PRIORITIES TO WAIVE PAYGO FOR THE AMT PATCH? By Aviva Aron-Dine

Universal Savings Account Proposal in New Republican Tax Bill Is Ill-Conceived

The Legacy of the 2001 and 2003 Bush Tax Cuts

July 31, First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

And Jobs Act, November 14, 2017, %20chairman's%20modified%20mark.pdf.

Revised April 13, 2006

WHAT THE NEW TRUSTEES REPORT SHOWS ABOUT SOCIAL SECURITY By Jason Furman and Robert Greenstein

Senator Kerry s Tax Proposals. Leonard E. Burman and Jeffrey Rohaly 1 Revised July 23, 2004

I S S U E B R I E F PUBLIC POLICY INSTITUTE PPI PRESIDENT BUSH S TAX PLAN: IMPACTS ON AGE AND INCOME GROUPS

ECONOMIC EVIDENCE FOR EXTENDING CAPITAL GAINS AND DIVIDEND TAX CUTS IS WEAK By Joel Friedman and Aviva Aron-Dine

OVERALL FEDERAL TAX BURDEN ON MOST FAMILIES AT LOWEST LEVELS SINCE AT LEAST Income Taxes for Median Family of Four at Lowest Level Since 1957

WHAT THE 2007 TRUSTEES REPORT SHOWS ABOUT SOCIAL SECURITY By Chad Stone and Robert Greenstein

SMALLER DEFICIT ESTIMATE NO SURPRISE New OMB Estimates Do Not Support Claims About Tax Cuts By James Horney

These three points are elaborated below. 820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

NEW TAX CUTS PRIMARILY BENEFITING MILLIONAIRES SLATED TO TAKE EFFECT IN JANUARY

NEW ESTATE TAX RULES SHOULD EXPIRE AFTER 2012 Shrinking the Tax Beyond the 2009 Level Is Unaffordable and Unnecessary By Gillian Brunet

SHOULD THE BUDGET RULES BE CHANGED SO THAT LARGE-SCALE BORROWING TO FUND INDIVIDUAL ACCOUNTS IS LEFT OUT OF THE BUDGET? 1

The Distribution of Federal Taxes, Jeffrey Rohaly

Extension of Saving and Investment Incentives

TAX EXPENDITURES FOR RETIREMENT PLANS

Income Taxes and Tax Rates for Sample Families, 2006 Greg Leiserson. December 2006

TAX CUTS PROPOSED IN PRESIDENT S BUDGET WOULD ULTIMATELY CAUSE LARGE STATE REVENUE LOSSES By Iris J. Lav

MORE THAN HALF OF BLACK AND HISPANIC FAMILIES WOULD NOT BENEFIT FROM BUSH TAX PLAN. by Isaac Shapiro, Allen Dupree and James Sly

Summary Preparing for financial security in retirement continues to be a concern of working Americans and policymakers. Although most Americans partic

Senate Tax Bill Has Same Basic Flaws as House Bill

Five Easy Pieces Scorecard

PROPOSED SENATE TAX CUTS FOR SMALL BUSINESSES AND FARMERS NOT A TOP PRIORITY, GIVEN BUDGET OUTLOOK AND OTHER PRESSURES.

THE ESTATE TAX: MYTHS AND REALITIES

ARE TAXES TOO CONCENTRATED AT THE TOP? Rapidly Rising Incomes at the Top Lie Behind Increase in Share of Taxes Paid By High-Income Taxpayers

An Analysis of the Tax Treatment of Capital Losses Summary Several reasons have been advanced for increasing the net capital loss limit against ordina

Retirement Tax Incentives Are Ripe for Reform

SENATE FINANCE COMMITTEE PLAN INCLUDES SOUND STIMULUS PROPOSALS. by Joel Friedman, Robert Greenstein, and Richard Kogan

The key differences between the Cooper-LaTourette plan and the Simpson-Bowles commission plan are:

What The New CBO Report Shows Budget And Economic Outlook Has Not Improved by James Horney and Richard Kogan

Tax Reform Options: Promoting Retirement Security. Testimony Submitted to United States Senate Committee on Finance. September 15, 2011

Vast Majority of Americans Would Likely Lose From Senate GOP s $1.5 Trillion in Tax Cuts, Once They re Paid For

There are several types of tax-favored retirement

Chart Book: Deficit Reduction, the Economy, And the Budget Negotiations By Sharon Parrott, Richard Kogan, Krista Ruffini, and William Chen

PROPOSAL FOR NEW HSA TAX DEDUCTION FOUND LIKELY TO INCREASE THE RANKS OF THE UNINSURED. by Edwin Park and Robert Greenstein

Taxing Capital Income Once * Leonard E. Burman

CBPP S UPDATED LONG-TERM FISCAL DEFICIT AND DEBT PROJECTIONS

MISCONCEPTIONS AND REALITIES ABOUT WHO PAYS TAXES By Chuck Marr and Chye-Ching Huang

PROGRESSIVITY AND SAVING: FIXING THE NATION S UPSIDE-DOWN INCENTIVES FOR SAVING

POLICY BRIEF. Tax legislation enacted in 2001 increased the value of the Child Tax

Research Report. The Population of Workers Covered by the Auto IRA: Trends and Characteristics. AARP Public Policy Institute.

D A T A D I G E S T PUBLIC POLICY INSTITUTE PPI. Extending Preferences for Dividends and Capital Gains: Who Gains the Most?

CORRECTING FIVE MYTHS ABOUT THE STIMULUS BILL By James R. Horney, Nicholas Johnson, and Lawrence J. Haas

A pril 15. It causes much anxiety, with

HEALTH INSURANCE DEDUCTION OF LITTLE HELP TO THE UNINSURED. by Joel Friedman and Iris J. Lav

Desperately Seeking Revenue

PRINCIPLES FOR ECONOMIC STIMULUS. By Andrew Lee

THE PRESIDENT S BUDGET: A PRELIMINARY ANALYSIS

THE INDIVIDUAL ALTERNATIVE MINIMUM TAX: HISTORICAL DATA

AN UNLIMITED ESTATE TAX EXEMPTION FOR FARMLAND Unnecessary, Open to Abuse, and Likely to Hurt, Rather than Help, Family Farmers By Aviva Aron-Dine

Investing in Children

75-YEAR PAY-AS-YOU-GO PROPOSAL COULD ADVERSELY AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY, MEDICARE, SSI, VETERANS DISABILITY, AND OTHER PROGRAMS

HOUSE LEGISLATION WOULD CAUSE 350,000 PEOPLE TO FORGO HEALTH COVERAGE AND COULD JEOPARDIZE HEALTH REFORM By Judith Solomon and Robert Greenstein

Health Insurance Data

DIVIDEND AND CAPITAL GAINS TAX CUTS UNLIKELY TO YIELD TOUTED ECONOMIC GAINS

Response by Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez to: The Top 1%... of What? By ALAN REYNOLDS

Understanding the Effects of the 2001, 2003, and 2004 Income Tax Cuts

Defining the problem: the difference between current deficit and long-term deficits

SENATE PROPOSAL TO ADD UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE BENEFITS IMPROVES EFFECTIVENESS OF STIMULUS BILL by Chad Stone, Sharon Parrott, and Martha Coven

HEALTH INSURANCE PROPOSALS IN ADMINISTRATION S BUDGET COULD WEAKEN THE EMPLOYER-BASED HEALTH INSURANCE SYSTEM. by Edwin Park

House Health Bill: Tax Cuts for Wealthy, Insurers, and Drug Companies Paid for by Low- and Middle-Income Families

The Saver s Credit: Issues and Options

ALLOWING HIGH-INCOME TAX CUTS TO EXPIRE ON SCHEDULE WOULD BE SOUND ECONOMIC AND FISCAL POLICY By Chuck Marr

REPLACING WAGE INDEXING WITH PRICE INDEXING WOULD RESULT IN DEEP REDUCTIONS OVER TIME IN SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS

FINANCE COMMITTEE MAKES FLAWED EMPLOYER REQUIREMENT IN HEALTH REFORM BILL STILL MORE PROBLEMATIC

CONGRESS HAS CUT DISCRETIONARY FUNDING BY $1.5 TRILLION OVER TEN YEARS First Stage of Deficit Reduction Is In Law

Hundreds of millions at stake for New York s working families: Current tax debate to determine future of key work-supporting tax credits

GAO STUDY CONFIRMS HEALTH SAVINGS ACCOUNTS PRIMARILY BENEFIT HIGH-INCOME INDIVIDUALS By Edwin Park and Robert Greenstein Summary

HOUSE WAYS AND MEANS OFFSET FOR REPEALING AFFORDABLE CARE ACT S TAX REPORTING REQUIREMENT WOULD WEAKEN HEALTH REFORM

The Saver s Credit: Issues and Options

Updated May 11, of Economic Research, August First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

1102 Longworth House Office Building 1106 Longworth House Office Building Washington, DC Washington, DC 20515

U.S. Household Savings for Retirement in 2010

Rewarding Work Through State Earned Income Tax Credits in 2018

Who can doubt that the U.S.

TESTIMONY OF ROBERT GREENSTEIN Executive Director, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities Before the House Budget Committee July 25, 2007

Medicare in Ryan s 2014 Budget By Paul N. Van de Water

In the United States, most tax incentives for saving are. The Taxation of Retirement Saving: Choosing Between Front Loaded and Back Loaded Options

WILL THE ADMINISTRATION S TAX CUTS GENERATE SUBSTANTIAL ECONOMIC GROWTH? by Richard Kogan

The Shrinking Tax Preference for Pension Savings: An Analysis of Income Tax Changes,

Analysis of CBO s Budget Outlook: Fiscal Years

Senate Republicans Take Big First Step Towards $1.5 Trillion Deficit-Increasing Tax Cut

THE WHITE HOUSE Office of the Press Secretary EMBARGOED FOR 8:00PM EST SATURDAY, JANUARY 17, 2015

Improving Tax Incentives for Low-Income Savers: The Saver s Credit

Census Data Show Robust Progress Across the Board in 2016 in Income, Poverty, and Health Coverage

Early Withdrawals and Required Minimum Distributions in Retirement Accounts: Issues for Congress

Ryan Plan Gets 69 Percent of Its Budget Cuts From Programs for People With Low or Moderate Incomes By Richard Kogan and Joel Friedman

Tax Freedom Day: A Description of Its Calculation and Answers to Some Methodological Questions

New House Republican Tax Proposal Fails Fiscal Responsibility Test, While Favoring the Wealthiest

ESTATE TAXES, DEFICITS and BUDGET IMPLICATIONS

Individual Retirement Accounts and 401(k) Plans: Early Withdrawals and Required Distributions

Verifying Incomes of All EITC Filers Would Delay Refunds, Raise Costs, Divert IRS Resources from More Effective Uses

Transcription:

820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org July 17, 2006 PENSION BILL CONFERENCE REPORT MAY MAKE SOME 2001 TAX CUTS PERMANENT WITHOUT OFFSETTING THEIR COSTS Bill Could Set Precedent for Other Unpaid-for Tax-Cut Extensions By Robert Greenstein and Aviva Aron-Dine Summary Pension legislation passed by the House late last year included provisions that would make permanent the higher contribution limits for tax-preferred retirement savings accounts enacted in 2001. The pension bill conferees reportedly are considering including these provisions in the pension bill conference report, without offsetting their cost. According to Joint Committee on Taxation estimates, making the higher contribution limits permanent would cost about $34 billion between 2007 and 2016. Moreover, that ten-year cost estimate reflects only six years of the cost of extending these tax cuts, because they do not expire until the end of 2010. Of greater concern, making the pension-related provisions of the 2001 tax cut permanent could set a precedent for extending other tax cuts enacted since 2001 without paying for them, an approach that ultimately could add as much as $3.3 trillion to deficits over the next decade. Extending the pension-related 2001 tax cuts now would contravene the principle, laid out by former Federal Reserve Chair Alan Greenspan among others, that expiring tax cuts should be extended only if offset. It also would be irresponsible to rush to extend these tax cuts for several additional reasons: First, these provisions primarily benefit high-income households and provide little or no assistance to low- and moderate-income taxpayers attempting to save for retirement. According to the Urban Institute-Brookings Institution Tax Policy Center, only 6 percent of all households and only 1 percent of households with incomes below $50,000 would benefit at all from the extension of these provisions. In contrast, nearly half of the households with incomes above $1 million would benefit. And overall, about three-quarters of the tax benefits would go to the less-than-one-sixth of taxpayers with incomes over $100,000 a year. Second, although the purported goal of raising the contribution limits for tax-preferred savings accounts is to increase personal saving, there is no evidence that higher contribution limits actually have this effect. The data needed to assess the impact of the 2001 pension tax cuts on

saving is not yet available. Moreover, as the Congressional Research Service recently reported, broader research on tax-preferred savings accounts has found that such accounts appear to be relatively ineffective in inducing new saving, and that when their effects in increasing the budget deficit are taken into account, the long-term effect on national savings and economic growth is likely negative. 1 In acting now to extend the 2001 provisions, Congress would be spending billions of dollars to make these tax cuts permanent without waiting for evidence on their effects, and in the face of evidence that other, similar provisions have proven ineffectual. Finally, conferees are reportedly considering making the increases in contribution limits permanent while only temporarily extending the saver s credit, the one provision of the 2001 tax cut that was intended to provide low- and moderate-income households with incentives to save. This approach is not only inequitable; it also ignores evidence that savings incentives targeted to low- and moderate-income households are effective. The Cost of Extending the 2001 Increases in Savings Account Contribution Limits The major tax legislation enacted in 2001 included several provisions that expanded tax incentives for retirement saving. One of these provisions, discussed below, created a tax credit to encourage saving among low- and moderate-income households. Other provisions increased the contribution limits for Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs) and employer-sponsored defined contribution retirement plans (such as 401(k)s). The 2001 legislation gradually increased the contribution limit for IRAs from the existing limit of $2,000 per person per year to $5,000 by 2008; after 2008, the $5,000 limit will be increased each year to reflect inflation. Similarly, the 2001 legislation increased the contribution limit for how much employees may contribute to their 401(k)s each year from $10,500 to $15,000 by 2006, with this limit, too, indexed for inflation in years after that. 2 The House pension bill would make these provisions permanent, at a cost of $34 billion between 2007 and 2016, according to Joint Committee on Taxation estimates. The Joint Tax Committee s ten-year figures, however, reflect only six years of the cost of extending the measures, which do not expire until the end of 2010. Of the projected $34 billion ten-year cost of extending these tax cuts, $32 billion or over 90 percent of it falls in the second five years of the budget window. The annual cost reaches almost $8 billion by 2016. 3 1 Thomas Hungerford, Saving Incentives: What May Work, What May Not, Congressional Research Service, June 20, 2006. 2 The 2001 bill also included additional increases in allowable contributions for taxpayers age 50 or older. In the case of IRAs, individuals in this age range can contribute an additional $1,000 per year to an account; in the case of 401(k)s, they can contribute an additional $5,000 (by 2006), with that amount indexed for inflation in future years. Thus, individuals age 50 or older now can place $20,000 a year in a 401(k). Their employers contributions are on top of this. 3 Extending the higher contribution limits for IRAs would also add substantially to the cost of a tax cut included in the tax reconciliation bill enacted in May. That provision lifted the income limits on conversions from IRAs to Roth IRAs, allowing high-income households to roll their traditional IRAs into Roth IRAs, from which withdrawals are tax exempt. Extending the 2001 provisions would enable high-income households to accumulate more funds in traditional IRAs and would thereby raise the cost of the rollover measure. See Aviva Aron-Dine and Robert Greenstein, Provision in Tax Cut Bill Effectively Eliminates Income Limits on Roth IRAs: Establishes Major New Tax Shelter for High-Income Households, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, revised May 15, 2006. 2

Of even greater concern from a fiscal standpoint, making the 2001 pension tax cuts permanent without offsetting their cost could initiate a process by which many provisions of the 2001 and 2003 tax-cut legislation (and other expiring tax cuts) are made permanent in a piecemeal fashion over several years. If various tax cuts are each extended separately, less consideration likely will be given to their combined effect on long-term deficits. But, according to the Congressional Budget Office, making all expiring provisions permanent would reduce revenues by $2.8 trillion over the next ten years, adding $3.3 trillion to deficits when the increased interest on the debt is taken into account. Such an addition to deficits does not become any more affordable simply because it is done piece by piece instead of all at once. Former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan, among others, has stressed the importance of paying for tax-cut extensions when they are enacted, rather than allowing the fiscal impacts to mount. 4 It is not fiscally responsible to start down a path of making expiring tax cuts permanent without considering where that path could lead, and without reaching agreement on which tax cuts we can afford to extend and what offsets should be adopted to cover the costs. Who Benefits from Increasing Savings Account Contribution Limits? The pension provisions of the 2001 tax cut are often mistakenly perceived to be middle-class tax cuts, perhaps because many middle-income taxpayers contribute to 401(k)s, and smaller but still significant percentages contribute to IRAs. What is important to remember, however, is that the 2001 changes benefit only those IRA and 401(k) participants who would otherwise have maxed out their allowable contributions. Thus, in reality, the substantial cost of extending these provisions would be spent on tax cuts for high-income households, who are evidently the least in need of incentives and assistance to save. Studies by the Treasury Department, the Congressional Budget Office, and the Employee Benefit Research Institute all indicate the that percentage of households that would otherwise have maxed out their allowable contributions is small, and tiny at low- and moderate-income levels. 5 A recent CBO study finds that, as of 2000, only about 6 percent of employees made the maximum allowable contribution to IRAs, and only about 2 percent made the maximum allowable contribution to 401(k)s. Further, a Treasury Department study, authored by current Deputy Assistant Secretary for Tax Analysis Robert Carroll, found that taxpayers who did not contribute at the maximum prior to an increase in contribution limits would be unlikely to increase their IRA contributions if contribution limits were increased. 6 For these reasons, a General Accounting Office study 4 For instance, at a Joint Economic Committee hearing on November 3, 2005, then-chairman Greenspan responded to a question about extending the reduced tax rate on dividends, saying: I would like to see the extension of that provision in the tax law, but I would insist that it be done in the context of PAYGO [ pay-as-you-go rules], which is not currently on the books. 5 Craig Copeland, IRA Assets and Characteristics of IRA Owners, EBRI Notes, December 2002; David Joulfaian and David Richardson, Who Takes Advantage of Tax-Deferred Savings Programs? Evidence from Federal Income Tax Data, Office of Tax Analysis, Department of Treasury, 2001; Robert Carroll, IRAs and the Tax Reform Act of 1997, Office of Tax Analysis, Department of Treasury. 6 Congressional Budget Office, Utilization of Tax Incentives for Retirement Saving: An Update, February 2006. 3

estimated in 2001 that increasing the contribution limits for 401(k)s would directly benefit fewer than 3 percent of those employees who participate in 401(k)s. 7 CBO analyses also show that highincome taxpayers are far more likely to contribute the maximum amounts than low- and moderate-income taxpayers. Among workers with incomes above $160,000 who contributed to 401(k)s in 2000, CBO found that about 40 percent contributed the maximum amount. In contrast, of the far smaller percentage of workers with incomes below $40,000 who contributed to 401(k)s at all, only 1-2 percent made the maximum allowable contribution. 8 FIGURE 1 Few Low- and Moderate-Income Households Benefit from Extension of Higher Contribution Limits 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1% 7% Under $50,000 $50,000- $100,000 Source: Tax Policy Center Percent of households that would benefit, 2011 14% $100,000- $200,000 Annual Income 37% $200,000-$1 million 46% Above $1 million CBO s study of retirement account participation confirms the conclusions reached by the Urban Institute-Brookings Institution Tax Policy Center. TPC finds that only 6 percent of all households would receive any benefits from extending the higher contribution limits enacted in 2001. Yet more than one-third of households with incomes between $200,000 and $1 million and nearly half of households with incomes above $1 million would benefit, in contrast to about 1 percent of households with incomes under $50,000 (see Figure 1). The Tax Policy Center also estimates that three-quarters of the benefits of extending the provisions would go to the 16 percent of households with incomes above $100,000, while only 6 percent of the benefits would go to the 60 percent of households with incomes below $50,000. Has Lifting Contribution Limits Boosted Retirement Saving? The available evidence suggests that tax-preferred savings accounts are relatively ineffective in spurring additional saving and that raising contribution limits for these accounts may be especially ineffectual. Certainly, a casual look at the historical record would lead one to suspect that tax-preferred savings accounts may have failed to achieve their goals. Over the past 20 years, Congress has repeatedly expanded tax-preferred savings accounts, and the cost of these tax expenditures has risen. 7 General Accounting Office, Private Pensions: Issues of Coverage and Increasing Contribution Limits for Defined Contribution Plans, GAO-01-846, September 2001. 8 Congressional Budget Office, Utilization of Tax Incentives for Retirement Saving: An Update, February 2006. 4

Over the same period, the personal savings rate has fallen. In 2005, the personal savings rate turned negative for the first time since the Great Depression. 9 Of course, it is possible that personal savings would have fallen even further without tax incentives. That is not, however, the general finding of careful empirical studies. Research suggests that increases in IRA and 401(k) contributions, especially by people at high-income levels, frequently represent shifts in assets to take advantage of the tax-preferred accounts, not new saving. For example, economists Eric Engen of the American Enterprise Institute and William Gale of the Brookings Institution found that high-income families tend to shift existing assets into 401(k)s to take advantage of pension tax breaks without increasing their current saving. Engen and Gale write that, In the top earnings group [i.e. people with incomes above $75,000 in 1991], there appears to be no impact of 401(k)s on financial assets or wealth, and a significant reduction in other assets due to 401(k)s. 10 On the basis of this and other evidence, a recent Congressional Research Service report concludes that tax incentives appear to be relatively ineffective in inducing new saving many of the families benefiting from the tax incentives likely shifted funds from other saving accounts into the taxpreferred accounts. 11 Such asset shifting is of particular concern in the case of the measures enacted in 2001. As discussed above, the increases in contribution limits enacted in 2001 primarily affect high-income households the households most likely to simply shift assets and thus are likely to be doing little to boost private saving even though they add to the deficit and thereby reduce public saving. The data needed to directly assess the effects of the increases in contribution limits enacted in 2001 are not yet available, and it is possible that these changes will turn out to have had surprising positive consequences. But since the provisions do not expire until the end of 2010, there is simply no reason to rush to extend them now rather than waiting for more evidence to become available. Furthermore, some analysts have warned that some of the pension provisions enacted in 2001 may reduce pension coverage for low- and moderate-income workers, by reducing incentives for small business owners to offer retirement plans for their employees. Because of the 2001 law, business owners will, by 2008, be able to put away $10,000 a year in IRAs for themselves and a spouse $12,000 a year if the business owner is 50 or older without having to set up an employer-sponsored retirement plan that also covers their employees. Prior to enactment of the 2001 tax law, business owners who wished to place more than $4,000 a year in a tax-advantaged retirement account for themselves and their spouse had to set up a plan that covered their employees as well. Some pension experts expect that this change in pension law will, over time, reduce the proportion of small business owners who offer retirement plans for their workers. This concern provides yet another reason to wait for more information to become available, rather than rushing to make the 2001 provisions permanent. 9 For comparisons between tax expenditures for savings and the personal saving rate, see Elizabeth Bell, Adam Carasso, and Eugene Steuerle, Retirement Saving Incentives and Personal Saving, Urban Institute, December 20, 2004. 10 Eric Engen and William Gale, The Effects of 401(k) Plans on Households Wealth: Differences Across Earnings Groups, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 8032, December 2000. 11 Thomas Hungerford, Saving Incentives: What May Work, What May Not, Congressional Research Service, June 20, 2006. 5

Inequitable Treatment of Low- and Moderate-Income Savers As noted, the 2001 tax cut included one retirement saving incentive targeted to low- and moderate-income households: the saver s credit. Taxpayers with incomes below $50,000 for a married couple (below $25,000 for an individual) are eligible to receive a tax credit of up to 10 percent, 25 percent, or 50 percent of the contributions (up to $2,000) that they have made during the year to employer-sponsored retirement plans or IRAs. (The credit rate depends on the taxpayer s income.) Considerable evidence suggests that tax incentives for low- and moderate-income taxpayers, unlike incentives directed at high-income taxpayers, can successfully spur new saving. A study by the Retirement Security Project, for example, found that, if appropriately designed, tax credits can induce increases in retirement saving by low- and moderate-income families, with larger credits resulting in more savings. 12 The saver s credit enacted in 2001 is limited, however, in several key respects. It is not refundable, which means that many low-income taxpayers cannot use it. For example, a couple with two dependent children that makes retirement contributions cannot benefit from this credit in 2006 unless its income surpasses $24,100. In addition, the credit rate phases down abruptly with income, and the limits are not indexed for inflation. Over time, therefore, families who use the saver s credit and whose income merely keeps pace with inflation would experience reductions, often significant, in the value of their credit and would consequently face higher income taxes. In contrast, the higher contribution limits for IRAs and 401(k)s enacted in 2001 are indexed for inflation. Also, unlike the other pension-related provisions of the 2001 tax cut, the saver s credit is scheduled to expire at the end of this year. The House pension bill would make the saver s credit permanent, but without fixing any of its limitations, and in particular, without indexing its income limits for inflation. Because of this flaw, the House bill which might seem to permanently protect the credit would, in fact, scale it back sharply over time and cause it eventually to disappear altogether. 13 Moreover, the pension bill conferees reportedly are considering extending the saver s credit only for a very brief period possibly just one year and doing so without addressing its flaws, even as they contemplate making the other 2001 pension tax cuts permanent, with their full inflation adjustments. A more logical strategy would be to respond to the recent research on low-income saving incentives by addressing at least one critical problem with the saver s credit the lack of inflation indexing while deferring consideration of the other pension-related tax cuts, which do not expire for four years, until more information becomes available on their effects and until some consideration has been given to how to pay for them. 12 See Esther Duflo, William Gale, Jeffrey Liebman, Peter Orszag, and Emmanuel Saez, Savings Incentives for Low- and Middle- Income Families: Evidence from a Field Experiment with H&R Block, Retirement Security Project 2005-5, May 2005. 13 The credit eventually would disappear because the income levels below which households do not owe income tax are indexed for inflation, while the income levels above which households are ineligible for the saver s credit would be frozen under the House bill. Eventually, all households that owe income tax would have incomes too high to qualify for the credit. See Robert Greenstein and Joel Friedman, Saver s Credit for Moderate-Income Families Would Fade Away Over Time If Not Indexed for Inflation, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, revised July 17, 2006. 6