Consequences of the 2013 FP7 call for proposals for the economy and employment in the European Union

Similar documents
EU-28 RECOVERED PAPER STATISTICS. Mr. Giampiero MAGNAGHI On behalf of EuRIC

Technical report on macroeconomic Member State results of the EUCO policy scenarios

Live Long and Prosper? Demographic Change and Europe s Pensions Crisis. Dr. Jochen Pimpertz Brussels, 10 November 2015

The costs of a non-innovative Europe: What can we learn and what can we expect from the simulation works

For further information, please see online or contact

EU BUDGET AND NATIONAL BUDGETS

Fiscal rules in Lithuania

European Advertising Business Climate Index Q4 2016/Q #AdIndex2017

NOTE. for the Interparliamentary Meeting of the Committee on Budgets

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, THE COUNCIL, THE EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COMMITTEE AND THE COMMITTEE OF THE REGIONS

Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD

EUROPA - Press Releases - Taxation trends in the European Union EU27 tax...of GDP in 2008 Steady decline in top corporate income tax rate since 2000

EMPLOYMENT RATE IN EU-COUNTRIES 2000 Employed/Working age population (15-64 years)

Consumer credit market in Europe 2013 overview

DG TAXUD. STAT/11/100 1 July 2011

PUBLIC PROCUREMENT INDICATORS 2011, Brussels, 5 December 2012

Enterprise Europe Network SME growth forecast

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018.

Electricity & Gas Prices in Ireland. Annex Business Electricity Prices per kwh 2 nd Semester (July December) 2016

EMPLOYMENT RATE Employed/Working age population (15 64 years)

Prospects for the review of the EU 2020 Strategy, the Juncker Plan and Cohesion Policy after 2020

CANADA EUROPEAN UNION

2017 Figures summary 1

STAT/12/ October Household saving rate fell in the euro area and remained stable in the EU27. Household saving rate (seasonally adjusted)

Investment in Germany and the EU

74 ECB THE 2012 MACROECONOMIC IMBALANCE PROCEDURE

Quarterly Financial Accounts Household net worth reaches new peak in Q Irish Household Net Worth

EMPLOYMENT RATE Employed/Working age population (15-64 years)

Macroeconomic scenarios for skill demand and supply projections, including dealing with the recession

THE IMPACT OF THE PUBLIC DEBT STRUCTURE IN THE EUROPEAN UNION MEMBER COUNTRIES ON THE POSSIBILITY OF DEBT OVERHANG

Raising the retirement age is the labour market ready for active ageing: evidence from EB and Eurofound research

EU KLEMS Growth and Productivity Accounts March 2011 Update of the November 2009 release

Courthouse News Service

Communication on the future of the CAP

Investment and Investment Finance. the EU and the Polish story. Debora Revoltella

Consumer Credit. Introduction. June, the 6th (2013)

Dividends from the EU to the US: The S-Corp and its Q-Sub. Peter Kirpensteijn 23 September 2016

Chart pack to council for cooperation on macroprudential policy

Investment in France and the EU

Quarterly Gross Domestic Product of Montenegro 3 rd quarter 2017

Updates and revisions of national SUTs for the November 2013 release of the WIOD

Taxation trends in the European Union Further increase in VAT rates in 2012 Corporate and top personal income tax rates inch up after long decline

Analysis of European Union Economy in Terms of GDP Components

EU Pension Trends. Matti Leppälä, Secretary General / CEO PensionsEurope 16 October 2014 Rovinj, Croatia

Measuring financial protection: an approach for the WHO European Region

PREZENTĀCIJAS NOSAUKUMS

A. INTRODUCTION AND FINANCING OF THE GENERAL BUDGET. EXPENDITURE Description Budget Budget Change (%)

Gender pension gap economic perspective

Aleksandra Dyba University of Economics in Krakow

EUREKA Programme A European Research Programme. > Not an EU-Programme (but complementarity and co-operation - ERA)

Key Trends of Energy Transition in the EU-28 Region

Lowest implicit tax rates on labour in Malta, on consumption in Spain and on capital in Lithuania

Introduction 283,602,000,000 ( 284 billion ) 71 billion 10.71%

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Accompanying the document

For further information, please see online or contact

Maintaining Adequate Protection in a Fiscally Constrained Environment Measuring the efficiency of social protection systems

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION

Assessing financial inclusion in Portugal from the central bank s perspective

Statistics: Fair taxation of the digital economy

Call for proposals. for civil society capacity building and monitoring of the implementation of national Roma integration strategies

Single Market Scoreboard

Report Penalties and measures imposed under the UCITS Directive in 2016 and 2017

New Member States Climate Protection and Economic Growth. Macroeconomic implications of a burden sharing non-ets GHG target in Bulgaria and Romania

Youth Integration into the labour market Barcelona, July 2011 Jan Hendeliowitz Director, Employment Region Copenhagen & Zealand Ministry of

Non-financial corporations - statistics on profits and investment

Borderline cases for salary, social contribution and tax

EIOPA Statistics - Accompanying note

The Eureka Eurostars Programme

Defining Issues. EU Audit Reforms: The Countdown Begins. April 2016, No Key Facts for U.S. Companies

EUROPEAN COMMISSION DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR RESEARCH & INNOVATION

EIOPA Statistics - Accompanying note

Governor of the Bank of Latvia

Bank resolution in the Swedish context

DYNAMICS OF BUDGETARY REVENUE IN THE CONDITIONS OF ROMANIAN INTEGRATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION - A CONSEQUENTLY OF THE TAX AND HARMONIZATION POLICY

Summary of the CEER Report on Investment Conditions in European Countries

How to complete a payment application form (NI)

THE ECONOMY AND THE BANKING SECTOR IN BULGARIA

May 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 6.9 bn euro 3.8 bn euro deficit for EU27

Reforming Policies for Regional Development: The European Perspective

THE ECONOMY AND THE BANKING SECTOR IN BULGARIA

First estimate for 2011 Euro area external trade deficit 7.7 bn euro bn euro deficit for EU27

The Tax Burden of Typical Workers in the EU

Social Protection and Social Inclusion in Europe Key facts and figures

June 2014 Euro area international trade in goods surplus 16.8 bn 2.9 bn surplus for EU28

Content. Allocation: Free allocation and auctioning. Experiences from the EU

Lithuania: in a wind of change. Robertas Dargis President of the Lithuanian Confederation of Industrialists

THE ECONOMY AND THE BANKING SECTOR IN BULGARIA

Growth, competitiveness and jobs: priorities for the European Semester 2013 Presentation of J.M. Barroso,

June 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 14.9 bn euro 0.4 bn euro surplus for EU27

OVERVIEW. The EU recovery is firming. Table 1: Overview - the winter 2014 forecast Real GDP. Unemployment rate. Inflation. Winter 2014 Winter 2014

August 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 6.6 bn euro 12.6 bn euro deficit for EU27

Macroeconomic overview SEE and Macedonia

Quarterly Gross Domestic Product of Montenegro 2st quarter 2016

Greek Parliamentary Budget Office Public Financial Management financial transparency and accountability

EIOPA Statistics - Accompanying note

International Seminar on Strengthening Public Investment and Managing Fiscal Risks from Public-Private Partnerships

Investment in Ireland and the EU

Quarterly Gross Domestic Product of Montenegro for period 1 st quarter rd quarter 2016

15 th ELD Government Experts Meeting 13 May 2015 Centre Borschette, Salle 1A. Commission Report under Article 18(2) ELD and REFIT Evaluation

MUTUALS IN EUROPE: WHO THEY ARE, WHAT THEY DO AND WHY THEY MATTER

Transcription:

Consequences of the 2013 FP7 call for proposals for the economy and employment in the European Union Paul Zagamé, Arnaud Fougeyrollas Pierre le Mouël ERASME, Paris, 31 May 2012 1

Executive Summary We present here the impact of the FP7 2013 budget of 8 billion. Our assessment uses the NEMESIS system of detailed macroeconomic models developed under the European Socio Economic Sciences and Humanities programme (SSH) 1. The FP7 call is expected to contribute to EU research and innovation by way of 8 billion grants. The private sector, with a leverage effect of 0.9, will invest 1.9 for every 1 of EU grant. The public laboratories will invest 1.5 for every 1 grant. The mean leverage effect, 0.74, is in line with the estimates in the econometric literature. This means that, for 1 grant, 0.74 more are invested. All told, 13.9 billion will be spent on R&D and innovation. Assuming a 13.9 billion investment, and if we suppose for convenience that R&D expenditure is concentrated in a single year i.e. a one-off shock then employment could be expected to increase in that one year by more than 210 000. But these newly created jobs would be transitory because the direct shock of R&D and innovation expenditure is itself transitory. Also, the effects of this shock pass through different phases that can diminish employment transitorily. This is the case for the restructuring phase, when innovation and productivity gains appear without any immediate increase in demand for goods, something that takes time to work through after a price reduction. But the diffusion of innovation and the increase in domestic demand and competitiveness will again stimulate employment. Ultimately, what is important is the cumulative effect of this one-off shock. For employment, it is the number of persons working during a period of time, which must be expressed in persons-year or the so called job-equivalents: The cumulative effect is 569 000 persons-year for the 15 years period, after the policy is implemented. The cumulative GDP represents the full value of the wealth created by the initial R&D expenditure. Here it is 75 billion after 15 years. Table 1: Impacts from a one-off shock induced by the FP7 2013 call for proposals EU investment in research ( billion) 8 Total investment in research ( billion) 13.9 Jobs created short term (persons-year) 210000 Cumulative job creation for the 15 years period (persons-year) 569000 Cumulative extra GDP for the 15 years period ( billion) 75 1 See the DEMETER, SIMPATIC, WIOD and NEUJOB research projects - http://ec.europa.eu/research/socialsciences/index_en.html 2

The impact of the FP7 2013 call for proposals, worth 8 billion, has been assessed using the NEMESIS system of macro econometric models. The results must not be considered an incontrovertible truth, but merely as certain elements which are open to comment. Nevertheless, they represent a serious attempt to analyse the impact of research and innovation funding, by using a coherent framework based on national accounting, a set of theoretical assumptions and numerical evidence linked to the state of art of research on the Economics of R&D, and up-to-date simulation techniques. Compared with last year s evaluation (FP 7 Call in 2012), the novelty lies in two major points. The volume is up from 7 billion to 8 billion, i.e. an increase of about 14 % in nominal value and of 12 % in real value. The new crisis, the scale of which was not foreseen in June 2011, increases the GDP gap (between GDP forecasts before the crisis and current forecasts) and then, if we follow some of the results of the DEMETER project, lowers the opportunity costs of R&D policies. 2 This document is organised as follows: We start with the main mechanisms we need to consider for R&D assessment with modelling, before presenting in four successive phases the effects on employment and economic activity of the 2013 call. The cumulative effects on job creation and GDP are then presented. 2 Fougeyrollas A, Haddad P., Le Hir B., Le Mouël P, Zagamé P., 2010, R&D effort during the crisis and beyond: some insights provided by the NEMESIS model simulations, Demeter project, European Commission publication. 3

1- Modelling for R&D assessment To assess R&D policy, we must use detailed macro sectoral models that describe the effect of FP funding for every activity. Three main mechanisms are involved: the leverage effect that enables us to determine the R&D expenditure arising from 1 public funding; the knowledge spillovers that describe knowledge transfers to other sectors and other countries, and that will determine the knowledge variables; and the economic performance of knowledge. 1.1- Leverage effect The leverage effect or crowding-in effect describes the multiplier effect that 1 of grant has on R&D expenditure. Econometrics gives some results, albeit mainly at a European or macro national level, more rarely at a sectoral level. This leverage effect depends on several conditions that determine expectations in terms of R&D returns. One main concern is about comparing the leverage effects of different sources of grants, e.g. regional, national or European. At a European level, research grants might induce more leverage effects that national or regional ones. Network effects, transfer of best practices and higher returns could explain the difference. Many of the new initiatives on joint technology projects, research programming and ERA creation are aimed at increasing this leverage effect. The Risk-Sharing Finance Facility (RSFF) uses and this is an innovation debt-based finance to complement FP7 funding. The risk is shared between the European Commission and the European Investment Bank. The first evaluations show that the leverage effect of the RSFF is very substantial. According to Soete (2010), since the creation of RSFF in June 2007, and up to December 2009, 0.5 billion of FP7 assigned to the RSFF has, with the EIB support of 0.5 billion, generated more than 16 billion of R&D expenditure. Any FP assessment exercises must take into account this RSFF procedure even if it concerns only a small part of FP7, and more generally make a sensibility analysis of results to the leverage adopted Taking into account recent literature results, we adopted for the present simulation of the 2013 call the following leverage effect: 0.5 for public R&D investments (40 % of the 8 billion funding) and 0.9 for the private sector. In mean terms, these assumptions give a leverage effect of about 0.74, which means that 1 EU investment from the 2012 FP7 budget generates 1.74 of research and innovation expenditure. This 0.74 figure is quite compatible with the results of the econometric literature, which indicates a leverage effect for the private sector of between 0.7 and 1.7. To sum up then, the 8 billion FP 2013 funding will generate 13.9 billion R&D and innovation expenditure. 4

1.2- Knowledge spillovers A second important matter is knowledge spillovers. Impacts of innovation in the model depend not only on R&D expenditure of the sector, but also on the knowledge spillovers coming from other sectors, other countries and public research centres. Quite a lot has been written about knowledge spillovers. For NEMESIS, we adapted the Johnson matrix (Johnson 2002) on technological flows based on patent data for inter-sectoral spillovers, while international spillovers were based on bilateral trade. During the DEMETER project, new knowledge matrices were built, using PATSTAT database and the Yale concordance matrix, and making it possible to describe inter-sectoral spillovers directly at international level. This work was based on the contribution of UNU-MERIT, 3 under the DEMETER Project, and was extended to General Purpose Technologies (GPT), used by almost all the sectors, e.g. the ICT, and a main carrier for knowledge externalities. 1.3- Economic performance The economic performance of knowledge was calibrated on econometric work initiated by Griliches and Mairesse (1983). Their work was adapted to NEMESIS, with past data being calibrated to take into account the impacts of spillovers and of product quality (Brécart et alii, 2006). Of course, these mechanisms play a major role in terms of the results. We assume in this document that the economic performance of the FP7 2013 funded projects is the same as for all other projects. This is a cautious assumption given that some studies argue that European funded R&D is more efficient. 1.4- Inter-sectoral and macroeconomic feedback in NEMESIS The last point concerns macroeconomics. Having assumed that innovation increases productivity, quality and then demand at a sectoral level, we must take into account the inter-sectoral and macroeconomic feedback. The NEMESIS model track is hybrid in the sense that it is the resultant of pure top-down forces, mainly savings and consumption, linked to wages, employment prices and profit, and bottom-up forces that come from the interactions between 30 heterogeneous sectors in terms of dynamics and R&D effort. All these forces determine the competitiveness, growth and employment that are the outcome of implementing R&D policies. These results are available at national and sectoral level for every European country. 3 www.merit.unu.edu. 5

2- The four phases of effects induced by 2013 FP funding Let us now look at the four different phases of effects of the 8 billion grants for the 2013 FP7. 2.1- Implementation The two main questions in terms of the implementation of FP concern the time profile and the allocation of grants. All the grant of 8 billion is handed over in the first year in a one-off shock. This is a simplification, because all the expenditure is in fact spent over at least three years, but making this simplification enables us to follow, year by year, the impact of this transitory grant, global effect of which will be assessed cumulatively. The allocation of FP7 funding between Member States is assumed to be as observed at the beginning of the FP7 (see Table 2). The allocation of research and innovation funding between economic sectors of the model in each country is based on the grandfathering principle, i.e. proportionate to the level of R&D expenditure in each sector. Grandfathering allocation tends to be virtual in that it does not necessarily accord with the current criteria for funds allocation in the FP. Table 2: FP7 allocation (source: DG Research) FP7 FP7 Austria 3.00 % Italy 11.50 % Belgium 4.70 % Latvia 0.10 % Bulgaria 0.50 % Lithuania 0.30 % Cyprus 0.30 % Luxembourg 0.10 % Czech- Republic 1.20 % Malta 0.10 % Denmark 2.30 % Netherlands 6.70 % Estonia 0.40 % Poland 1.90 % Finland 2.80 % Portugal 1.70 % France 11.60 % Romania 0.90 % Germany 18.00 % Slovakia 0.40 % Greece 3.50 % Slovenia 0.80 % Hungary 1.10 % Spain 7.70 % Ireland 1.30 % Sweden 4.30 % United Kingdom 12.70 % 2.2- R&D allocation phase The 8 billion grants, with a leverage effect of 0.74, generate 13.9 billion R&D expenditure. Figure 1 shows that GDP grows from year one on a scale slightly below the shock effect. In fact, R&D investment consists mainly in physical investment (research hardware) and in jobs, which result in 6

higher pay and consumption. During the first three years, there are only demand effects, because the additional R&D has not yet achieved its full impact. This translates into higher prices and imports, which upsets the external balance somewhat and causes the multiplier to leak. If the instant multiplier is smaller than one, the sum of the effects on the first three years is greater than unity, which is consistent with what is expected. 210 000 jobs are created in the first year; the number then falls back almost completely, as does the GDP, since the shock is one-off. Figure 1: One-off shock across all sectors (% gap from central account) 0.14 0.12 0.1 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 GDP Exports Imports Investment Consumption 0-0.02 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 t+6 t+7 t+8 t+9 t+10 t+11 t+12 t+13 t+14 t+15-0.04-0.06 Figure 2: Employment trend (% gap from central account) 0.14 0.12 0.1 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0-0.02 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 t+6 t+7 t+8 t+9 t+10 t+11 t+12 t+13 t+14 t+15-0.04 7

2.3- Innovation and restructuring phase R&D then leads to a phase of innovation and restructuring in t+3, which increases labour productivity, reduces production costs and pushes down prices. However, the increase in demand will take time to work through, so during this phase employment will fall below business-as usuallevel, because of productivity gains. 2.4- Diffusion and increase in demand phase During this phase, lower prices and improvements in quality will help boost domestic demand and improve competitiveness and the external balance. Thus, between t+5 and t+10 the GDP continues to grow above the BAU level due to higher exports, lower imports and increased consumption. Job creation is around + 0.02 % in t+10, which is small compared to GDP growth, but this is explained by higher innovation-induced productivity growth. In contrast, spending on research and innovation results in higher GDP and competitiveness, which may reduce the deficits of Member States. 2.5- The obsolescence of innovation phase With the scrapping of knowledge capital, the effects of innovation will decrease over time, and so GDP and its components will decrease, as will employment. In t+15 the residual effect will be much diminished, but will not be negligible: +0.02 % jobs, and + 0.02 % GDP. 3- The cumulative socio-economic effects for the next 15 years After the dynamic description of impacts year by year, it is important to calculate the cumulative effects associated with this one-off shock. If we look at the time t+15 on Figure 1, we can observe in two distinct ways the effect on employment, and on GDP and its components. The first is the slack between, for instance, employment resulting from research and innovation grants and the baseline without grants. What we can see on the graph is that this effect depends on the phase in which it is observed. It is of course very important at the beginning when the R&D expenditure takes place. We have already commented on the chain of these different phases. But the important thing, when we comment on the results, is to compare the cost for the European Commission ( 8 billion) to the cumulative jobs or the cumulative GDP created. The cumulative jobs created are the area between the employment curves and the time axis. It must be expressed in terms of persons-years: it is a number of persons working during a period of time. In addition, all the financing demand on the FP must be associated with a work plan presented in person-months. 8

The cumulative GDP represents all the wealth created by the initial FP funding. It is interesting to calculate the multiplier effect of this expenditure, to see what value 1 of FP can create. If we look at Figure 1, we can see that almost all the components of GDP decrease after t+15, the obsolescence effect grows and then the benefits of research and innovation fade away. Of course, that situation is purely virtual in the sense that other FP expenditures after 2013 will take over. For these reasons, we decided to give the cumulative effects after 15 years. Of course the figures would have been higher after 30 years or more, and then the results are an underestimation of all the effects displayed by the one-off shock policy. Cumulative job creation in 2027 (t+15) is 569 000 persons-year. Over the 15 years period, this represents in average 38 000 jobs more than in a situation without the FP7 2013 call. After 15 years, the wealth created came to 75 billion; after 20 years it came to 86 billion. At this time, the multiplier effect of R&D expenditures is 86/12.9, about 6.3. If we were to extend the simulation horizon to 25 years, the multiplier would have converged to a figure between 6.5 and 7, 6.5 being the figure generally calculated for the multiplier effect of a sustained shock after 25 years, 4 equivalent to the multiplier of a cumulative GDP reported for the one-off shock. 4- References Brécard D., Fougeyrollas A., Lemiale L., Le Mouël P, Zagamé P., 2006: Macroeconomic consequences of European research policy: Prospects of the Nemesis model in the year 2030, Research Policy 35 (2006), 910 924. Fougeyrollas A., Le Mouël P. and Zagamé P., 2001: Semi-endogenous growth in a computable general equilibrium approach, Sixth Congress of the Society of Computational Economics, Yale University. Fougeyrollas A, Haddad P., Le Hir B., Le Mouël P, Zagamé P., 2010, R&D effort during the crisis and beyond: some insights provided by the NEMESIS model simulations, Demeter project, European Commission publication. Fougeyrollas A, Le Mouël P, Zagamé P., 2010: Consequences of the 2010 FP7 budget on European economy and employment, Demeter project, European Commission publication. Griliches Z., Mairesse J., 1983: Comparing productivity growth: An exploration of French and US industrial and firm data, European Economic Review, 21(1-2), 89-119. Soete, L., 2010: The costs of a non-innovative Europe: Challenges ahead, Demeter project, European Commission Publication. Zagamé P., 2010: The costs of a non-innovative Europe: what can we learn and what can we expect from the simulations works, European Commission publication. 4 See Brécart et alii, 2006. 9