Random Walks vs Random Variables. The Random Walk Model. Simple rate of return to an asset is: Simple rate of return

Similar documents
Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell. Midterm 2014 Suggested Solutions. TA: B. B. Deng

Monetary Economics Measuring Asset Returns. Gerald P. Dwyer Fall 2015

Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell Midterm 2014

Economics 424/Applied Mathematics 540. Final Exam Solutions

Washington University Fall Economics 487. Project Proposal due Monday 10/22 Final Project due Monday 12/3

Example 1 of econometric analysis: the Market Model

GARCH Models. Instructor: G. William Schwert

Economics 483. Midterm Exam. 1. Consider the following monthly data for Microsoft stock over the period December 1995 through December 1996:

JZ Assignment Page 1 of 5

Final Exam Suggested Solutions

Global Journal of Finance and Banking Issues Vol. 5. No Manu Sharma & Rajnish Aggarwal PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS OF HEDGE FUND INDICES

Washington University Fall Economics 487

Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2007, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Midterm

Empirical Asset Pricing for Tactical Asset Allocation

Financial Econometrics: Problem Set # 3 Solutions

Return Volatility, Market Microstructure Noise, and Institutional Investors: Evidence from High Frequency Market

Chapter 4 Level of Volatility in the Indian Stock Market

The Capital Asset Pricing Model CAPM: benchmark model of the cost of capital

Two Hours. Mathematical formula books and statistical tables are to be provided THE UNIVERSITY OF MANCHESTER. 22 January :00 16:00

The Estimation Model for Measuring Performance of Stock Mutual Funds Based on ARCH / GARCH Model

Define risk, risk aversion, and riskreturn

Conditional Heteroscedasticity and Testing of the Granger Causality: Case of Slovakia. Michaela Chocholatá

Midterm Exam. b. What are the continuously compounded returns for the two stocks?

Gloria Gonzalez-Rivera Forecasting For Economics and Business Solutions Manual

Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2007, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Final Exam

Financial Data Analysis, WS08/09. Roman Liesenfeld, University of Kiel 1

The Norwegian State Equity Ownership

Rationale. Learning about return and risk from the historical record and beta estimation. T Bills and Inflation

Donald Trump's Random Walk Up Wall Street

Financial Time Series and Their Characteristics

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

Econometric Models for the Analysis of Financial Portfolios

HowBehavioralAspectsAffectMarketEfficiency-EvidencefromKSE100Index

Appendixes Appendix 1 Data of Dependent Variables and Independent Variables Period

Indian Institute of Management Calcutta. Working Paper Series. WPS No. 797 March Implied Volatility and Predictability of GARCH Models

2.4 STATISTICAL FOUNDATIONS

CHAPTER 5 MARKET LEVEL INDUSTRY LEVEL AND FIRM LEVEL VOLATILITY

OPTIMAL RISKY PORTFOLIOS- ASSET ALLOCATIONS. BKM Ch 7

LAMPIRAN PERHITUNGAN EVIEWS

Research Article The Volatility of the Index of Shanghai Stock Market Research Based on ARCH and Its Extended Forms

Financial Econometrics

Booth School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2014, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Midterm

Problem Set 4 Answer Key

What is the Expected Return on a Stock?

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Tuesday October 6 Portfolio Allocation Mean-Variance Approach

Prerequisites for modeling price and return data series for the Bucharest Stock Exchange

Lecture 1: Empirical Properties of Returns

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

Financial Econometrics

DATABASE AND RESEARCH METHODOLOGY

Chapter 13 Return, Risk, and Security Market Line

CHAPTER 5. Introduction to Risk, Return, and the Historical Record INVESTMENTS BODIE, KANE, MARCUS. McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Supervisor, Prof. Ph.D. Moisă ALTĂR. MSc. Student, Octavian ALEXANDRU

Ch. 8 Risk and Rates of Return. Return, Risk and Capital Market. Investment returns

Derivation Of The Capital Asset Pricing Model Part I - A Single Source Of Uncertainty

John Hull, Risk Management and Financial Institutions, 4th Edition

Are Market Neutral Hedge Funds Really Market Neutral?

VOLATILITY. Time Varying Volatility

9. Appendixes. Page 73 of 95

The intervalling effect bias in beta: A note

Brief Sketch of Solutions: Tutorial 1. 2) descriptive statistics and correlogram. Series: LGCSI Sample 12/31/ /11/2009 Observations 2596

MASTER DEGREE PROJECT

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Quantitative Portfolio Theory & Performance Analysis

A Generalized Measure of Riskiness

Does Systemic Risk in the Financial Sector Predict Future Economic Downturns?

Yafu Zhao Department of Economics East Carolina University M.S. Research Paper. Abstract

Research Article Estimating Time-Varying Beta of Price Limits and Its Applications in China Stock Market

CHAPTER 8 Risk and Rates of Return

σ e, which will be large when prediction errors are Linear regression model

State Ownership at the Oslo Stock Exchange

Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2007, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Hydrology 4410 Class 29. In Class Notes & Exercises Mar 27, 2013

Exploring Financial Instability Through Agent-based Modeling Part 2: Time Series, Adaptation, and Survival

Financial Markets. Laurent Calvet. John Lewis Topic 13: Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)

OVERVIEW OF FINANCIAL RISK ASSESSMENT. A thesis submitted to the. Kent State University Honors College. in partial fulfillment of the requirements

FINANCIAL MODELING OF FOREIGN EXCHANGE RATES USING THE US DOLLAR AND THE EURO EXCHANGE RATES: A PEDAGOGICAL NOTE

Sensex Realized Volatility Index (REALVOL)

FIN 6160 Investment Theory. Lecture 7-10

Fin285a:Computer Simulations and Risk Assessment Section 7.1 Modeling Volatility: basic models Daníelson, ,

Analysis of the Influence of the Annualized Rate of Rentability on the Unit Value of the Net Assets of the Private Administered Pension Fund NN

Modeling Uncertainty in Financial Markets

Time-variation of CAPM betas across market volatility regimes for Book-to-market and Momentum portfolios

Chapter 6 Part 3 October 21, Bootstrapping

Does Idiosyncratic Risk Really Matter?

Example of a model for non-stationary variables: Lead-Lag Relationships btw Spot and Futures prices

Additional Case Study One: Risk Analysis of Home Purchase

Asset Allocation with Exchange-Traded Funds: From Passive to Active Management. Felix Goltz

Monthly Seasonality in the New Zealand Stock Market

Lecture 5a: ARCH Models

Financial Risk Forecasting Chapter 1 Financial markets, prices and risk

Fundamentals of Finance

Chapter. Return, Risk, and the Security Market Line. McGraw-Hill/Irwin. Copyright 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.

The histogram should resemble the uniform density, the mean should be close to 0.5, and the standard deviation should be close to 1/ 12 =

IMPACT OF MACROECONOMIC VARIABLE ON STOCK MARKET RETURN AND ITS VOLATILITY

Global Volatility and Forex Returns in East Asia

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2010, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay Solutions to Final Exam

A market risk model for asymmetric distributed series of return

P2.T5. Market Risk Measurement & Management. Bruce Tuckman, Fixed Income Securities, 3rd Edition

Portfolio Risk Management and Linear Factor Models

Transcription:

The Random Walk Model Assume the logarithm of 'with dividend' price, ln P(t), changes by random amounts through time: ln P(t) = ln P(t-1) + µ + ε(it) (1) where: P(t) is the sum of the price plus dividend payments made in period t, µ = E {ln[p(t)/p(t-1)]} is the expected continuously compounded return, and Random Walks vs Random Variables If changes in (log) stock prices are random, then (log) price levels follow a random walk Distinction between random variables and random walks is confusing for many (most) students ε(it) is the random change in the stock price from period t-1 to period t Simple rate of return to an asset is: R(t) = [P(t) - P(t-1) + D(t)] / P(t-1) (2) which is close to the continuously compounded return r(t) for small values of the returns Simple rate of return Equation (1) can be rewritten in terms of returns: r(t) = µ + ε(it) (3) where the 'unexpected' return in period t is the error term ε(it) As with the errors from regression models (e.g., APS 402), the errors should be random Some Properties of the Random Walk Model The mean and variance of returns are proportional to the length of the measurement interval k E ln[p(t) / P(t-k)] = k µ Var ln[p(t) / P(t-k)] = k σ² (4a) (4b) More Properties of the Random Walk Model Autocorrelation tests on returns are equivalent to testing whether the errors are indeed random corr[r(t), R(t-k)] is the autocorrelation coefficient at lag k Most evidence finds that common stock returns have very small autocorrelations for daily or monthly data for many lags k thus, these tests are consistent with the random walk model for stock prices Professor Schwert 1-6 Spring 1997

40000 30000 20000 10000 Prediction of Dow Jones Industrial Average (Random Walk Model, 1997 = 7000) [Mean = 3.0%, Std Dev = 18.0%] 0 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 40000 30000 20000 10000 Prediction of Dow Jones Industrial Average (Random Walk Model, 1997=7000) [Mean = 7.0%, Std Dev = 15.1%] 0 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 Based on historical estimates, 1834-96 Low (-2 sd) High (+2 sd) Based on historical estimates, 1946-96 Low (-2 sd) High (+2 sd) U.S. Monthly Stock Returns, 1834-1996 Volatility of Monthly US Stock Returns, 1885-1996 Percent Return per Month 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% -10% -20% -30% Percent Return per Month 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% (Based on Daily Returns Within the Month) -40% 0% 1834 1839 1844 1849 1854 1859 1864 1869 1874 1879 1884 1889 1894 1899 1904 1909 1914 1919 1924 1929 1934 1939 1944 1949 1954 1959 1964 1969 1974 1979 1984 1989 1994 Percentage of Returns 1885 1890 1895 1900 1905 1910 1915 1920 1925 1930 1935 1940 1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% Histograms of Monthly US Stock Returns, 1834-1996 -5-4 -3-2 -1.5-1 -0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 3 4 5 >5 Standard Deviations from the Mean 1834-1996 1834-1925 1926-1945 1946-1996 Distribution of Stock Returns A statistic which measures the 'fat-tailedness' of a sample is the studentized range, SR: SR = (Max - Min) / Standard Deviation Jarque-Bera statistic (in Eviews) measures whether the skewness & kurtosis statistics are consistent with a Normal distribution skewness should equal 0 and kurtosis should equal 3 Professor Schwert 7-12 Spring 1997

Short-term Interest Rates, 1834-1995 Avg 0.79% 0.41% 0.37% Std 4.89% 1.30% 0.24% Max 38.28% 8.89% 1.67% Min -29.00% -7.35% -0.02% SR 13.75 12.47 7.10 T-stat 7.17 12.77 68.08 Short-term Interest Rates, 1834-1925 Avg 0.67% 0.46% 0.42% Std 4.36% 1.04% 0.20% Max 17.59% 6.92% 1.67% Min -24.37% -7.35% 0.13% SR 9.62 13.75 7.54 T-stat 5.08 12.87 68.78 Short-term Interest Rates, 1926-1945 Avg 0.85% 0.29% 0.09% Std 8.06% 1.32% 0.13% Max 38.28% 5.06% 0.43% Min -29.00% -7.83% -0.02% SR 8.35 9.75 3.56 T-stat 1.63 3.44 10.93 Short-term Interest Rates, 1946-1995 Avg 1.01% 0.48% 0.38% Std 4.08% 1.72% 0.26% Max 16.53% 9.84% 1.35% Min -21.81% -7.20% 0.03% SR 9.40 9.90 5.18 T-stat 6.07 6.90 34.83 Returns Over More than One Period When analyzing returns over more the one period it is convenient to use continuously compounded returns, r(t) = ln [1+R(t)], since these returns add up over time Returns Over More than One Period Thus, the k-period return [P(t+k)/P(t)]-1, is just [1+R(t+1)][1+R(t+2)]...[1+R(t+k)] - 1 = R(t+1) + R(t+2) +... + R(t+k) + cross-product terms These cross-product terms can be important, however Professor Schwert 13-18 Spring 1997

Returns to Different Assets Returns Over More than One Period Period Asset A Asset B Asset C 1.10.20.30 2.10.00 -.10 Average 2-period Return.10.10.10 Assets with the highest standard deviation of simple returns have the lowest terminal value, for a given level of average simple returns Value of $1 Investment in Period 0 at the end of Period 2 $ 1.21 $ 1.20 $ 1.17 Simple returns are easiest to use when measuring the returns to many different securities at the same point in time Define a portfolio return as the weighted average of the returns to the N securities in the portfolio: R(pt) = Σ w(it) R(it) where Σ w(it) = 1. The portfolio weights w(it) represent the proportion of wealth invested in asset i at the beginning of period t. If an investor put equal dollar amounts in each of N securities, this would be an equal-weighted portfolio w(it) = w(i) = 1 / N If one invested in proportion to the outstanding market value (i.e., price times shares outstanding) of each of N securities, this would be a value-weighted portfolio w(it) = value of asset i / total value of all N assets The return to an equal-weighted portfolio is the average return to the assets in the portfolio in period t, so it is easy to compute but it is hard to maintain an equal-weighted portfolio through time you must rebalance every period as the value of the holdings change Professor Schwert 19-24 Spring 1997

The return to a value-weighted portfolio is difficult to compute because the value-weights change every period but it is easy to maintain a value-weighted portfolio it requires no rebalancing (except to account for new issues or retirements of securities) The S&P 500 and the CRSP value-weighted portfolios are examples of value-weighted portfolios By construction, a value-weighted portfolio places larger weight on large firms therefore smaller weight on small firms relative to an equal-weighted portfolio A comparison of the returns to the CRSP valueand equal-weighted portfolios of all NYSE stocks from 1926-95 shows this effect for 1926-95, the mean monthly returns are.96% and 1.31% for the value and equal-weighted portfolios the monthly standard deviations of returns are 5.53% and 7.61% Thus, the risks and returns to small stocks are probably higher than for large stocks. Distribution of CRSP Value & Equal-weighted Stock Returns, 1926-1995 Cont Comp Simple Simple CRSP VW CRSP VW CRSP EW Returns Returns Returns Avg 0.80% 0.96% 1.31% Std 5.52% 5.53% 7.61% Max 32.41% 38.28% 65.51% Min -34.25% -29.00% -31.23% SR 12.08 12.16 12.71 t-test 4.22 5.03 4.98 Distribution of CRSP Value & Equal-weighted Stock Returns, 1926-1945 Cont Comp Simple Simple CRSP VW CRSP VW CRSP EW Returns Returns Returns Avg 0.53% 0.85% 1.64% Std 7.99% 8.04% 11.66% Max 32.41% 38.28% 65.51% Min -34.25% -29.00% -31.23% SR 8.34 8.37 8.29 t-test 1.02 1.63 2.18 Distribution of CRSP Value & Equal-weighted Stock Returns, 1946-1995 Cont Comp Simple Simple CRSP VW CRSP VW CRSP EW Returns Returns Returns Avg 0.91% 1.00% 1.18% Std 4.13% 4.12% 5.16% Max 15.33% 16.56% 29.92% Min -25.48% -22.49% -27.10% SR 9.89 9.48 11.05 t-test 5.43 5.97 5.58 Professor Schwert 25-30 Spring 1997

Market model regression: R(it) = α(i) + β(i) R(mt) + ε(it), t = 1,...,T (5) where R(it) is the return to asset i and R(mt) is the return to the "market" portfolio of assets in period t is a time series regression model the slope coefficient β(i) ("beta") is a measure of the relative nondiversifiable risk of the asset which is the dependent variable in the regression [R(it)] as part of the portfolio which is the independent variable [R(mt)] Weighted average beta Σ β(i) β equals 1 by construction for the set of assets i which make up the regressor portfolio [R(mt)] Weighted average intercept Σ α(i) α in the market model regression (5) must equal 0 by construction If the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) is true, then the intercept α(i) = [1 β(i)] R(f) where R(f) is the risk-free rate of return so betas β(i) > 1 would typically be associated with α(i) < 0 Table below shows the market model regression using the CRSP value-weighted portfolio as the regressor, R(et) = α + β R(vt) + ε(it) where R(et) is the simple return to the equal-weighted portfolio and R(vt) is the simple return to the value-weighted portfolio in period t Market Model: Equal-weighted Returns on Value-weighted Returns 1926-95 1926-45 1946-95 α 0.10% 0.49% 0.08% β 1.257 1.365 1.095 t(β=1) 5.69 5.71 2.57 R².835.886.762 Risk Premium Market Model: CAPM Test for the Equal-weighted CRSP Portfolio 1926-95 1926-45 1946-95 α 0.18% 0.52% 0.11% t(α=0) 1.86 2.23 1.12 β 1.258 1.366 1.094 t(β=1) 5.72 5.73 2.58 Professor Schwert 31-36 Spring 1997