Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth

Similar documents
Exercises on chapter 4

ECON Micro Foundations

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set 3 Solutions

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Problem Set 3. Consider a closed economy inhabited by an in ntely lived representative agent who maximizes lifetime utility given by. t ln c t.

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Solutions to Problem Set # 2

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

LECTURE 1 : THE INFINITE HORIZON REPRESENTATIVE AGENT. In the IS-LM model consumption is assumed to be a

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

EconS Constrained Consumer Choice

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

Econ Review Set 3 - Answers

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market.

Econ Homework 4 - Answers ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS OF CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION. 1. Assume that a rm produces product x using k and l, where

Fall Midterm Examination Solutions Monday 10 November 2014

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

Problem Set (1 p) (1) 1 (100)

Cash in Advance Models

Equilibrium Asset Returns

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Fall 2009

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III

Multiperiod Market Equilibrium

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Principles of Optimal Taxation

1 Dynamic programming

Consumption and Saving

Problem Set I - Solution

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the

Lecture Notes 1

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems I (Solutions)

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

ECONOMICS 723. Models with Overlapping Generations

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Advanced Macroeconomics Tutorial #2: Solutions

ECON385: A note on the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). In this note, we will try to understand the permanent income hypothesis (PIH).

Answer Key Practice Final Exam

1. Introduction of another instrument of savings, namely, capital

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Economics 101. Lecture 8 - Intertemporal Choice and Uncertainty

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Macro Consumption Problems 33-43

Midterm 2 (Group A) U (x 1 ;x 2 )=3lnx 1 +3 ln x 2

The Role of Physical Capital

On Diamond-Dybvig (1983): A model of liquidity provision

Micro Theory I Assignment #5 - Answer key

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Section 2 Solutions. Econ 50 - Stanford University - Winter Quarter 2015/16. January 22, Solve the following utility maximization problem:

Macro Consumption Problems 12-24

Revision Lecture. MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

1 Consumer Choice. 2 Consumer Preferences. 2.1 Properties of Consumer Preferences. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 4 of the text.

Problem set 1 ECON 4330

Complete nancial markets and consumption risk sharing

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

We want to solve for the optimal bundle (a combination of goods) that a rational consumer will purchase.

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

Limits to Arbitrage. George Pennacchi. Finance 591 Asset Pricing Theory

Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model

(0.50, 2.75) (0,3) Equivalent Variation Compensating Variation

Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply

1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is. x + F (q) y. where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not

Real Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade Obstfeld and Rogo, Chapter 4

The Representative Household Model

Lecture 1: A Robinson Crusoe Economy

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7

Mean-Variance Analysis

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 1

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

ECON 200 EXERCISES. (b) Appeal to any propositions you wish to confirm that the production set is convex.

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Economics 11: Solutions to Practice Final

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

Lecture 4 - Utility Maximization

EconS Substitution E ects

Introducing money. Olivier Blanchard. April Spring Topic 6.

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 7 of the text.

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 6a

Transcription:

Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth Alberto Bisin October 29, 2009 Question Consider a two period economy. Agents are all identical, that is, there is one representative agent. The representative agent is alive at time t and t +, and has preferences: lnx t + lnx t+ ; < : This agent is endowed with 0 units of the consumption good at time t and at time t +. There is no in ation in this economy, and hence you can assume throughout that the price for the good at time t is.. Write down the consumer maximization problem of the representative agent (call the real interest rate r in the budget constraint), rst order conditions, and demand functions. 2. Write down the market clearing conditions (that is, feasibility conditions) for the whole economy. 3. Solve for the equilibrium interest rate and for the representative agent equilibrium allocation. 4. Suppose the agent cannot borrow and lend, that is, savings are zero and there is no interest rate r: he/she has to consume his/her own endowment in each period. How would you write the budget constraints?

[hint: the plural is not a typo; there is a budget constraint for each time period] Once again the price of consumption at t and also at t + now can be normalized to. Are his/her equilibrium allocations changed? 5. Suppose again that the representative agent cannot borrow or lend, but he/she can now invest units of the consumption good at time t (he/she still has his/her endowment as before). Call the amount invested k t+ ; the production function is y t+ = k t+ ; > that is, the agent can give up k t+ units of consumption at time t to get k t+ extra units at time t + (this is all per-capita; in terms of the notation used in class, k t = 0). Assume > (you will need this later). 5-i. Write down the budget constraints for the representative agent [be careful here! the plural is still not a typo]. 5-ii. Write down the consumer maximization problem, using the budget constraints you derived, to solve for the optimal choice of investment k t+. Then solve for the equilibrium allocations. 5-iii. [Bonus Question; this is hard] Suppose that borrowing and lending markets are now open, that is, there is an interest rate to be determined. This of course together with the investment and production technology as above. How does the budget constraint [yes, singular] look like? Are equilibrium allocations changed? What is the equilibrium interest rate?. Answer. For the maximisation problem, we need the objective function, which is the utility function above, and a budget constraint. To get the budget constraint we use the de nition of savings and solve as we did in class s = m t x t = 0 x t x t+ = m t+ + ( + r)s = 0 + ( + r)s ) x t + + r x t+ = 0 + + r 0 = 0( + r + ) 2

This gives the Lagrangian L(x ; x 2 ; ) = lnx t + lnx t+ (x t + + r x t+ 0 And rst order necessary conditions: Combining these gives us @L = = 0 @x t x t @L = @x t+ x t+ + r = 0 @L @ = x t + + r x t+ 0 + r 0 = 0 + r 0) x t+ x t = ( + r) Substituting into the constraint gives us ) x t+ = ( + r)x t x t + x t = 0( + + r ) ) x t = 0 + (2 + r + r ) ) x t+ = 0 (2 + r) + 2. As always, the market clearing (feasibility) conditions tell us that the sum of the demand for a particular good across all agents has to equal the total supply (or endowment). Here this is pretty easy, as there is only one agent! So we have Substituting in from above gives x t = m t = 0 x t+ = m t+ = 0 0 + (2 + r + r ) = 0 0 (2 + r) + = 0 3

3. Due to Walras Law, we know we only need to use one of these conditions to solve for the equilibrium interest rate. For ease, we ll use the second one. We can rearrange as follows: 0 (2 + r) = 0 + 2 + r = + r = + 2 r = Substituting back into the demand functions gives 0 x t= + (2 + r + r ) = 0 + + = 0 + = 0 + + + and x t+ = 0 (2 + r) + = 0 + + = 0 Note that we didn t really have to substitute back in at this stage. We already know from feasability that consumption has to equal endowment in each period. 4. If the agent cannot borrow or lend, then they have to balance the budget in each period. In other words, savings have to be equal to zero. Using the expressions we wrote down for savings before, we get s = m t x t = 0 x t = 0 ) x t = 0 4

and x t+ = m t+ + ( + r)s = 0 + ( + r)s = 0 As the consumer cannot borrow and save, there is no choice for her to make: she just has to eat her endowment each period. In fact, this is the same as the equilibrium allocation from the previous problem though note that they come about from very di erenct processes. Here, we have constrained the agents to eat their own endowment each period. Previously it was the feasibility constraint that led to the agent eating their own endowment. 5. We know that in period, the agent receives his endowment of 0 units. At this point, she can choose to consume these units or save them as capital. This gives us our period budget constraint: x t + k t+ = m t = 0 In the second period, the agent receives her endowment, plus the output from investment in period. She will spend all this income on consumption. This gives the second budget constraint: x t+ = y t+ + m t+ = k t+ + 0 We solve for the equilibrium allocation. There are lots of di erent ways to do this. The way we will follow here is as follows. First note that the only thing that the agent really gets to choose is the amount she saves k t+. Once we know this, we know c t from the rst budget constraint, and c t+ from the second budget constraint. We are going to therefore proceed by using the budget constraints above to get an expression for c t and c t+ and substitute this into the utility function x t = 0 k t+ x t+ = k t+ + 0 ) U = ln(0 k t+ ) + ln(k t+ + 0) This now an unconstrained maximisation problem in which the agents have 5

to choose k t+. Taking rst order conditions gives: @U = + @k t+ 0 k t+ k t+ + 0 = 0 ) = 0 k t+ k t+ + 0 k t+ + 0 = (0 k t+ ) k t+ + k t+ = 0 0 ( + )k t+ = ( ) 0 ( ) 0 k t+ = ( + ) Note that this is only positive if. Otherwise (as we don t allow the person to invest negative amounts), the optimal choice will be k t+ = 0. Assuming that this condition is satis ed, we can calculate x t and x t+ ( ) 0 ( + ) ( ) x t = 0 k t+ = 0 = 0( ) ( + ) ( + ) ( + ) = 0 ( + ) ( ) 0 ( ) 0 x t+ = k t+ + 0 = + 0 = + 0 ( + ) ( + ) (( ) + ( + )) ( + ) = 0 = 0 ( + ) + [Bonus Question] First, let s write down the budget constraint for each period. In the rst period, the number of bonds that the agent will buy is equal to her income minus her spending on consumption minus her spending on capital: s = m t x t k t+ In the second period, she will spend all the income she gets, which is equal to her endowment, plus the return she gets from bonds, plus the return she gets from her capital x t+ = m t+ + ( + r)s + k t+ 6

We can now combine these two budget constraints in the usual way: s = ( + r) (x t+ m t+ k t+ ) ) m t x t k t+ = ( + r) (x t+ m t+ k t+ ) ) x t + ( + r) x t+ = m t + ( + r) m t+ + ( + r )k t+ Now stare hard at the right hand side of the equation, remembering that the left hand side is the amount that the person spends and the right hand side is the amount that they have to spend. What will happen if +r > 0? Then the agent just gets richer and richer the more capital they buy. In this case, they will just keep on borrowing money and spending it on capital, so the demand for capital will be in nite. This cannot be an equilibrium. Why is this happening? Note that the condition +r > 0 ) > + r or in other words the return on the bond is lower that the marginal product of capital. This explains our previous result: There is an arbitrage opportunity in this economy. The agent can borrow money on bonds and invest it in capital to make free money. The only possible equilibrium of this economy is therefore when +r 0, or the interest rate on the bond is greater than or equal to the marginal product of capital. If < 0 ) < +r then the marginal product of +r capital is less than the interest rate. In this case, we might think that there is an arbitrage opportunity from the agent selling capital and buying bonds. However, this is not the case because the agent cannot buy less than 0 units of capital. However, we do know that the agent will never buy capital, as she would do better by investing in the bond. The economy therefore looks exactly the same as if there was no capital and investment, in other words the one we solved in part one of this question. In this case, we know that r =. So if + r = >, this will be an equilibrium with allocations + 0 in each period. There will always be another equilibrium in which = + r. Here the rate of return on bonds is exactly the same as the rate of return on capital, so people will be indi erent between the two methods of investing. We can therefore safely assume that the bonds don t exist. In this case, we will be in exactly the same equilibrium we calculated above with no bonds. 7

2 Question 2 Consider the following economy. Time is t = ; 2. There is a representative consumer whose production technology is: Y t = F (k) = Ak t where k t is the per capita capital stock at time t and A has a productivity parameter interpretation. The consumer OWNS the production technology and thus makes the production decisions. The capital stock from one period can be stored and re-used in the next period (with NO depreciation). The consumer is endowed with k > 0 units of capital stock in t = : There is no uncertainty. Write the consumer s capital accumulation problem. 2. Answer The story is the following: There is one consumer (who is assumed to represent the aggregate preferences of many consumers) who has access to a production technology (capital can be used to produce an output good) and a storage technology (capital is accumulated from period to period). The output good in each period can be used for one of two purposes - consumption or increasing the capital stock for the next period (investment/savings). The period by period "resource" constraints are that consumption today plus the change in capital stock must equal production today. The change in capital stock is the capital stock tommorrow minus the capital stock today. This means the resource constraints are c t + (k t+ k t ) = y t Remember that the production is given by the production function, y t = Ak t. Putting this into the resource constraint gives c t + (k t+ k t ) = Ak t 8

The nal thing to notice is that the consumer only lives for two periods. Thus he/she has no incentive to build up capital stock for the next period. As a consequence he/she will not save/invest in the nal period. Thus the second period resource constraint will be c 2 = Ak 2 Given these constraints, the capital stock in the initial period that the consumer is endowed with, the consumer needs to nd the combination of consumption in the two periods and capital stock in the second period that maximises his/her utility. This leads to the capital accumulation problem. The consumer needs to solve the following problem Given fk g Choose fc ; c 2 ; k 2 g to Maxfln c + ln c 2 g s:t: c + (k 2 k ) = Ak c 2 = Ak 2 This problem can be vastly simpli ed by substituting out c ; c 2 and solving the following problem Given fk g Choose fk 2 g to The f:o:c: for this problem is Max fln[ak (k 2 k )] + ln Ak 2 g [Ak (k 2 k )] ( ) + (Ak Ak2 2 ) = 0 To solve for the growth rate of consumption. The thing to notice here is that, by the nature of using the chain rule, we can easily substitute back the expressions for c and c 2 : Remember from our period by period budget constraints c = Ak (k 2 k ) c 2 = Ak 2 9

Putting these into the f:o:c: and rearranging [c ] ( ) + c 2 (Ak 2 ) = 0 (Ak2 ) = c 2 c Ak2 = c 2 c as was done in the lecture notes. Do notice that this is not technically a full solution to the problem yet since k 2 is the choice variable of the problem. To solve for k 2, rearrange the f:o:c: and massage them: [Ak (k 2 k )] = Ak 2 (Ak 2 ) =) = [Ak (k 2 k )] (Ak 2 ) Ak2 =) = [Ak (k 2 k )]k2 =) k 2 = Ak k 2 + k =) ( + )k 2 = (Ak + k ) =) k 2 = ( + ) (Ak + k ) 3 Question 3 The economy is exactly the same as in Question, except that now we introduce uncertainty over the value of the productivity parameter, A, which is now a random variable. In any time period, t, it takes the value A with probability p and the value A 2 with probability ( p). Formulate the capital accumulation problem. 3. Answer As a consequence of uncertainty, the consumer does not know what his resource constraints will be in future periods. This depends on which "state" the world is in, i.e. whether productivity is A or A 2. Thus in future periods there will be one resource constraint for each state. Speci cally this 0

will mean in period 2 we have c 2 (A ) = A k2 if A = A and c 2 (A 2 ) = A 2 k 2 if A = A 2 Thus the consumer is also uncertain as to his/her future consumption. To describe the knowledge that the consumer has more fully, at any time period, t, the consumer knows k t A at time t (this can be either A or A 2, but we will denote it A) c t (once he/she has chosen it) k t+ (once he/she has chosen it) The consumer does not know A at time t+ c t+ The consumer is assumed to be an expected utility maximiser. Thus he chooses fc ; c 2 ; k t+ g in order to maximise the following objective function E(u(c ; c 2 )) = E(ln c + ln c 2 ) where E is the expectation operator and the expectation is taken over the random variable A. Since the E is a linear operator (essentially this means that E(aX + by ) = ae(x) + be(y )) and c is known when the optimisation is done (in period one) E(u(c ; c 2 )) = ln c + E(ln c 2 ) Since the random variable A is discrete, the expectation of a function of the random variable is given by E(f(A)) = pf(a ) + ( p)f(a 2 ) where f(:) is a function that takes the random variable, A, as an arguement.

This means that the second term of the objective function can be expressed as E(ln c 2 ) = p ln[c 2 (A )] + ( p) ln[c 2 (A 2 )] The consumer needs then to solve the following problem Maxfln c + p ln[c 2 (A )] + ( Given fk ; Ag Choose fc ; c 2 (A ); c 2 (A 2 ); k 2 g to p) ln[c 2 (A 2 )]g s:t: c + (k 2 k ) = Ak c 2 (A ) = A k 2 c 2 (A 2 ) = A 2 k 2 This problem can be vastly simpli ed by substituting out c ; c 2 (A ); c 2 (A 2 ) and solving the following problem Given fk ; Ag Choose fk 2 g to Max fln[ak (k 2 k )] + p ln[a k 2 ] + ( p) ln[a 2 k 2 ]g The f:o:c: for this problem is p ( ) + (A [Ak (k 2 k )] A k2 k2 ) + ( p) (A A 2 k2 2 k2 ) = 0 Solve for the growth rate of consumption. Notice that, by the nature of using the chain rule, we can easily substitute back the expressions for c and c 2 (A ), c 2 (A 2 ). Remember from our period by period budget constraints c = Ak (k 2 k ) c 2 (A ) = A k 2 c 2 (A 2 ) = A 2 k 2 2

Putting these into the f:o:c: and rearranging p ( ) + [c ] c 2 (A ) (A k2 ) + p c 2 (A ) (A k2 ) + 4 Question 4 k 2 ( p) c 2 (A 2 ) (A 2k2 ) = 0 ( p) c 2 (A 2 ) (A 2k2 ) = c p A c 2 (A ) + ( p) A 2 c 2 (A 2 ) A k2 E c 2 (A) E Ak2 c c 2 (A) 0 u (c 2 ) u 0 (c ) E (MP K) = c = c = = Consider the following economy. There are 3 periods: t = ; 2; 3: Population is constant population equal to L every period. Consider a representative agent. Preferences of the representative agent are u(c ) + u(c 2 ) + 2 u(c 3 ); where u(c) = log(c) The technology is as follows. Production is Cobb-Douglas, i.e., Y t = AKt L The capital stock from can be stored and re-used in the next period (with depreciation rate ). The initial capital s endowment is K > 0: There is no uncertainty. Formulate the problem for the representative consumer and solve for consumption and investment per capita every period with full depreciation, i.e. =. 4. Answer To formulate the problem for the representative agent, we rst de ne the per capita variables. Let y t and k t denote output per capita and capital per capita, respectively, i.e. y t = Yt L t and k t = Kt L t : Notice that, by dividing the production function 3 t :

by total labor L t ; we express y t in terms of k t ; Y t L t = A Kt Lt L t L t y t = Ak t In our setup there is no population growth, i.e. L t = L for t = ; 2; 3: In case there was, it is necessary to make the appropiate adjustment in the investment process by the population growth rate. For example, consider a population growth percent rate equal to every period, i.e. + = L t+ L t. Then, investment per capita in period 2 is given by i 2 = K 3 ( )K 2 L 2 = K 3 L 2 ( ) K 2 L 2 = K 3 L 3 L 3 L 2 ( )k 2 = k 3 ( + ) ( )k 2 Before formulating the problem notice that, since the consumer lives for only three periods, it makes no sense to invest in the third period, that is, increase future capital stock. In the third period, the consumer will optimally choose not to invest and consume all the output instead. Hence, the capital accumulation problem for the consumer consists of choosing consumption and investment allocations (c ; c 2 ; c 3 ; i ; i 2 ). to max log(c ) + log(c 2 ) + 2 log(c 3 ) subject to c + i = Ak with i = k 2 ( )k () c 2 + i 2 = Ak 2 with i 2 = k 3 ( )k 2 (2) c 3 = Ak 3 (3) given k = K L > 0 With = investment collapses to i = k 2 and i 2 = k 3 : In our model the representative consumer decides to invest in capital stock for two main reasons. First, it is clear from the preferences of the consumer that he wants to smooth consumption over time, and the only means to do this is by carrying over capital to the next period and using it in the production. Second, the higher the capital stock, the higher the output and, consequently, the higher the consumption. 4

Using the three resource constraints we obtain expressions for consumption per capita in terms of capital per capita and plug them into the objective function: max log(ak k 2 ) + log(ak 2 k 3 ) + 2 log(ak 3 ) Taking FOCs with respect to the two choice variables, k 2 and k 3 ; we have which imply respectively c + c 2 Ak 2 = 0 c 2 + 2 c 3 Ak 3 = 0 c 2 = Ak2 (4) c c 3 = Ak3 (5) c 2 Plugging (3) into (5) we obtain the following expression for k 3 k 3 = c 2 (6) Substituting k 3 by expression (6) in resource constraint (2) leads to the following condition for c 2 c 2 = + Ak 2 (7) Then, combining (7) and (4) we obtain c = + k 2 (8) We can now pin down optimal k2 as a function of k by plugging (8) in resource constraint () k2 = Ak + Given this value for k 2; optimal c ; c 2; k 3 and c 3 are determined by applying equations (8), (7), (6) and (3), respectively. Recall the Chain Rule: @f(g(x)) @x = @f @g @g @x 5

5 Question 5 Consider a savings problem with budget constraints and preferences: c + s = m c 2 = m 2 + ( + r)s ln c + ln c 2 Construct the intertemporal budget constraint (IBC) and solve for savings s. Find how s depends on r: Embed now the economy in a overlapping generations economy with 2 consumers, i = A; B with preferences: and endowments: 5. Answer U i (c i ; c i 2) = ln c i + ln c i 2 2 (0; ); (m A ; m A 2 ) = (0; m) (m B ; m B 2 ) = (m; 0): The intertemporal budget constraint (IBC) is constructed as follows from the budget constraints: s = c 2 ( + r) =) c + c 2 ( + r) m 2 ( + r) m 2 ( + r) = m =) c + c 2 ( + r) = m + m 2 ( + r) 6

The intertemporal choice problem is: c + c 2 ( + r) c 0 c 2 0 To choose fc ; c 2 g to Maxfln c + ln c 2 g s:t: = m + m 2 ( + r) Use Langrangian technique L= ln c + ln c 2 + c + c 2 ( + r) m 2 m ( + r) The f:o:c: are @L @c = c + = 0 =) c = @L = + @c 2 c 2 ( + r) = 0 =) ( + r) c 2 = Eliminating Putting this into the IBC ( + r) = c c 2 =) c 2 = ( + r)c c + ( + r)c ( + r) = m + m 2 ( + r) =: W =) c = W ( + ) ( + r) =) c 2 = ( + ) W 7

Solving for the rst period savings Then s = m c = m m + m 2 (+r) ( + ) =) s = @s @r ( + ) m! m 2 ( + r)( + ) = m 2 d ( + ) dr ( + r) = m 2 ( + )( + r) 2 0 In the overlapping generations economy, an allocation is a list of consumption bundles, one for each consumer fc A ; c B g where c A = (c A ; c A 2 ) 2 X c B = (c B ; c B 2 ) 2 X A feasible allocation is an allocation that satis es c A + c B = m A + m B = m c A 2 + c B 2 = m A 2 + m B 2 = m i.e. satis es the resource constraints of the economy. A price-allocation pair, br; fc ba ; c B g where br= (; br) and c bi = (bc i ; bc i 2), is a competitive equilibrium (CE) if: For i = A; B and given prices br= (; br), the bundle b c i = (bc i ; bc i 2) solves the problem: c i 0 c i 2 0 Choose fc i ; c i 2g to maxfln c i + ln c i 2g s:t: c i + ci 2 ( + br) = m i + mi 2 ( + br) 8

Markets clear: bc A + bc B = m A + m B = m bc A 2 + bc B 2 = m A 2 + m B 2 = m Therefore, for f(c A ; c A 2 ); (c B ; c B 2 )g the consumer optimisation condition implies: c A = c A 2 = c B = c B 2 = W A ( + ) = m ( + )( + r) ( + r) ( + ) W A = ( + ) m W B ( + ) = m ( + ) ( + r) ( + ) W B = ( + r) ( + ) m Using the market clearing for consumption at time : m ( + )( + r) + m ( + ) = m =) + ( + r) = ( + )( + r) =) 2 + r = ( + ) + r + r =) = r =) + r = + =) + r = Checking the solution with the market clearing condition for consumption at time 2 ( + ) m + ( + ) m = ( + ) m ( + ) = m as required. 9

The price-allocation pair that forms a Competitive Equilibrium is br = bc A = bc A 2 = bc B = bc B 2 = m ( + ) m ( + ) m ( + ) m ( + ) Notice two important elements of this equilibrium: Agent B receives more consumption in both periods and thus has a higher utility than agent A. Both agents perfectly smooth their consumption over the two time periods. 6 Other problems For the following intertemporal utility functions, solve the consumer s problem (in other words, solve for the demand of each good in each period as a function of prices. To do this, you will have to construct a budget constraint for the agent. Assume that the agent has an income of w i in each period and that there is an interest rate + r i between period i and i +. ). In each case, calculate savings as a function of interests rate(s), and decide how savings will change as the interest rate changes.. U = u(c ) + u(c 2 ) where u(c) = c 2. U = u(c ) + u(c 2 ) + 2 u(c 3 ) where u(c) = ln c: (i.e., there are three periods) 3. U = x x 2 + x x 2. Here there are 2 goods available in each period. Assume that, in each time period, the price of x is p and the price of good x 2 is p 2 20

4. U = c + c 2 (here you should consider three cases, where is greater than, the same as, or less than + r: 5. For Question above, assume that there is in ation is 0% between the two periods (i.e. there is a price p, p 2 for the good in the two periods, and that p 2 = :p. First assume that the agents income is denominated in real terms. What is the equilibrium nominal interest rate. Now assume that the agent s income in denominated in nominal terms. What is the agent s income? 6. For the following economies, solve for the competitive equilibrium interest rate(s) and allocations 7. U A = u(c A ) + u(c2 A ), U B = u(c B ) + u(c2 B ), where the instantaneous utility functions are logarithmic, and with endowments (wa ; w2 A ), (wb ; w2 B ) 8. As above, but let u(c) = c and (w A ; w2 A ) = (; 3), (w B ; w2 B ) = (2; ) 9. U A = u(c A ) + u(c2 A ) + 2 u(c 3 A ), U B = u(c B ) + u(c2 B ) + 2 u(c 3 B ), where the instantaneous utility functions are logarithmic, and with endowments (w A ; w2 A ; w3 A ), (w B ; w2 B ; w3 B ) 0. U A = log c A + log c2 A ; U B = c B + c2 B and endowments (w A ; w2 A ) = (; 3), (wb ; w2 B ) = (2; ): 6. Answer. U = u(c ) + u(c 2 ); where u(c) = c The consumer problem is given by max u(c ) + u(c 2 ) subject to c + c 2 + r = w + w 2 + r Taking FOC with respect to c and c 2 we obtain respectively u 0 (c ) = 0 u 0 (c 2 ) = 0 + r 2

where is the Lagrange multiplier associated with the budget constraint. Using these two equations we obtain u0 (c 2 ) u 0 (c ) = + r Given the utility speci cation we assumed, this condition collapses to c2 = c + r implying that c 2 c = (( + r )) Let k = (( + r )) : Then, c2 = kc : Substituting c 2 by kc in the budget constraint leads to c + k = w + w 2 + r + r Then we can express c as a function of the endowments, ; r and ; c = w ( + r ) + w 2 + r + (( + r )) We can now pin down the saving function as s = w c = w w ( + r ) + w 2 + r + (( + r )) (9) (0) 2. U = u(c ) + u(c 2 ) + 2 u(c 3 ); where u(c) = log(c) The consumer problem is given by subject to c + c 2 + r + max u(c ) + u(c 2 ) + 2 u(c 3 ) c 3 ( + r )( + r 2 ) = w + w 2 + + r Taking FOC with respect to c ; c 2 and c 3 we obtain respectively 2 u 0 (c 3 ) u 0 (c ) = 0 u 0 (c 2 ) = 0 + r = 0 ( + r )( + r 2 ) 22 w 3 ( + r )( + r 2 )

where is the Lagrange multiplier associated with the budget constraint. Using the rst two equations we obtain while using the rst and third equation leads to u0 (c 2 ) u 0 (c ) = + r () 2 u 0 (c 3 ) u 0 (c ) = ( + r )( + r 2 ) (2) Given that u(c) = log(c), condition 4 collapses to c2 = c + r implying that or, equivalently, so, Condition 5 turns to be c3 c c 2 c = ( + r ) c 2 = ( + r )c (3) = ( + r )( + r 2 ) c 3 = ( + r )( + r 2 )c (4) We can now plug equations 3 and 4 into the budget constraint and derive an expression for c as a function of the endowments, interest rates and : c = ( + + 2 w + w 2 w 3 + ) + r ( + r )( + r 2 ) We now pin down c 2 and c 3 by substituting this expression into 3 and 4 c ( + r ) 2 = ( + + 2 w + w 2 w 3 + ) + r ( + r )( + r 2 ) c = ( + r )( + r 2 ) ( + + 2 w + w 2 w 3 + ) + r ( + r )( + r 2 ) 23

It follows that the saving functions in period and 2 are w + w 2 + + r s = w c 2 = w ( + + 2 ) s 2 = w 2 + s ( + r ) c 2 w 3 ( + r )( + r 2 ) 3. U = x x 2 + x 2 x 2 2; where x t i is the consumption of good i in period t: We can formulate this consumer problem as follows max x x 2 + x 2 x 2 2 subject to x + px 2 + x2 2 + p 0 x 2 2 + r = w + pw 2 + w2 + p 0 w 2 2 + r where p = p 2 is the relative price in the rst period and p 0 = p2 p 2 p 2 price in the second period. is the relative This utility function is convex and we will be having corner solutions. In particular either all the consumption today is zero or all future consumption is zero 2. Let W = w + pw 2 + w2 +p0 w 2 2 +r : Now, if we assume that consumption today is positive, we can take FOC for x and x 2; x : x 2 = 0 x 2 : x p = 0 where is the Lagrange multiplier for the budget constraint. It follows that px 2 = x Hence, if consumption today is positive, the individual will be spending half of W in good and the other half in good 2. In that case the utility is U = W 2 W 2p + 0 0 = W 2 4p Now let us assume that consumption in period is zero and consumption in period 2 is positive. Taking FOC with respect to x 2 and x 2 2 we have, x 2 : x 2 2 x 2 2 : x 2 +r = 0 p 0 +r = 0 2 We face the same problem as in the Planner problem solved in the lab. 24

implying that p 0 x 2 2 = x 2 Now the individual is spending half of W ( + r ) in good and the other half in good 2; 3 getting a utility value of U = 0 0 + W ( + r ) W ( + r ) = 2 W ( + r ) 2 2p 0 p 0 2 We have to decide whether the individual has zero consumption in period 2 or 2. As long as W 2 W (+r ) 4p p 0 2, or equivalently, p 0 ( + r p ) 2 ; the individual will only be consuming in period. In case p0 ( + r p ) 2 he will only consume in period 2. It is left to you to derive the saving function. 7. U A = u(c A ) + u(c2 A ); U B = u(c B ) + u(c2 B );where u(c) = log(c); and (wa ; w2 A ); (w B ; w2 B ): In the previous question we showed that when u(c) = log(c) condition 3 holds. This means that in this case we have c 2 A = ( + r )c A c 2 B = ( + r )c B Summing up these two equations we obtain C 2 = ( + r )C where C i is the total consumption in period i: Using the resource constraints, we know that C = wa + w B and C2 = wa 2 + w2 B : Hence, the equilibrium interest rate is given by ( + r ) = w 2 A + w2 B w A + w B The allocations can be pinned down by substituting this value for + r in the saving functions: s A = wa wa + w2 A + + r s B = wb wb + w2 B + + r 3 Notice that now he consumes W ( + r ) rather than just W because he is consuming in period 2. 25

8. U A = u(c A ) + u(c2 A ); U B = u(c B ) + u(c2 c B );where u(c) = ; and (wa ; w2 A ) = (; 3); (w B ; w2 B ) = (2; ): Now we are considering an economy populated by two individuals, A and B; where they can borrow and lend from each other, and the interest rate r will adjust endogenously to clear the market. Since we know that the two individuals have same preferences as before, it follows that c 2 A = kc A c 2 B = kc B where k = (( + r )) : If we aggregate consumption we obtain that C2 = kc ; where C and C 2 are total consumption in period and 2, respectively. Moreover from the resource constraints we have C = wa + w B = 3 and C 2 = wa 2 + w2 B = 4: Thus, k = 4 which implies that 3 + r = 4 3 The saving functions will look the same as in the previous exercise; we just need to plug in this expression for r : 26