Private pensions. A growing role. Who has a private pension?

Similar documents
Earnings related schemes: Design, options and experience. Edward Whitehouse

Pension reforms. Early birds and laggards

COVERAGE OF PRIVATE PENSION SYSTEMS AND MAIN TRENDS IN THE PENSIONS INDUSTRY IN THE OECD

Income support for older persons in the Republic of Korea : a perspective of older persons

axia Axia Economics Civil-service pension schemes Edward Whitehouse Civil-Service World Bank core course Washington DC, April 2016

Corrigendum. Page 41, Table 1.A1.1. Details of pension reforms, September 2013-September 2015 : Columns on Portugal should read as follows:

THE TAX SYSTEM IN BELGIUM COMPARED TO OTHER OECD COUNTRIES

Revenue Statistics Tax revenue trends in the OECD

Pensions at a Glance: Europe and Central Asia

Corrigendum. OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI: ISBN (print) ISBN (PDF) OECD 2012

Outlook Overview: OECD Countries UN LINK Conference, Bangkok October, 2009

Can employment be increased only at the cost of more inequality?

education (captured by the school leaving age), household income (measured on a ten-point

Capital Access Index 2006 Gauging Entrepreneurial Access to Capital

PENSIONS IN OECD COUNTRIES: INDICATORS AND DEVELOPMENTS

The Challenge of Public Pension Reform in Advanced and Emerging Economies

HOW MUCH REDISTRIBUTION DO WELFARE STATES ACHIEVE? THE ROLE OF CASH TRANSFERS AND HOUSEHOLD TAXES

Statistical annex. Sources and definitions

Pensions Incentives to Retire

Public Pension Spending Trends and Outlook in Emerging Europe. Benedict Clements Fiscal Affairs Department International Monetary Fund March 2013

OECD Report Shows Tax Burdens Falling in Many OECD Countries

The Challenge of Public Pension Reform

Primary Health Care Needs-Based Resource Allocation through Financing of Health Regions

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2016

LA SOSTENIBILITÀ E L ADEGUATEZZA DEI SISTEMI PENSIONISTICI NEI PAESI OCSE

Statistical Annex ANNEX

Pensions at a Glance

FDI drops 18% in 2017 as corporate restructurings decline

Extract from Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising

NATIONAL COMMUNICATIONS FROM PARTIES INCLUDED IN ANNEX I TO THE CONVENTION

Entrepreneurship at a Glance 2018 Highlights

Slovak Competitiveness: Fundamentals, Indicators and Challenges

TAX REFORM TRENDS IN OECD COUNTRIES

Alternative measures of well-being

EFFICIENCY OF EDUCATION EXPENDITURE IN OECD COUNTRIES

THE NEED FOR MORE SOCIAL SECURITY AND SECURE PENSIONS

Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD

Structural Policy Priorities

PUBLIC POLICIES ACROSS OECD COUNTRIES

LONG-TERM PROJECTIONS OF PUBLIC PENSION EXPENDITURE

London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine. Affording Our Future Conference Wellington, December, 2012

MINIMUM WAGES ACROSS OECD COUNTRIES: BACK TO THE FUTURE?

HOUSING MARKETS, BUSINESS CYCLES AND ECONOMIC POLICIES

8-Jun-06 Personal Income Top Marginal Tax Rate,

An International Perspective on Tax Reform in OECD countries

Ageing and employment policies: Ireland

Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons

REVERSE MORTGAGES: A TOOL TO IMPROVE LIVING STANDARDS OF THE ELDERLY? A EUROPEAN PERSPECTIVE

Plan: Reform Strategy - Bermuda Experience. Caribbean Conference on Health lhfinancing Initiatives

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2017

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2018

Statistical Annex. Sources and definitions

Low employment among the 50+ population in Hungary

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY PRIVATE PENSIONS OUTLOOK 2008 ISBN

Insurance Markets in Figures

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016

HEALTH LABOUR MARKET TRENDS IN OECD COUNTRIES

17 January 2019 Japan Laurence Boone OECD Chief Economist

GLOBAL TRENDS IN PENSION POLICIES AND REGULATIONS

Pension Markets. Pension fund assets hit record USD 20.1 trillion in 2011 but investment performance weakens IN THIS ISSUE. September 2012, Issue 9

Double-Taxing Capital Income: How Bad Is the Problem?

Written Statement to Senate Special Committee on Aging. Mark Pearson, Head, Health Division, OECD

POLICY TRENDS IN OECD COUNTRIES TO INCREASE COVERAGE AND CONTRIBUTIONS INTO FUNDED PENSION PLANS

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2014

RESILIENCE IN A TIME OF HIGH DEBT

Recommendation of the Council on Tax Avoidance and Evasion

Switzerland and Germany top the PwC Young Workers Index in developing younger people

Pension Fund Investment and Regulation - An International Perspective and Implications for China s Pension System

The Economic Contribution of Older Workers

Decumulation debate. New Zealand Society of Actuaries Financial Services Forum 16 November 2015

Finally arriving? Pension Reforms in Europe

Sources of Government Revenue across the OECD, 2015

The Norwegian Economy

Tax Working Group Information Release. Release Document. September taxworkingroup.govt.nz/key-documents

Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area

WORKING PAPERS. Sustaining Employment of Older Workers in an Ageing Society. Gudrun Biffl, Joseph E. Isaac

Major Trends in Pension Reforms. Ambrogio Rinaldi Director, COVIP, Italy Chair, OECD Working Party on Private Pensions

Monitoring Health System Reform in China: An OECD perspective

STATISTICS. Taxing Wages DIS P O NIB LE E N SPECIAL FEATURE: PART-TIME WORK AND TAXING WAGES

Pensions at a Glance 2011 RETIREMENT-INCOME SYSTEMS IN OECD AND G20 COUNTRIES

Development Assistance for HealTH

COMPARISON OF RIA SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES

Indicator B3 How much public and private investment in education is there?

Live Long and Prosper? Demographic Change and Europe s Pensions Crisis. Dr. Jochen Pimpertz Brussels, 10 November 2015

REFORMING PENSION SYSTEMS: THE OECD EXPERIENCE

Performance Budgeting (PB) in OECD Countries

Nero Meeting: Alain de Serres OECD Economics Department. 21 June 2013

Household Financial Wealth By Selected Country

WHAT ARE THE FINANCIAL INCENTIVES TO INVEST IN EDUCATION?

Coordinating Central and Local Governments Policy in Iceland. Björn Rúnar Guðmundsson Head of Economic Department Ministry of Economic Affairs

High Debt, Slow Growth, Financial Instability, Growing Inequality: What Role for Economic Policy?

International comparison of poverty amongst the elderly

EMPLOYABILITY AND LABOUR MARKET

The public private pension mix in OECD countries

Generic market trends in Europe

Introduction to Public Finance

Glossary of Defined Terms

Investing for our Future Welfare. Peter Whiteford, ANU

THE BENEFITS OF EXPANDING THE ROLE OF WOMEN AND YOUTH IN ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

Transcription:

Private pensions A growing role Private pensions play an important and growing role in providing for old age in OECD countries. In 11 of them Australia, Denmark, Hungary, Iceland, Mexico, Norway, Poland, the Slovak Republic, Sweden, Switzerland and the United Kingdom the private sector delivers part of the mandatory provision for income in old age. In addition, voluntary private pensions have broad coverage in a number of OECD economies. Three kinds of policy have increased the role of private pensions. First, Hungary, Mexico, Poland, the Slovak Republic and Sweden have recently introduced mandatory private pensions as a substitute for part of the public pension provision. Secondly, Australia and Norway have added a mandate for a private pension on top of existing public plans. Finally, many countries have scaled back their public pensions, leaving a greater role for voluntary, private savings. These include most notably Germany and Japan. take out a private pension. Hence, coverage of these programmes is between 45% and 60% of the current workforce, but this will rise over time to the whole labour force. Broad industrial-relations agreements ensure high coverage in some countries (Denmark, Netherlands, Sweden) and so can be thought of as quasi-mandatory. This briefing focuses on voluntary private pension provision: voluntary in the sense that either employers do not have to provide an occupational plan or that individuals do not have to join a personal plan. Who has a private pension? Data on coverage of private pensions, unfortunately, can be very difficult to obtain and are often difficult to compare between countries due to institutional differences in the markets for long-term savings. Table 1 draws on a number of sources; the OECD is working to improve these preliminary data. Table 1 shows coverage by type of scheme personal or occupational and by whether plans are voluntary or mandatory. Coverage is naturally higher when private pensions are mandatory (Australia, Iceland, Norway, Switzerland). In Hungary, Poland and the Slovak Republic, coverage of private pensions is only mandatory for younger workers and/or new labour-market entrants, whilst others had a choice as to whether to This media briefing is one of a pair prepared for the launch of the second edition of OECD Pensions at a Glance in Paris on 7 June 2007.

Table 1. Coverage of private pension plans Mandatory Coverage Voluntary Coverage personal occupational Denmark >90% Austria 35% Hungary 58% Belgium 40-50% Mexico 31% Canada 39% Poland 49% Finland 7% Slovak Republic 45% France 10% Sweden >90% Germany 57% Ireland 50% Mandatory occupational Italy Japan 8% 45% Australia >90% Luxembourg 20% Denmark >80% New Zealand 20% Iceland >90% Norway 45% Netherlands >90% Portugal 4% Norway >90% Spain 10% Sweden >90% United Kingdom 43% Switzerland >90% United States 47% Source: OECD Pensions at a Glance; OECD private pension statistics Voluntary occupational pension plans have long had broad coverage in English-speaking countries, such as Canada, Ireland, the United Kingdom and the United States, where it currently reaches 40% or more of employees. Belgium, Germany, Japan and Norway also achieve this degree of coverage. At the other end of the spectrum, 10% or fewer workers are covered by voluntary, occupational, private pensions in Finland, France, Italy, Portugal and Spain. The pension gap In countries with relatively small public pensions, individuals will need to make extra, voluntary, private savings to ensure that their living standards do not decline sharply as they move into retirement. Figure 1 shows the gross replacement rate pension in retirement relative to earnings when working for average earners in OECD countries. The projected gross replacement rate from mandatory pension schemes for the average earner with a full career ranges from 31% of individual earnings in the United Kingdom to 96% in Greece. The 11 countries at the bottom of the chart, which have below-average mandatory replacement rates, are the focus of this 2 briefing. What level of voluntary, private pension savings would be needed to deliver an overall gross replacement rate in these countries that equalled the OECD average? This is obviously an arbitrary target but it is useful to set a benchmark relative to all OECD countries, including those with mainly mandatory retirement provision. The difference between the national mandatory replacement rate and the OECD average is here called the pension gap. Along with all six of the mainly Englishspeaking members of the OECD Australia, Canada, Ireland, New Zealand, the United Kingdom and the United States mandatory gross replacement rates are below the OECD average in four continental European countries Belgium, the Czech Republic, France and Germany and in Japan. In the United Kingdom, private pension savings would need to deliver a replacement rate of 28% to bring the overall pension up to the level of the OECD average. France has the smallest retirement savings gap of the 11 countries analysed: 7.5%. For the 11 countries as a whole, the replacement rate from mandatory pensions is 40.6% for average earners, giving a retirement-savings gap of 18.2% on average.

Figure 1. The pension gap Gross replacement rate for an average earner from mandatory pension schemes and difference from OECD average replacement rate 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 Greece Luxembourg Netherlands Spain Austria Iceland Hungary Denmark Turkey Italy Korea Finland Sweden Poland Norway Switzerland Slovak Republic Portugal France Czech Republic Canada Australia United States Belgium Germany New Zealand Mexico Japan Ireland United Kingdom OECD average 58.7% Mandatory Mandatory Pension gap Source: OECD Pensions at a Glance Filling the pension gap The savings effort required to fill the pension gap obviously varies with the size of the gap: contributions would need to be larger in the United Kingdom than in France, for example. But it also depends on how long the pension is likely to be paid, i.e. on life expectancy, as well as the value of the pension, which in turn is largely determined by investment returns on pension savings. Life expectancy in France and Japan is much higher than it is in the Czech Republic. The length of time over which the pension is paid also depends on the age of retirement. The normal pension age is age 65 in eight of the countries, but is 60 in France, 62 in Hungary and 67 in the United States. The normal pension age also affects the duration over which contributions are made. On the baseline assumption of labour-market entry at age 20, individuals who contribute for a full career will pay into their pension funds for between 40 and 47 years, although in most cases this will be for 45 years. Taking account of all these factors differences in pension age, life expectancy and the pension gap it is possible to calculate the percentage of earnings that individuals would need to contribute to achieve an overall mandatory plus voluntary replacement rate equal to the OECD average. The results are shown in Figure 2. 3

Figure 2. Filling the pension gap Contribution rate required for average earner to reach average OECD replacement rate United Kingdom Japan Ireland New Zealand Germany Belgium Australia United States Canada France Czech Republic 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Source: OECD Pensions at a Glance The United Kingdom has the largest replacement-rate gap and the highest required contribution rate. Japan s replacement-rate gap is four percentage points lower than in the United Kingdom but life expectancy is longer. The required contribution rate in Japan is 6.7% compared with 6.9% in the United Kingdom. France has the smallest replacement-rate gap, but normal retirement age of 60 and life expectancy above the OECD average together increase the required contribution rate compared with countries with normal retirement at 65 or more. The required contribution rate is just 2.6% in France and the Czech Republic. How many people save for old age? Do individuals respond to lower replacement rates from mandatory pensions by making voluntary, private provision for retirement? Figure 3 compares coverage of voluntary private pensions with the size of the mandatory (public and private) replacement rate. There are two clear clusters of countries. First, there is a range of mainly Southern European countries Greece, Italy, Portugal, Spain and Turkey but also including Finland and Poland, that have voluntary private pension coverage of less than 10%. These countries also have relatively high mandatory replacement rates for average earners. For these seven countries, the average gross replacement rate is 71% compared with 59% for the OECD as a whole. The second cluster consists of eight countries with much lower mandatory replacement rates. Unsurprisingly, half of this group are from the mainly English-speaking countries Canada, Ireland, the United Kingdom and the United States. However, Belgium, the Czech Republic, Germany and Japan show a similar relationship between private pension coverage and the scale of the mandatory pension system. In these eight countries, the mandatory replacement rate for the average earner is just 38%. For how long should people save? People are unlikely to spend their whole working lives covered by voluntary, private pensions precisely because they are voluntary. How does the number of years over which people contribute affect the contribution rate required to fill the pensions gap, that is, to deliver an overall mandatory plus voluntary replacement rate that equals the OECD average mandatory replacement rate? Figure 4 gives the answer. 4

Mandatory gross replacement rates (per cent) Figure 3. Voluntary pensions fill the pension gap left by mandatory provision Projected replacement rate from mandatory pensions for average earners versus coverage of voluntary private pensions 100 GRC LUX 75 ESP ITA TUR HUN AUT 50 25 FIN POL PRT FRA NZL SVK NOR CZE CAN JPN BEL IRL USA DEU GBR 0 0 25 50 75 100 Voluntary private pension coverage (per cent) Source: OECD Pensions at a Glance; OECD private pension statistics At the left-hand side of the chart is the required contribution rate with a full contribution history from age 20 to national normal pension age. The next entry on the chart shows the situation with five years missing from the contribution history, i.e., assuming people delay starting their private pension until age 25. With ten missing years at the centre of the chart the required contribution rate in the United Kingdom increases to nearly 10%, compared with 7% with a full career. With 20 missing years, contributions need to be nearly 15% to plug the retirement-savings gap. In Ireland and Japan, the necessary contribution rates are a little below the rates for the United Kingdom. In Belgium, Germany and New Zealand, the required contribution rate is around 4.6% for a full career, 6.7% with 5 ten missing years and 10% with 20 missing years. The role of investment returns The value of defined-contribution pensions during retirement depends crucially on the rate of return on investments as well as on the amount contributed. The baseline assumption is a 3.5% real annual return. What happens when rates of return differ from this assumption? Ireland, Japan and the United Kingdom have the largest retirement-savings gaps, averaging 6.7% on the baseline assumptions. However, a lower rate of return would naturally mean that individuals would need to contribute more. To fill the retirement savings gap these three countries would need a 9.5% contribution rate if real returns were only 2%.

Figure 4. How years of contributions affect the pension gap Contribution rate needed to reach OECD average replacement rate for average earners by years of contributions 15.0 12.5 Required contribution, per cent of earnings United Kingdom Japan Ireland 10.0 7.5 5.0 New Zealand Belgium, Germany Australia Canada, United States France Czech Republic 2.5 0.0 Full career 5 years missing 10 years missing 15 years missing 20 years missing Source: OECD Pensions at a Glance In contrast, higher returns would offset some of the requirement to contribute to the private pension plan, lowering the necessary contribution rate to only 4.5%. At the other end of the scale, the contribution rates required in the Czech Republic and France would be 3.7% with low returns, 2.6% at the baseline and 1.8% with high returns. Conclusions In around a dozen OECD countries the target replacement rate from the mandatory (usually public) pension system is relatively low, leaving a large space for voluntary, private pension provision. In most of these 6 countries, coverage of private pensions is broad. Around one half of employees contribute to private pensions (on the best available evidence). Data on average contribution rates are even more difficult to obtain than information on coverage. Preliminary evidence shows average (mean) contribution rates for those covered of 8.5% in Canada, around 9% in the United Kingdom and United States and 10% in Ireland. These contribution rates would be sufficient to fill the pension gap, but only if people contribute for most of their working lives at these rates. A related concern for policymakers arises because private-pension coverage data are

a snapshot whereas lifetime coverage and contributions determine individual s retirement incomes. It is often not possible, for example, to know whether snapshot coverage of 50% implies that half the workforce contributes for every year of their working lives or the whole workforce contributes for half of their working lives. The implications for pension policy are very different if the target is to get more people to contribute or to get the same people to contribute for more of their careers. The traditional way of encouraging voluntary savings for retirement has been through tax incentives. However, these can be expensive and there is strong evidence that they are inefficient, in that much of the saving would have happened anyway without the incentive; tax incentives tend to be worth more to higher earners, for example. Moreover, voluntary private pension coverage does not reach much over 50% of the workforce in any OECD country. From the international experience, mandating private pensions appears to be the only way to have private pensions that cover significantly more than half the working-age population. But mandatory coverage has also its problems. People may resent being forced to save for retirement and may have good reasons not to: for example, because they are poor, their jobs are insecure or they have other reasons to save. New approaches to encouraging private pension saving, which avoid having to resort to compulsion, rely on the insights of behavioural economics about people s natural inertia. Such soft compulsion, requiring people to save unless they opt out, will be introduced at a national level, first, with the KiwiSaver plan in New Zealand. The United Kingdom aims to introduce a similar scheme and Ireland is debating the merits of going down this route. Evidence from US surveys suggests that other mechanisms can also help increase coverage of private pension plans, such as simplifying plan rules for eligibility and enrolment and providing financial education for workers. Tax credits rather than tax deductions may provide more encouragement for low-income workers to sign up for private pensions while part-time and self-employed workers may be reached through the promotion of personal pension plans. About Pensions at a Glance Government-mandated pension and retirement policies have changed dramatically during the past decade. Pensions at a Glance presents a consistent framework for comparing public pension policies across OECD countries, as well as reliable data. The report thus provides the basis for not only evaluating existing pension systems, but also designing and implementing future reforms. The second edition updates in-depth information on the key features of mandatory pension systems both public and private in the 30 OECD countries, including projections of retirement income for today s workers. Two new and important sections have been added to this edition: 1) description and analysis of pension reform in OECD countries during the past decade; and 2) a closer look at the complex range of private, voluntary retirement plans now playing a greater role in pension provision in many OECD countries, including an analysis of the private savings effort required to maintain standards of living during retirement. 7

Follow-up Please contact the OECD media division for more information: telephone: + 33 1 45 24 97 00. e-mail: news.contact@oecd.org To discuss the OECD s work on pensions systems, please contact directly: Monika Queisser telephone: + 33 1 45 24 96 34 e-mail: Monika.Queisser@oecd.org Edward Whitehouse telephone: + 33 1 45 24 80 79 e-mail: Edward.Whitehouse@oecd.org www.oecd.org/els/social/ageing/pag About the first edition Pensions at a Glance deserves much more than a glance. It is a compendium of facts and analyses that should inform policymaking and public debate around the world for years to come. By providing in clear and easy-to-understand form a wealth of information about pension systems throughout the OECD, it will make it much harder for even the most insular to ignore the valuable lessons to be learned from the pension experience of other nations. Henry J. Aaron The Brookings Institution Named one of 12 international notable government documents by the American Library Association. 8