The Black-Scholes Equation

Similar documents
Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

Pricing Options with Binomial Trees

Hedging. MATH 472 Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan

Forwards on Dividend-Paying Assets and Transaction Costs

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

Forwards and Futures. MATH 472 Financial Mathematics. J Robert Buchanan

The Spot Rate. MATH 472 Financial Mathematics. J Robert Buchanan

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

The Theory of Interest

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Expected Value and Variance

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Extensions to the Black Scholes Model

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

The Black-Scholes Model

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS WITH ADVANCED TOPICS MTHE7013A

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS WITH ADVANCED TOPICS MTHE7013A

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Financial Derivatives Section 5

The Black-Scholes Model

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Forwards and Futures

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Attempt QUESTIONS 1 and 2, and THREE other questions. Do not turn over until you are told to do so by the Invigilator.

The Black-Scholes Model

Attempt QUESTIONS 1 and 2, and THREE other questions. Do not turn over until you are told to do so by the Invigilator.

Financial Risk Management

MÄLARDALENS HÖGSKOLA

Homework Set 6 Solutions

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems

Basics of Asset Pricing Theory {Derivatives pricing - Martingales and pricing kernels

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

The Theory of Interest

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Lecture 3. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6

Finance II. May 27, F (t, x)+αx f t x σ2 x 2 2 F F (T,x) = ln(x).

In chapter 5, we approximated the Black-Scholes model

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Chapter 9 - Mechanics of Options Markets

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

Option Pricing. Simple Arbitrage Relations. Payoffs to Call and Put Options. Black-Scholes Model. Put-Call Parity. Implied Volatility

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Computational Finance

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

MAS452/MAS6052. MAS452/MAS Turn Over SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS AND STATISTICS. Stochastic Processes and Financial Mathematics

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

3.1 Itô s Lemma for Continuous Stochastic Variables

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Constructing Markov models for barrier options

Lecture 1. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. No tutorials in the first week

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Solutions of Exercises on Black Scholes model and pricing financial derivatives MQF: ACTU. 468 S you can also use d 2 = d 1 σ T

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

1 The continuous time limit

How Much Should You Pay For a Financial Derivative?

The Forward PDE for American Puts in the Dupire Model

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

Modeling via Stochastic Processes in Finance

Derivative Securities Section 9 Fall 2004 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences.

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Derivative Securities

Mathematical Modeling and Methods of Option Pricing

Degree project. Pricing American and European options under the binomial tree model and its Black-Scholes limit model

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

Risk Neutral Pricing Black-Scholes Formula Lecture 19. Dr. Vasily Strela (Morgan Stanley and MIT)

MATH 476/567 ACTUARIAL RISK THEORY FALL 2016 PROFESSOR WANG. Homework 3 Solution

5. Itô Calculus. Partial derivative are abstractions. Usually they are called multipliers or marginal effects (cf. the Greeks in option theory).

Stochastic Modelling in Finance

King s College London

MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN LECTURE 6: EXTENSIONS OF BLACK AND SCHOLES RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Transcription:

The Black-Scholes Equation MATH 472 Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan 2018

Objectives In this lesson we will: derive the Black-Scholes partial differential equation using Itô s Lemma and no-arbitrage assumptions, determine the appropriate boundary conditions for European options, summarize the initial, boundary value problem for European options. Note: in this presentation the notation dw (t) will be used in place of dw t since this derivation will make extensive use of partial derivatives.

Assumptions Price of the security follows the log-normal random walk. Risk-free interest rate r and volatility of security σ are known functions of time. No transaction costs. Security pays no dividends. No arbitrage, trading of assets takes place continuously, short selling is possible, and fractions of an asset can be sold.

Black-Scholes Equation We have already approximated the price of a European call option using a multi-step binomial model. Now we will use the continuous stochastic model of stock prices. Suppose a stock obeys an Itô process of the form: ds = µs dt + σs dw (t) An investor will create a portfolio Y, consisting of a short position in a European call option and a long position of shares of the stock. Y = F(S, t) = C e (S, t) ( )S

Black-Scholes Equation We have already approximated the price of a European call option using a multi-step binomial model. Now we will use the continuous stochastic model of stock prices. Suppose a stock obeys an Itô process of the form: ds = µs dt + σs dw (t) An investor will create a portfolio Y, consisting of a short position in a European call option and a long position of shares of the stock. Y = F(S, t) = C e (S, t) ( )S Use Itô s lemma to find the stochastic process followed by Y.

Recall Itô s Lemma Lemma (Itô s Lemma) Suppose that the random variable X is described by the Itô process ds = a(s, t) dt + b(s, t) dw (t) where dw (t) is the differential of the standard Wiener process. Suppose the random variable Y = F(S, t). Then Y is described by the following Itô process. dy = (a(s, t)f S + F t + 12 ) (b(s, t))2 F SS dt + b(s, t)f S dw (t)

Partial Derivatives F(S, t) = C e (S, t) ( )S F S = CS e F SS = CSS e F t = Ct e

Itô Process for dy Let a(s, t) = µ S and b(s, t) = σ S then dy = (a(s, t)f S + F t + 12 ) (b(s, t))2 F SS dt + b(s, t)f S dw (t) ( = µs ( CS e ) + 1 ) 2 σ2 S 2 CSS e + Ce t dt + σs ( CS e ) dw (t)

Itô Process for dy Let a(s, t) = µ S and b(s, t) = σ S then dy = (a(s, t)f S + F t + 12 ) (b(s, t))2 F SS dt + b(s, t)f S dw (t) ( = µs ( CS e ) + 1 ) 2 σ2 S 2 CSS e + Ce t dt + σs ( CS e ) dw (t) Note: the process becomes deterministic if = C e S. dy = ( ) 1 2 σ2 S 2 CSS e + Ce t dt

No Arbitrage Assumption The payoff from the portfolio should be the same as that generated by investing an amount of cash equal to Y in savings earning interest compounded continuously at rate r. Y = Y 0 e r t dy = r Y 0 e r t dt = r Y dt = r(c e ( )S) dt = r ( C e C e S S) dt

No Arbitrage Assumption The payoff from the portfolio should be the same as that generated by investing an amount of cash equal to Y in savings earning interest compounded continuously at rate r. Y = Y 0 e r t dy = r Y 0 e r t dt = r Y dt = r(c e ( )S) dt = r ( C e C e S S) dt Recall from Itô s lemma that ( ) 1 dy = 2 σ2 S 2 CSS e + Ce t dt. Equating the two expressions for dy yields the Black-Scholes partial differential equation r C e = C e t + r S C e S + 1 2 σ2 S 2 C e SS.

Final and Boundary Conditions (1 of 2) In order to solve the Black-Scholes PDE we must have some boundary and final conditions.

Final and Boundary Conditions (1 of 2) In order to solve the Black-Scholes PDE we must have some boundary and final conditions. At expiry the call option is worth (S(T ) K ) +, so this is the final condition. C e (S, T ) = (S(T ) K ) +,

Final and Boundary Conditions (1 of 2) In order to solve the Black-Scholes PDE we must have some boundary and final conditions. At expiry the call option is worth (S(T ) K ) +, so this is the final condition. C e (S, T ) = (S(T ) K ) +, The stock will have a value in the interval [0, ). The boundary at S = 0 is absorbing, so if there is a time t 0 such that S(t ) = 0, then S(t) = 0 for all t t. In this case the option will never be exercised and is worthless. Thus C e (0, t) = 0, which is the boundary condition at S = 0.

Boundary Conditions (2 of 2) From the Put-Call Parity Formula: C e = P e + S Ke rt lim S Ce = lim S Pe + S Ke rt C e S Ke rt as S.

Boundary Conditions (2 of 2) From the Put-Call Parity Formula: C e = P e + S Ke rt lim S Ce = lim S Pe + S Ke rt C e S Ke rt as S. As the security grows unbounded in value: a put option (right to sell at a finite price) becomes worthless, and the call option is worth the difference between the security price and the present value of the strike.

IBVP: European Call For (S, t) in [0, ) [0, T ], r C e = Ct e + r S CS e + 1 2 σ2 S 2 CSS e C e (S, T ) = (S(T ) K ) + for S > 0, C e (0, t) = 0 for 0 t < T, C e (S, t) = S K e r(t t) as S.

European Put If an investor creates a portfolio by buying a European put and shorting shares of the security, then the steps followed above for the European call produce the PDE: r P e = P e t + r S P e S + 1 2 σ2 S 2 P e SS. Question: What are the appropriate final and boundary conditions for a European put?

IBVP: European Put For (S, t) in [0, ) [0, T ], r P e = Pt e + r S PS e + 1 2 σ2 S 2 PSS e P e (S, T ) = (K S(T )) + for S > 0, P e (0, t) = K e r(t t) for 0 t < T, P e (S, t) = 0 as S.

Effect of Continuous Dividends Assumption: the stock pays dividends at a continuous rate proportional to the value of the stock dividend per unit time = δs How much dividend is paid in a short time interval dt? dividend paid = δs dt What stochastic differential equation would the value of the stock paying a continuous proportional dividend obey? ds = (µ δ)s dt + σs dw (t)

Arbitrage-free Portfolio Suppose C e,δ (S, t) is the value of a European call option on the stock paying a continuous dividend. As before, create a portfolio of a short position in the call option and a long position in shares of the stock. Y = C e,δ ( )S

Change in Portfolio Value One share of stock pays δs dt in dividends during a time interval of length dt, thus shares of stock pays δ( )S dt in dividends.

Change in Portfolio Value One share of stock pays δs dt in dividends during a time interval of length dt, thus shares of stock pays δ( )S dt in dividends. Using Itô s Lemma, the portfolio changes in value dy = d(c e,δ ( )S) δ( )S dt ( = (µ δ)sc e,δ S + 1 ) 2 σ2 S 2 C e,δ SS + Ce,δ t dt + σsc e,δ S dw (t) = ( ) ((µ δ)s dt + σs dw (t)) δ( )S dt ( (µ δ)s(c e,δ S ) + 1 ) 2 σ2 S 2 C e,δ SS + Ce,δ t δ( )S dt + σs(c e,δ S ) dw (t).

Eliminating Randomness Choose = C e,δ S and the portfolio obeys the stochastic differential equation: ( ) 1 dy = 2 σ2 S 2 C e,δ SS + Ce,δ t δ S C e,δ S dt. In the absence of arbitrage the change in the value of the portfolio should be the same as the interest earned by a equivalent amount of cash. dy = r(c e,δ ( )S) dt

Eliminating Randomness Choose = C e,δ S and the portfolio obeys the stochastic differential equation: ( ) 1 dy = 2 σ2 S 2 C e,δ SS + Ce,δ t δ S C e,δ S dt. In the absence of arbitrage the change in the value of the portfolio should be the same as the interest earned by a equivalent amount of cash. dy = r(c e,δ ( )S) dt Thus the Black-Scholes partial differential equation for the stock paying continuous dividends becomes r C e,δ = C e,δ t + 1 2 σ2 S 2 C e,δ SS + (r δ)s Ce,δ S.

Similarities with Non-Dividend-Paying Stocks Payoff of the call option at expiry: C e,δ (S, T ) = (S(T ) K ) +. Boundary condition at S = 0 is C e,δ (0, t) = 0. Boundary condition as S : C e,δ (S, t) = P e + S e δ(t t) r(t t) K e lim S Ce,δ (S, t) = lim S (P e + S e δ(t t) r(t K e t)) = S e δ(t t) K e r(t t).

IBVP: European Call with Continuous Dividends For (S, t) in [0, ) [0, T ], r C e,δ = C e,δ t + (r δ) S C e,δ S C e,δ (S, T ) = (S(T ) K ) + for S > 0, C e,δ (0, t) = 0 for 0 t < T, + 1 2 σ2 S 2 C e,δ SS C e,δ (S, t) = S e δ(t t) K e r(t t) as S.

Homework Read Sections 7.4, 7.5 Exercises: 10

Credits These slides are adapted from the textbook, An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics, 3rd edition, (2012). author: J. Robert Buchanan publisher: World Scientific Publishing Co. Pte. Ltd. address: 27 Warren St., Suite 401 402, Hackensack, NJ 07601 ISBN: 978-9814407441