Lecture 6 Applications of Static Games of Incomplete Information

Similar documents
Experiments on Auctions

Games of Incomplete Information ( 資訊不全賽局 ) Games of Incomplete Information

Auctions. Episode 8. Baochun Li Professor Department of Electrical and Computer Engineering University of Toronto

Auctions: Types and Equilibriums

EconS Games with Incomplete Information II and Auction Theory

Auctions. Agenda. Definition. Syllabus: Mansfield, chapter 15 Jehle, chapter 9

Social Network Analysis

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

Today. Applications of NE and SPNE Auctions English Auction Second-Price Sealed-Bid Auction First-Price Sealed-Bid Auction

CMSC 474, Introduction to Game Theory Introduction to Auctions

Auctions and Optimal Bidding

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Bayesian Nash Equilibrium

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012

Auctions. Microeconomics II. Auction Formats. Auction Formats. Many economic transactions are conducted through auctions treasury bills.

Bayesian games and their use in auctions. Vincent Conitzer

Auction Theory for Undergrads

CSV 886 Social Economic and Information Networks. Lecture 4: Auctions, Matching Markets. R Ravi

ECON Microeconomics II IRYNA DUDNYK. Auctions.

Subjects: What is an auction? Auction formats. True values & known values. Relationships between auction formats

Games with Private Information 資訊不透明賽局

Strategy -1- Strategic equilibrium in auctions

Auctions and Common Property

Auction is a commonly used way of allocating indivisible

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

Recap First-Price Revenue Equivalence Optimal Auctions. Auction Theory II. Lecture 19. Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 1

Auctions. Economics Auction Theory. Instructor: Songzi Du. Simon Fraser University. November 17, 2016

A Systematic Presentation of Equilibrium Bidding Strategies to Undergradudate Students

A Nearly Optimal Auction for an Uninformed Seller

Auction Theory - An Introduction

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

by open ascending bid ("English") auction Auctioneer raises asking price until all but one bidder drops out

1 Theory of Auctions. 1.1 Independent Private Value Auctions

1 Auctions. 1.1 Notation (Symmetric IPV) Independent private values setting with symmetric riskneutral buyers, no budget constraints.

Game Theory Lecture #16

Auction Theory: Some Basics

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 6. Separation of Ownership and Control

Consider the following (true) preference orderings of 4 agents on 4 candidates.

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

Auctions. N i k o l a o s L i o n i s U n i v e r s i t y O f A t h e n s. ( R e v i s e d : J a n u a r y )

1 Intro to game theory

Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010

Dynamic games with incomplete information

Topics in Informational Economics 2 Games with Private Information and Selling Mechanisms

M.Phil. Game theory: Problem set II. These problems are designed for discussions in the classes of Week 8 of Michaelmas term. 1

Multiunit Auctions: Package Bidding October 24, Multiunit Auctions: Package Bidding

October An Equilibrium of the First Price Sealed Bid Auction for an Arbitrary Distribution.

Strategy -1- Strategy

Problem Set 5 Answers

Algorithmic Game Theory

Random Search Techniques for Optimal Bidding in Auction Markets

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Auctions. Book Pages Auction. Auction types. Rules to Auctions

Ideal Bootstrapping and Exact Recombination: Applications to Auction Experiments

ECO 426 (Market Design) - Lecture 8

Auction types. All Pay Auction: Everyone writes down a bid in secret. The person with the highest bid wins. Everyone pays.

SI Game Theory, Fall 2008

For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market. June 2017

ECO 426 (Market Design) - Lecture 9

Game Theory. Important Instructions

HW Consider the following game:

Chapter 17 Auctions and Bargaining. Outline. Auctions

Auctions 1: Common auctions & Revenue equivalence & Optimal mechanisms. 1 Notable features of auctions. use. A lot of varieties.

Notes on Auctions. Theorem 1 In a second price sealed bid auction bidding your valuation is always a weakly dominant strategy.

Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation

Auctions. Michal Jakob Agent Technology Center, Dept. of Computer Science and Engineering, FEE, Czech Technical University

Auction. Li Zhao, SJTU. Spring, Li Zhao Auction 1 / 35

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Coordination and Bargaining Power in Contracting with Externalities

Optimal Auctions. Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham

Microeconomics Comprehensive Exam

Matching Markets and Google s Sponsored Search

Solution to Tutorial 1

Games of Incomplete Information

Auctions That Implement Efficient Investments

Game Theory. Jiang, Bo ( 江波 )

Simon Fraser University Spring 2014

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY HANDOUT ON PERFECT BAYESIAN EQUILIBRIUM- III Semi-Separating equilibrium

Auction Theory. Philip Selin. U.U.D.M. Project Report 2016:27. Department of Mathematics Uppsala University

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Economics 101A (Lecture 21) Stefano DellaVigna

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Lecture Notes on Anticommons T. Bergstrom, April 2010 These notes illustrate the problem of the anticommons for one particular example.

Secret Reserve Price in a e-ascending Auction

Game Theory and Auctions

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions.

Auction theory. Filip An. U.U.D.M. Project Report 2018:35. Department of Mathematics Uppsala University

Shills and Snipes. June Abstract

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Comprehensive Exam

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Exercises on Auctions. What are the equilibrium bidding functions a * 1 ) = ) = t 2 2. ) = t 1 2, a 2(t 2

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 10: Introduction to Game Theory 2

Solution to Tutorial /2013 Semester I MA4264 Game Theory

Almost essential MICROECONOMICS

Auctions. Michal Jakob Agent Technology Center, Dept. of Computer Science and Engineering, FEE, Czech Technical University

Notes for Section: Week 7

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

Analyses of an Internet Auction Market Focusing on the Fixed-Price Selling at a Buyout Price

2 Comparison Between Truthful and Nash Auction Games

Transcription:

Lecture 6 Applications of Static Games of Incomplete Information Good to be sold at an auction. Which auction design should be used in order to maximize expected revenue for the seller, if the bidders valuation of the good is private knowledge? English auction: Oral bids, ascending until nobody wants to make a higher bid. The person with the highest bid gets the good and has to pay his highest bid. Most used auction form, used e.g. for art auctions. Dutch auction: Auctioneer starts with a high price, then lowers it gradually until the rst buyer accepts. This buyer gets the good and has to pay the price he accepted. Used e.g. for ower and vegetable auctions. () September 6, 014 1 / 15

Sealed bid auction: each bidder makes just one bid simultaneously, and the bidder with the highest price wins. If two or more bidders make the same highest bid, then winner randomly chosen. First price: Winner pays his own bid, i.e. the highest bid Second price: Winner pays the highest of the loosing bids, i.e. the second highest bid. The framework Two bidders, who can make non-negative bids. The value of the good for each bidder is private information: bidder i knows only his own valuation v i. Independent draws of the valuation for each bidder: Private value auction () September 6, 014 / 15

Example of private value: art object bought by collector Opposite: Good has the same value for everyone, but true value is unknown to the bidders: "Public value auction". Example: mobile phone licence. v i drawn from uniform distribution over [0, 1], i.e. for 0 k l 1 probfk v i lg = l k Note: probfv i = cg = 0 for all c. payo s: u i = v i a if bidder i wins and pays price a u i = 0 otherwise. () September 6, 014 3 / 15

1. Sealed bid auction Bayesian game G = fa 1,...A n ; T 1,...T n ; p 1,...p n ; u 1,...u n g Action sets: A 1 = A = [0, ) Type spaces: T 1 = T = [0, 1] =) Strategy of player i: s i : [0, 1]! [0, ) with s i (v i ) being i 0 s bid when i 0 s valuation is v i () September 6, 014 4 / 15

beliefs: i 0 s belief that j 0 s valuation is between k and l is given by p i (k < v j < l jv i ) = l k = p i (k < v j < l) i 0 s belief that j 0 s valuation is c is given by: p i (v j = c) = 0 Reason: independent drawings from uniform distributions Other extreme case: drawings completely aligned: 1 if k vi l p i (k v j l jv i ) = 0 else () September 6, 014 5 / 15

1.1. First price sealed bid auction expected payo of player i with a valuation v i and a bid a i, given player j 0 s strategy s j (v j ) u i (v i, a i, s j (v j )) = probfa i > s j (v j )g(v i a i ) + 1 prob fa i = s j (v j )g (v i a i ) Proposition: Both players choosing the strategy si (v i ) = v i Nash equilibrium. is a Bayesian () September 6, 014 6 / 15

Proof: In order to prove the proposition, we have to show that for every type (i.e. for every valuation) the proposed bid indeed maximizes the expected payo of player i, given the strategy of player j. Take player 1 with a valuation v 1 and assume that player bids v for all possible v. Then probfa 1 > s (v )g = 1 probfa 1 v g = 1 p 1 fa 1 v 1g = 1 (1 a1 ) = a 1 if a 1 1 1 else probfa 1 = s (v )g = 0 ) u 1 (v 1, a 1, s (v )) = a1 (v 1 a 1 ) if a 1 < 1 (v 1 a 1 ) if a 1 1 () September 6, 014 7 / 15

If a 1 < 1 : 0 = v 1 4a 1 ) a 1 = v 1 if a 1 1 : a 1 = 1 Hence, a1 = v 1 is the optimal action for any v 1 against player 0 s strategy, and therefore player 1 0 s strategy s1 (v 1) = v 1. By symmetry, player 0 s strategy is also optimal against player 1 0 s strategy ) si (v i ) = v i for both players is a Nash equilibrium. () September 6, 014 8 / 15

Revenue of the seller π s : Denote by w the player with the higher valuation v w, and by l the player with the lower valuation v l. Due to uniform distribution, the expected v l = v w. Hence, the seller s expected revenues are: π s = v w = v l () September 6, 014 9 / 15

1.. Second price sealed bid auction expected payo of player i with a valuation v i and a bid a i, given player j 0 s strategy s j (v j ): u i (v i, a i, s j (v j )) = probfa i > s j (v j )g(v i s j (v j )) + 1 prob fa i = s j (v j )g (v i s j (v j )) Proposition: Both players choosing the strategy s i (v i ) = v i is a Bayesian Nash equilibrium. () September 6, 014 10 / 15

Proof: Take player 1 with a valuation v 1 and a bid a 1 = v 1. We have to distinguish between 3 cases: a > a 1 = v 1. In this case, any other bid a 0 1 with a0 1 < a would not make any di erence for player 1, since he still does not win. With the alternative bid a 0 1 > a, player 1 wins the good, but has to pay a price of a which is above his valuation of the good -1 makes a loss. Finally, for the alternative bid a 0 1 = a, there is a chance that player 1 wins the good and makes a loss. Hence, no pro table deviation from a 1 = v 1 is possible when a > v 1. a < a1 = v 1. In this case, any other bid a1 0 with a0 1 > a would not make any di erence for player 1, since he would still win and pay a. With the alternative bid a1 0 < a, player 1 does no longer win the good and gets zero, whereas with a1 = v 1 he would get v 1 a > 0. Finally, for the alternative bid a1 0 = a, there is a chance that player 1 does not win the good, although winning would be pro table. Again, no pro table deviation from a1 = v 1 is possible. () September 6, 014 11 / 15

a = a 1 = v 1. In this case, any other bid a 0 1 with a0 1 > a would not make any di erence for player 1, since he wins and pays a so that his utility would still be zero. With the alternative bid a 0 1 < a, player 1 does no longer win the good and gets zero, too. Again, no pro table deviation from a 1 = v 1 is possible. Hence, for all possible a, no type of player 1 can pro tably deviate from a 1 = v 1. By symmetry, the same holds for player. Revenue of the seller π s Denote by w the player with the higher valuation v w, and by l the player with the lower valuation v l. Due to uniform distribution, the expected v w = v l. Hence, the seller s expected revenues are: π s = v l = v w () September 6, 014 1 / 15

Revenue equivalence: The same expected revenue for the seller in the rst and in the second price sealed bid auction! Reason: For given bids, the revenues are higher in the rst price auction. However, bidders bid higher in the second price auction, since the winner s payment does not depend on his own bid. Both e ects exactly o set each other. Revenue equivalence holds for any number of bidders and any distribution of values, as long as the values are drawn independently - pure private value auctions. For n bidders: First price sealed bid auction: s i (v i ) = (n Second price sealed bid auction: s i (v i ) = v i 1)v i n () September 6, 014 13 / 15

. English auction As long as at least two players bid, none of the bidder can gain, if he stops before his valuation is reached. No bidders bids higher, when his valuation level is reached. No bidder goes on if the second highest valuation is overbid by the smallest possible amount, i.e. one cent. Hence, everyone s but the winner s highest bid is his valuation, and the price paid by the winner is (nearly) the second highest valuation ) The English auction generates (nearly) the same bidding behavior as the second price sealed bid auction. It leads to the same winner (bidder with the highest valuation), and the same revenues between the English and the second price sealed bid auction di er only by 1 cent. Again, it can be shown that this equivalence holds whenever we have a pure private value auction. () September 6, 014 14 / 15

3. Dutch auction The Dutch auction is equivalent to the rst price sealed auction. Reason: When in a Dutch auction a player is the rst to accept the descending price, he acts without knowing when the others would accept. Hence, accepting a certain price in the Dutch auction is equivalent as bidding the same price in the rst price sealed bid auction. Furthermore, the consequences are the same: The winner pays the accepted price (i.e. his own bid). Therefore, any equilibrium in the Dutch auction has the same outcome as the any equilibrium in the rst price sealed bid auction. () September 6, 014 15 / 15