Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 12: Introduction to International Taxation

Similar documents
Economics 230a, Fall 2018 Lecture Note 14: Tax Competition

Tax Treaties and the International Allocation of Production: The Welfare Consequences of Location Decisions and Strategic Tax Setting

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Is Foreign Direct Investment Sensitive to Taxes?

Discussions of the possible adoption of dividend exemption. Enacting Dividend Exemption and Tax Revenue

RIETI Special Seminar. U.S. Tax Reform: Prospects and Roadblocks. Handout. Alan J. Auerbach

GUIDE TO TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL COUNTRY NOTES

Subject Index. Canada: depreciation rules, ; generally accepted accounting principles, 202; inventory

Chapter URL:

Corporate Taxation. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

A Hybrid Approach: The Treatment of Foreign Profits under the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act

Volume Title: International Taxation and Multinational Activity. Volume URL:

The Tax Revenue Capacity of the U.S. Economy

The impact of worldwide vs territorial taxation on the location of assets and the scale of investment: A survey of the empirical evidence

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 11: Capital Gains and Estate Taxation

Nuts & Bolts of Corporate Tax Reform

Under the current tax system both the domestic and foreign

Tax Reform in Theory and Practice. Alan Auerbach August 20, 2017

Territorial Taxation: Choosing Among Imperfect Options

Coversheet: Company tax rate issues further information

Chapter 9. Tax Issues Surrounding Multinational Corporations. Introduction

Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries

MEASURING TAXES ON INCOME FROM CAPITAL:

Volume Title: The Effects of Taxation on Multinational Corporations. Volume URL:

A new design for the corporate income tax?

Capital Cost Recovery across the OECD, 2018

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE TAX REFORM ACT OF 2014

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 9: Dynamic Taxation II Optimal Capital Taxation

TAXING CORPORATE INCOME

Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting. Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley

Taxing Corporate Income

Tanzi (1987) studies the sweeping tax reform that occurs

Lecture 7: Taxation of capital income

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Economics 230a, Fall 2015 Lecture Note 11: Capital Gains and Estate Taxation

TRENDS IN BUSINESS DEVELOPMENT COMPANIES 2017

Competition for R&D tax incentives in the European Union how an optimal R&D system shall be designed

6080 INTERNATIONAL TAXATION

The Institute for Fiscal Studies (IFS) has commissioned two large-scale reviews of the ISSUES IN THE DESIGN OF TAXES ON CORPORATE PROFIT

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 7: Externalities, the Marginal Cost of Public Funds, and Imperfect Competition

Optimal Labor Income Taxation. Thomas Piketty, Paris School of Economics Emmanuel Saez, UC Berkeley PE Handbook Conference, Berkeley December 2011

International Tax Reforms with Flexible Prices

Suggested answers to Problem Set 5

Taxes and the co-location of intangibles and tangibles

Taxable Income Elasticities. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Offshore Profit Shifting and Domestic Productivity Measurement

A Singular Achievement of Recent Monetary Policy

The Development and Use of Models for Fiscal Policy Analysis. Alan Auerbach September 23, 2016

PRESENT LAW AND ISSUES IN U.S. TAXATION OF CROSS-BORDER INCOME

Simulations of the macroeconomic effects of various

A Macro Assessment of the DBCFT Costs and Benefits

Research Philosophy. David R. Agrawal University of Michigan. 1 Themes

TAXABLE INCOME RESPONSES. Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics. Lecture Notes for MSc Public Economics (EC426): Lent Term 2014

Headquarter Relocations and International Taxation

The Crossroads Versus the Seesaw: Getting a Fix on Recent International Tax Policy Developments

Capital Taxation after EU Enlargement

I. Interest Groups and the Government Budget

Demystifying the Destination-Based Cash-Flow Tax

The Zero Lower Bound

Moving to a (Properly Designed) Territorial System of Taxation Will Make America s Tax System Internationally Competitive

Globalization, Economic Statistics, Policy, and Business Decisions: A Framework for Measurement

The one-minute trade policy theorist. (most of what you need to know)

Notes on Obstfeld-Rogoff Ch.1

Strategic Treaty Shopping

Do Tax Havens Divert Economic Activity?

Corporate Taxation. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

FINANCE & DEVELOPMENT

Basic Macroeconomic Relationships

Back from the Dead: How to Revive Transfer Pricing Enforcement

Steinar Holden, August 2005

Tax Working Group Information Release. Release Document. September taxworkingroup.govt.nz/key-documents

Tax Policy and Foreign Direct Investment in Open Economies

Internet Taxation. Francis Bloch. Toulouse, Postal Conference, April 16, Université Paris 1 and PSE

Macroeconomic Measurement 3: The Accumulation of Value

Chapter 8 Canada and the Rest of the World

5. Openness in Goods and Financial Markets: The Current Account, Exchange Rates and the International Monetary System

Tax Policies in Open Economies

Equilibrium Audit Strategies Against Tax Treaty Shopping

SAMPLE QUESTION PAPER 2 ECONOMICS Class XII BLUE PRINT

It has been suggested in the literature that a shortage of sound and liquid financial

Some Basic Facts about Government Expenditures and Taxation in Canada. Econ 525

International Monetary Systems

Seasoned International Tax Professionals

rate (%) Nuclear fuel 42.4 Prepackaged software 39.7 Inventories 39.0 Office and accounting equipment 39.0 Computers and peripheral equipment

Perhaps the most striking aspect of the current

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

TAXING PROFITS IN A CHANGING WORLD

Hilary Hoynes UC Davis EC230. Taxes and the High Income Population

How the Foreign Exchange Market Works

Outline. What is Money? What does affect the supply of Money? What does affect the demand of Money? Asset Portfolio Decision

Asian Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee

GPP 501 Microeconomic Analysis for Public Policy Fall 2017

Module 19 Equilibrium in the Aggregate Demand Aggregate Supply Model

MOBILITY AND FISCAL IMBALANCE. Robin Boadway Queen s University, Canada. Jean-François Tremblay University of Ottawa, Canada

ejournal of Tax Research

Hamid Rashid, Ph.D. Chief Global Economic Monitoring Unit Development Policy Analysis Division UNDESA, New York

INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL TAXATION

Department of Economics Working Paper 2019:1

The International Comparison Program (ICP) provides estimates of the gross domestic product

Transcription:

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 12: Introduction to International Taxation It is useful to begin a discussion of international taxation with a look at the evolution of corporate tax rates over the past few decades. Here are the rates (for all levels of government combined) for the G-7 countries since 1981, from the OECD Tax Database: 70.0% G-7 Corporate Tax Rates 60.0% 50.0% 40.0% 30.0% 20.0% 10.0% 0.0% 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 Canada France Germany Italy Japan United Kingdom United States There is a pretty clear downward trend, with rates ranging from 36%-60% in 1981 and 21%-39% in 2014. Of note is that the highest tax rate in 2014 is for the United States. A similar trend exists for other developed countries as well. Also, there are many countries, typically quite small in population and GDP, where corporate tax rates are close to or equal to zero. Such countries are commonly known as tax havens. In between tax havens and the G-7 countries, in both size and tax rates, are countries like Ireland, where the tax rate in 2014 is 12.5%. Even Ireland, though, has made a transition to this low tax rate, having begun in 1981 with a tax rate of 45%. The trend toward lower tax rates is sometimes characterized as a race to the bottom resulting from tax competition among governments, but such a description fails to explain why competition might have become more intense over time, as the falling rates would suggest. We will discuss the tax competition literature, but it is first necessary to explore in more detail the important attributes of international tax systems.

The Basic Structure of International Tax Systems International tax systems differ not only in their rates and their bases (e.g., what expenses are deductible, etc.), but also, very importantly, in the principles countries use to determine which income to tax. While it may at first seem straightforward for a country to tax its income, there is no clear definition of the income of any particular country. One obvious distinction, as in the national income accounting distinction between GDP and GNP, is between income earned in a country and income earned by a country, which in the international tax context amounts to the difference between taxing income according to its source, i.e., where production occurs, and taxing income according to residence, i.e., the location of those earning it. The United States is sometimes said to have a residence-based tax system (also known as a worldwide tax system) rather than a source-based system (also known as a territorial tax system), but the US system is better understood as a hybrid, with some characteristics of a residence-based tax system, some characteristics of a source-based tax system, and still other characteristics that are present under neither the source nor residence approach. Modeling the Effects of International Taxation Suppose that there are two countries, the home country and the foreign country, with available before-tax rates of return r at home and r * abroad. Suppose that the home corporate tax rate is t and the foreign tax rate is t *. What will be the conditions for cross-border investment in equilibrium? Under a source-based tax, the home investor s after-tax return at home is r(1 t); the investor s return abroad is r (1 t ). The same returns are available for the foreign investor. Therefore, in capital market equilibrium where both investors are indifferent, the before-tax returns in two countries must satisfy r = r (1 t )/(1 t). Both investors receive the same after-tax rates of return, but the before-tax rates of return are unequal unless t * = t. Under a residence-based tax, the home investor s after-tax returns at home and abroad are r(1 t) and r (1 t), respectively, while the foreign investor s after-tax returns are r(1 t ) and r (1 t ). In this case, both investors will be indifferent if r = r *, although the after-tax returns received by home and foreign investors will be equal only if t * = t. To summarize the results so far, after-tax returns in a particular location are independent of the investor s residence under source-based taxation, while after-tax returns for a particular investor are independent of the investment s location under residence-based taxation. Also note that under residence-based taxation, but not under source-based taxation, before-tax rates of return are equal across the two countries. Now, consider a hybrid tax system such as that in the United States, which starts from a residence-based tax but then (1) gives a credit against foreign-taxes for US residents, up to the US tax rate; and (2) imposes domestic tax on all investments, not just those owned by US residents. Now, what will the capital-market equilibrium look like, if both countries follow such a tax scheme? 2

For home investors, after-tax returns for investments at home and abroad are r(1 t) and r (1 t ) 1 t c, where c = min (t, 1 c 1 c t ) is the maximum rate of foreign tax credit the home country allows. For the foreign investor, the corresponding after-tax returns are r (1 t ) and r(1 t) 1 t 1 c c 1 c, where c = min (t, t ). Note that, for the country with the lower tax rate, the credit rate will be the same as its own tax rate, so that the investor from that country will effectively confront a source-based tax system. On the other hand, the higher-tax country will provide a credit rate equal to the foreign country s tax rate, so that the investor from that country will face the same tax rate regardless of the location of investment, as under a residence-based tax system. That is, suppose that t > t *, as is realistic if the home country is the United States. Then the aftertax returns for home and foreign investors are, respectively: home investor: r(1 t), r (1 t ) 1 t t = r (1 t) foreign investor: r (1 t ), r(1 t) 1 t t = r(1 t) Now, capital-market equilibrium is not consistent with both investors investing in both countries, since for the home investor this would require r = r, while for the foreign investor the condition is r = r ( ) > r, since we have assumed that t > t *. It follows that equilibrium will be one in which at least one of the investors is specialized. If the home investor invests in both countries, then r = r and the foreign investor invests only in the foreign country, since r < r ( ). If the foreign investor invests in both countries, then is r = r ( ) and the home investor invests only at home, since r > r. If r ( ) > r > r, then both investors will specialize in their own countries. Thus, the tax system gives rise to a type of home bias in which each investor invests at home but at most only one investor invests abroad. In reality, the US tax system has another important attribute, namely that earnings abroad are subject to US tax only when the earnings are repatriated, not immediately. This may encourage US companies to keep earnings abroad, to defer paying US tax. As in the case of capital gains taxes discussed in an earlier lecture, this incentive to defer may be especially strong if the companies think that there is a possibility of a lower tax rate in the future. This incentive to defer is sometimes called the lock-out effect, as, in contrast to the induced behavior under capital gains taxation, funds are kept out of US investments, rather than kept in them. The paper by Forbes et al. studies the impact on repatriations of an interesting natural experiment in which the United States offered a substantial one-year reduction in the tax rate on repatriations. There was a huge surge in repatriations during that period, although the effects on domestic US investment were small, suggesting that the repatriating companies had sufficient capital market access without the repatriated funds. Note that the lock-out effect would not be present under a pure source-based system or a pure residence-based one; it is the combination of residence-based taxation and deferral that generates it. 3

Optimal Taxation in an International Setting In thinking about what a particular country s tax system should look like (and leaving aside the potential reactions of other governments, which will be covered in the next lecture on Tax Competition), it is useful to consider the three potential tax rates on capital income that the home country might impose in the above-two country model: the tax rate on domestic investment undertaken by domestic residents, say τ, the tax rate on domestic investment undertaken by foreign residents, say φ, and the tax rate on foreign investment undertaken by domestic residents, say τ f. (We assume, realistically, that the home country can t impose tax on the fourth combination of investor residence and investment location, investment abroad by foreign investors.) Under a pure source-based system, τ = φ, and τ f = 0. Under the pure residence-based system, τ =τ f and φ = 0. Under a hybrid system like that of the United States, but ignoring the possibility of deferral of tax on unrepatriated earnings, τ = φ, and 0 < τ f < τ, the last result reflecting the impact of the foreign tax credit, which reduces tax on foreign-source income by as little as 0 (if the foreign tax rate = 0) and by as much as to eliminate any domestic tax (if the foreign tax rate is at least as high as τ). The same effect of reducing τ f could, of course, be accomplished in a more straightforward manner simply by eliminating the foreign tax credit and imposing a lower statutory rate on foreign-source income, and we can think of the problem of optimal policy design as one of choosing the three tax rates, τ, φ, and τ f. This problem was first analyzed by Feldstein and Hartman (QJE 1979), and we can distinguish the cases of a small country and a large one. It is also helpful to think about special cases in which only home companies invest abroad and in which only foreign companies invest abroad. For a small, capital exporting country, the operative tax rates are τ andτ f, and a simple corollary of the Diamond-Mirrlees production efficiency theorem is that capital invested at home and abroad by domestic residents should face the same domestic tax rate in order for domestic and foreign uses of capital to be efficient, from the home country s perspective. (Note that from a worldwide perspective this won t result in efficient capital allocation if the foreign country s tax rate is positive, but we are considering what is optimal from the home country s perspective, taking foreign taxes as given.) Hence τ and τ f should be equal. For a small, capital importing country, there is no benefit to taxing capital imports, so φ should be zero. This result (as discussed in Gordon, AER 1986) follows from the fact that the elasticity of supply of capital to a small country is effectively infinite, so that a tax on capital imports falls on workers, just like a labor income tax. But the tax on capital also distorts domestic production, making it too labor intensive. Together, these results lead to the conclusion that small countries should adopt a pure residence-based tax on capital income, to the extent that capital income is taxed (which was considered in an earlier lecture). See the Gordon-Hines Handbook chapter for further discussion. For a large country, these results break down because tax policy can affect the terms of trade. For a capital exporting country, a higher tax on foreign source income reduces investment abroad and may therefore increase the before-tax return on such investment. For a capital importing country, a tax on income from inbound investment may drive capital out but also reduce the worldwide rate of return and the hence the cost of funds to the domestic economy. 4

Further Margins of Behavioral Response The discussion so far relates to a setting in which national corporations invest in homogenous capital on behalf of their country s residents, choosing between investment at home and abroad. But this abstracts from three key elements of reality: (1) Investments are not homogeneous, and may yield different payoffs to different investors; (2) Residents of a particular country may invest in domestic or foreign companies, domestic companies obtain funds in a world capital market, and a company s national identity is not fixed; and (3) The actual source of production and earnings is difficult to determine when an individual company operates in more than one jurisdiction. The first of these points suggests that it is not simply the level of capital, but also the pattern of capital ownership, that may be distorted. For example, a country might simultaneously be a capital exporter and a capital importer, even if it is a net capital importer, if its companies are particularly good at investing in certain places abroad. Then, a tax on inbound investment, which raises the domestic before-tax return and leads to a reduction in capital exports, also distorts the pattern of ownership by domestic firms, causing them to invest too much at home and too little abroad. Thus, the home government may wish to reduce the tax on foreign investment, τ f, below τ, in order to offset this distortion (Slemrod et al., J Pub. E. 1997). The second point means that taxing the income of resident corporations is not equivalent to taxing the income of resident individuals. Thus, the efficiency arguments for residence-based taxation at the corporate level are less apparent. Further, another margin of potential distortion arises in a company s choice of residence, which has been a major policy issue recently in the United States. Consider, for example, a case in which Germany and the United States have the same corporate tax rates, but Germany follows a territorial tax system and the United States follows a worldwide tax system with foreign tax credits. A company obtaining funds in a world capital market will face the same cost of capital regardless of its own residence, and will also face the tax rate on operations in either Germany or the United States. But a German company operating in a third, low-tax country, say Ireland, will face only the low tax rate in that country (because Germany has a territorial tax system), while the US company will face Irish tax plus additional US tax, because the tax credit for Irish tax offsets only some of the US tax liability on repatriated earnings. Hence, the US company faces a competitive disadvantage relative to the German company on operations in Ireland and other low-tax jurisdictions. If the company can relocate from the United States to Germany, it may do so, even if there are economic benefits to being in the United States. This change in residence is commonly called a corporate inversion because the simplest way to accomplish it (prior to 2004 legislation) was to have the US parent switch places in the corporate structure with a foreign subsidiary, as shown in the figure below. The approach taken more US parent German parent recently is for a US company to merge with a foreign tax no tax company and declare residence German sub. Irish sub. for the combined entity in the US sub. Irish sub. other company s country. 5

The third point above means that firms will engage in profit-shifting across jurisdictions in which they operate when different tax rates apply. For example, a US corporation may license intellectual property developed in the United States to a wholly owned Irish subsidiary for a very low price, meaning that the US company s profits will be understated and the Irish subsidiary s profits overstated. If the Irish subsidiary s profits were immediately subject to US tax, as under a pure residence-based tax, there would be no incentive for the US company to engage in profit shifting, which underlies arguments for a shift toward more immediate taxation of US profits abroad. But this shift would also increase the taxes on US companies relative to foreign companies and exacerbate incentives for US companies to engage in corporate inversions. On the other hand, a US shift toward source-based taxation would lessen incentives for inversions but increase incentives for profit shifting. The paper by Dharmapala and Riedel estimates the extent of profit-shifting among a sample of European multinationals by measuring the reaction to a parent s earnings shocks of the earnings of subsidiaries in other countries. They find that earnings in low-tax countries respond more positively than earnings in high-tax jurisdictions, suggesting that the parent is shifting some of the home income shock to the low-tax jurisdictions. The authors identify the choice of borrowing location as a key channel through which the profit-shifting occurs (accomplished through interest deductions in the location where the borrowing takes place). Returning to the figure presented at the beginning of the lecture, we can observe that a reduction in the corporate tax rate reduces incentives for inversions (by lowering US tax on foreign operations) and for profit shifting (by reducing the tax benefit of shifting profits from the US to other countries). This, along with the growing importance of multinational companies in the global economy, may help explain the trend toward lower corporate tax rates around the world, although there has also been a movement away from residence-based taxation, at least outside the United States. 6