Implications of Fiscal Austerity for U.S. Monetary Policy

Similar documents
The U.S. Economy: An Optimistic Outlook, But With Some Important Risks

Monetary Policy as the Economy Approaches the Fed s Dual Mandate

Exploring the Economy s Progress and Outlook

The Economic Outlook and Unconventional Monetary Policy

Estimating Key Economic Variables: The Policy Implications

One Policymaker s Wait for Better Economic Data

Implications of Low Inflation Rates for Monetary Policy

Past, Present and Future: The Macroeconomy and Federal Reserve Actions

Monetary Policymaking in Today s Environment: Finding Policy Space in a Low-Rate World

Monetary, Fiscal, and Financial Stability Policy Tools: Are We Equipped for the Next Recession?

Reviewing Monetary Policy Frameworks

Improving the Outlook with Better Monetary Policy. Bloomington, Eden Prairie, Edina and Richfield Chambers of Commerce Edina, Minnesota March 27, 2013

Economic Outlook, January 2016 Jeffrey M. Lacker President, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

Making Monetary Policy: Rules, Benchmarks, Guidelines, and Discretion

Views on the Economy and Price-Level Targeting

Current Economic Conditions and Selected Forecasts

Goal-Based Monetary Policy Report 1

The Economic Recovery and Monetary Policy: Taking the First Step Towards the Long Run

Clarifying the Objectives of Monetary Policy 1

Some Thoughts on the Current Economic Situation

Philip Lowe: Changing relative prices and the structure of the Australian economy

Economic Outlook and Forecast

Financial Stability: The Role of Real Estate Values

INFLATION REPORT PRESS CONFERENCE. Thursday 10 th May Opening Remarks by the Governor

Data Dependence and U.S. Monetary Policy. Remarks by. Richard H. Clarida. Vice Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

William C Dudley: A bit better, but very far from best US economic outlook and the challenges facing the Federal Reserve

Monetary Policy and the Economic Outlook: A Fine Balancing Act

of the University of Chicago Booth School of Business Narayana Kocherlakota President Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

FOMC Statement: December th

Policy Alternatives for a Return to Full Employment in Spain

Some Considerations for U.S. Monetary Policy Normalization

Finland falling further behind euro area growth

Economic ProjEctions for

Views on the Economic and Policy Outlook. Raphael Bostic President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Report Documentation Page Form Approved OMB No Public reporting burden for the collection of information is estimated to average 1 hour per re

Spring Forecast: slowly recovering from a protracted recession

Brian P Sack: Managing the Federal Reserve s balance sheet

The U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy. Esther L. George President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

Thoughts about the Outlook

Haruhiko Kuroda: Japan s economy and monetary policy

Low Inflation and the Symmetry of the 2 Percent Target

Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments

Balance-Sheet Adjustments and the Global Economy

Are we on the road to recovery?

MINUTES OF THE MONETARY POLICY COMMITTEE MEETING 4 AND 5 NOVEMBER 2009

Monetary Policy Frameworks

Brian P Sack: The SOMA portfolio at $2.654 trillion

Lars Heikensten: Monetary policy and the economic situation

The Outlook for the U.S. Economy March Summary View. The Current State of the Economy

Thomas Jordan: Challenges facing the Swiss National Bank

PRESENTATION BY PROF. E. TUMUSIIME-MUTEBILE, GOVERNOR, BANK OF UGANDA, TO THE NRM RETREAT, KYANKWANZI, JANUARY

Lars Heikensten: The Swedish economy and monetary policy

Central Bank Balance Sheets: Misconceptions and Realities

Threading the Needle. Esther L. George President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

Economic Outlook, January 2015 January 9, Jeffrey M. Lacker President Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

The Taylor Rule: A benchmark for monetary policy?

Ashdon Investment Management Q ECONOMIC COMMENTARY

BANK OF FINLAND ARTICLES ON THE ECONOMY

Global Macroeconomic Monthly Review

Ashdon Investment Management Q ECONOMIC COMMENTARY

Monetary Policy in a New Environment: The U.S. Experience

INFLATION AND THE ECONOMIC OUTLOOK By Darryl R. Francis, President. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking

APPENDIX: Country analyses

2014 Annual Review & Outlook

Global Economic Outlook January 2015

The Economic Outlook

Legal services sector forecasts

Gauging Current Conditions:

Erdem Başçi: Recent economic and financial developments in Turkey

THE NEW ECONOMY RECESSION: ECONOMIC SCORECARD 2001

Japan's Economy and Monetary Policy

Notes Numbers in the text and tables may not add up to totals because of rounding. Unless otherwise indicated, years referred to in describing the bud

Gauging Current Conditions: The Economic Outlook and Its Impact on Workers Compensation

Mario Draghi: Monetary policy and the outlook for the economy

Monetary, Fiscal, and Financial Stability Policy Tools: Are We Equipped for the Next Recession?

A Story of Economic Progress

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking

A Discussion of Key Secular Trends, Economic Conditions and Monetary Policy

April 4, Euro Area: Inflation. ECB Forecasts. Northern Trust Global Economic Research 50 South LaSalle Chicago, Illinois northerntrust.

FINAL EXAM: Macro 302 Winter 2014

REMARKS BY JAVIER GUZMÁN CALAFELL, DEPUTY GOVERNOR AT THE BANCO DE MÉXICO, ON MEXICO S MONETARY POLICY AND ECONOMIC OUTLOOK.

FISCAL POLICY* Chapt er. Key Concepts

Analysis of Congressional Budget Office s August 2012 Updateof the Budget and Economic Outlook

INFLATION REPORT PRESS CONFERENCE. Thursday 8 th February Opening Remarks by the Governor

Gauging Current Economic Momentum. Dennis Lockhart President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Normalizing Monetary Policy

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s

Monetary Policymaking in Today s Environment: Finding Policy Space in a Low-Rate World

Ben S Bernanke: The US economic outlook

The Long Hard Slog BY JASON M. THOMAS

Estimating Key Economic Variables: The Policy Implications

Svante Öberg: Potential GDP, resource utilisation and monetary policy

Why are bond yields and volatility so low?

Leumi. Global Economics Monthly Review. Arie Tal, Research Economist. May 8, The Finance Division, Economics Department. leumiusa.

CBIA and the Metro Hartford Alliance Economic Summit & Outlook 2013 Recent Developments in the US Economy

Inflation and Monetary Policy in Extraordinary Times

2012 Economic Outlook: Overview of U.S. Economy. Presented by: Mark Evans, CFA Director of Investment Strategies

1. Inflation target policy how does it work?

Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy

Transcription:

Implications of Fiscal Austerity for U.S. Monetary Policy Eric S. Rosengren President & Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Boston The Global Interdependence Center Central Banking Conference Milan, Italy May 16, 2013 It is a great pleasure to be invited to participate in the Global Interdependence Center s conference on central banking. This continues to be a period requiring unusual policy actions even experimentation at central banks around the world. So it is important to understand the forces affecting policymaking as well as the impact of the policies, both domestically and internationally. I always begin my talks by noting that these remarks reflect my views, not necessarily those of my colleagues on the Federal Reserve s Board of Governors or the Federal Open Market Committee (the FOMC). That is always the case, but I want to emphasize it today given my topic the implications of fiscal austerity for monetary policy. This is a matter of great debate in most developed economies, as governments contend with relatively high debt burdens at least by recent 2

historical standards as well as the after-effects of a deep recession, and a painfully slow recovery. Certainly fiscal matters are the subject of intense debate in the United States. Of course, much of the discussion and many of the headlines about fiscal austerity emanate from Europe. But, when we total up the cuts in state and local government spending and employment, the cuts in federal government spending and employment, and recent tax policy, we actually see that U.S. fiscal policy has been quite contractionary for several years now beginning well before the recent payroll tax increase and the reductions in fiscal spending mandated by the federal sequester. Unlike some of its counterparts around the world, the U.S. central bank has a dual mandate, covering both inflation and employment. So it is important when pursuing our mandate and shaping our policy to consider all the factors that affect the economy. Fiscal policy is one such factor. For instance, contractionary fiscal policy will in the near term place downward pressure on inflation and upward pressure on unemployment. Currently the personal consumption expenditures or PCE inflation rate, which the Federal Reserve chose as the measure for its inflation goal a year ago, is about 1.0 percent. This is well below our 2 percent target. And the unemployment rate is 7.5 percent, which while lower than many other countries remains well above most estimates of U.S. full employment. It is critically important that the United States achieve a balanced and sustainable framework for government spending, but the timing is important. For example, making cuts too quickly to restore balance to the federal budget deficit will have a dampening effect on near-term growth and the recovery, and as such will push the economy further from a state that achieves both elements of the Fed s dual mandate. 1 3

As I mentioned a moment ago, fiscal policy is just one of the many factors that the Federal Reserve considers in policymaking, but one can see how the central bank pursuing its dual mandate would be likely to adopt a more accommodative monetary policy stance if government spending were contracting in the midst of an economic recovery. Again, timing is key long-term budget sustainability is vital, but decisions to front-load or back-load cuts in spending, or increases in taxes, have implications for the current stance of monetary policy. Of course, some observers and indeed policymakers have criticized the degree of monetary accommodation in the United States as excessive. However, when we look at the data on outcomes in the economy to date, I see it differently. The outcomes could lead one to argue that policy has not been sufficiently accommodative. Inflation is below target and unemployment is above target, and based on the summary of economic projections (or SEP ) which is published by the Federal Reserve and summarizes the economic forecasts of FOMC members this condition is likely to persist for several more years. At least part of this miss on inflation and employment outcomes can be attributed to the emergence of more fiscal restraint than might have been expected. You may recall that the federal sequester was originally designed to pose such an unpalatable outcome that all involved would prefer to reach an agreement on a more balanced fiscal approach. Unfortunately, that has not been the result. By definition, the increased fiscal austerity in the U.S. has weakened the outlook for near-term GDP growth, since government spending is a component of GDP. To be sure, the progress of the economic recovery to date has been frustrating. And, despite the presence of significant headwinds fiscal, financial, and otherwise some have suggested that the slow recovery proves that recent monetary policy actions have been ineffective. However, contrary to what these observers claim, I would argue that the miss on outcomes is not evidence of monetary 4

policy ineffectiveness. In fact, in the sectors of the economy that are likely to be most responsive to lower interest rates, like housing and consumer durables, recent growth has been quite rapid. Contrary to the notion that policy has not succeeded, I would actually say that monetary policy has been quite effective in offsetting the contractionary effects of recent fiscal policies. Fiscal Policy and the Recovery As everyone here probably knows, the overall growth rate of real U.S. GDP during this recovery has been quite slow averaging roughly 2 percent at an annual rate. Growth has also been slow relative to the growth that occurred during the most recent economic recoveries in the U.S. However, looking at overall GDP growth is only part of the story. Looking more closely at the components of real GDP reveals differences, and provides more perspective on the U.S. economy s tepid recovery. Figure 1 shows growth in real final sales to private domestic purchasers. Essentially this is just the consumption and investment components of GDP (household and firm spending), net of inventory accumulation. It tries to capture the growth in domestic spending not attributed to government spending or to the foreign sector. Over the past three years, real final sales to private domestic purchasers have been quite strong, reflecting particular strength in consumer durables and residential investment 2 the most interest-sensitive sectors. With household and firm spending relatively strong, other sectors of the economy must account for the slow growth in overall GDP. Figure 2 adds real final sales to all domestic purchasers to Figure 1, so the difference between the two lines is attributable to government spending. This measure has only been growing at a rate a little below 2 percent over the past three years. In short, while household and firm spending has been 5

relatively robust, it has been offset by a fiscal headwind reduced government spending netting out to only tepid overall growth. Figure 3 shows the growth in government spending. Clearly, over the past three years the growth rate has been mostly negative, so real government spending has brought down the GDP total. This is in contrast to the earlier period, during the recession, when government spending was actually an offset to the weakness in the private sector. During that period there was federal stimulus money, and federal funding for state and local governments designed to help them better weather the storm. Figure 4 shows another way to measure the impact of government spending on economic growth the percent contribution of government spending to the percent change in real GDP. Recently, the increase in real GDP includes a sizable negative contribution from reductions in government spending. Figure 5 splits government spending into the federal component, and the state and local component. State and local spending has been weak over the entire recovery, although as the economy has recovered and state and local governments have seen more tax revenue, it has become much less of a headwind than earlier in the recovery. On the other hand, federal spending has recently fallen sharply and is likely to continue to be a source of weakness in the GDP accounts, given the federal sequester. Historically speaking, this pattern is unusual during economic recoveries. Figure 6 indexes government spending at the trough of the recession to 100 for the current and previous three recoveries. This recovery has been unusual in that government spending is not normally a significant source of headwind as the economy recovers in fact usually the opposite is true. Consider the 1982 recovery the last time we had a recession where the unemployment rate reached 10 percent. Government spending by this stage of the recovery had increased by 20 percent, 6

one reason that particular recovery was strong. By contrast, during this recovery real government spending has declined by more than 5 percent over the 15 quarters of the recovery. Figure 7 shows total payroll employment and private payroll employment. The difference between the two reflects changes in government employment. During the recession, total payroll employment was less negative than private payroll employment, indicating the government sector was not shedding jobs at a time when the private sector was significantly downsizing. However, during the recovery period, private sector payroll employment has grown more rapidly than the total, reflecting the loss of government jobs that has persisted over the recovery. In sum, fiscal restraint during the recovery has been notable and naturally has factored into the recovery s pace. While the sectors that are sensitive to monetary policy have responded to the Fed s accommodative policy actions, the results have not fully offset the headwinds, fiscal and otherwise, that we have seen. The overall result has been economic growth around 2 percent, and only a very gradual improvement in labor markets. Fiscal Restraint and Inflation The unemployment rate is about 7.5 percent at least 2 percentage points above my estimate of the U.S. full employment rate. Add to this the recent U.S. inflation experience and the other factors I have been discussing, and it seems to me that highly accommodative monetary policy is currently appropriate. Despite concerns expressed by some that increases in the Federal Reserve balance sheet may be inflationary in the near term, the inflation rate remains well below target nearly five years after our balance sheet expanded significantly. Make no mistake, in many situations such balance sheet 7

activity would be inflationary, but the fact that it has not been underlines how challenging the recent financial crisis, recession, and slow recovery have been. Figure 8 provides total and core PCE inflation. Core PCE inflation has remained below 2 percent since December 2008 and currently is only 1.1 percent, close to the low for the last five years. Total PCE inflation is slightly below 1 percent, at 0.97 percent. Indeed, the level to which the inflation rate has fallen would actually be of some concern in the event that the economy was hit by a negative shock. Such a situation might echo the historical experience of Japan, where low rates of inflation were not addressed and a significant negative shock caused Japan to experience deflation, which has been quite difficult to reverse. In the U.S. there is no evidence that inflation expectations have fallen, despite the actual experience of persistently undershooting the Fed s 2 percent target. However, remaining at such a low rate of inflation rate does increase the risk that a negative shock could alter the stable inflation expectations that we have experienced. Figure 9 shows one reason why this is a concern. It plots the real interest rate as the difference between the 3-month Treasury rate and the year-over-year core PCE inflation rate. In effect, this assumes that inflation expectations equal the past year s core PCE inflation rate. Since the 3-month Treasury rate has remained very close to zero for more than four years, the movements in the real rate must primarily reflect changes in the other part of the equation the inflation rate. Importantly, as the inflation rate falls, the real interest rate rises. Higher real interest rates make it more expensive to borrow, after controlling for changes in inflation. Japan has been an extreme example of this dynamic, given that deflation has caused the real interest rate to remain positive despite a weak economy and falling prices. 8

In sum, the longer we in the U.S. remain so far below our 2 percent target, the greater the risk that inflation expectations could fall and real interest rates rise. In part to offset this risk, the Fed has conducted large-scale asset purchases that increase its balance sheet. Balance Sheet Implications Figure 10 shows central bank assets in the United States, United Kingdom, and the Euro area. Each central bank has expanded its balance sheet, with the U.K. and the U.S. being particularly active. The U.S. Federal Reserve has seen a renewed increase in the size of its balance sheet, starting in the fall of last year, reflecting the new program of open-ended asset purchases. This latest program has helped keep prevailing interest rates low, so that housing and consumer durables can continue to support the expansion and so we make further progress on both elements of the Fed s dual mandate (inflation and employment). We have seen a gradual improvement in labor markets, in part as a result of these actions. The unemployment rate was 7.8 percent in September when we began the program, and is currently 7.5 percent. Employment growth averaged about 150,000 jobs per month in the three months ending in September; then for the most recent three months (February through April) employment growth averaged over 200,000 jobs per month. But despite modest increases in employment in recent months, the employment-to-population ratio remains low. This last observation carries the more ominous implication that, while there has been improvement in labor markets, much of the improvement in the unemployment rate is just a result of workers leaving the labor force. More significant improvement in the employment picture will require growth in real GDP that is faster than the 2 percent we have been averaging. 9

As I noted earlier, restrictive fiscal policy has had an impact on near-term economic growth during the recovery. As Figure 11 shows, cuts in real government spending in the United States over the past three years have been quite large. In fact, the cuts in government spending in the United States have been much larger in percentage terms than in the U.K. or the Euro area, where fiscal austerity has received more attention. Fiscal restraint is one of the headwinds that we factored into monetary policymaking, framed of course by our mandates from Congress. While Figure 11 considers only government spending, Figure 12 presents a broader measure of fiscal austerity, by including the revenue side and adjusting for the business cycle. The chart shows the impact of changes in taxes as well as government spending, after controlling for economic growth (removing the impact of the business cycle). Looking at the change in the general government structural budget balance 3 relative to potential GDP over the period 2010 to 2013, the degree of fiscal austerity is fairly similar across the U.S., U.K., and Euro area. Given the additional restraint imposed by the federal sequester, the United States is likely to once again be a leader in cutting government spending. The Federal Reserve should, and will, continue to consider the likely state of fiscal policy, like many other economic factors, in making monetary policy. Concluding Observations The U.S. economy has continued to gradually improve. Labor markets have also slowly improved. The progress has been in part the result of the accommodative monetary policy. While household and firm spending has grown relatively rapidly, it has been partially offset by headwinds including cuts in government spending resulting in only modest overall economic growth. 10

Let me close by reiterating that a long-term sustainable solution for fiscal balance is absolutely in the country s interest. But timing is an issue. We have suffered a severe financial crisis, a deep recession, and a painfully slow recovery. Fiscal policy is obviously the jurisdiction of the legislative and executive branches of government, but given the economic realities I would urge policymakers to consider scenarios where some elements of fiscal rebalancing take effect only after the economy has more fully improved, and the possibility of a less restrictive fiscal stance until that time. Thank you. NOTES: 1 Some would observe that much of the current federal budget deficit is cyclical, not structural that simply moving to full employment would eliminate a significant share of the budget deficit. 2 Residential investment has grown strongly over the last six quarters; prior to that its performance was more mixed. 3 The structural budget balance refers to the general government cyclically adjusted balance adjusted for nonstructural elements beyond the economic cycle. These include temporary financial sector and asset price movements as well as oneoff, or temporary, revenue or expenditure items. The cyclically adjusted balance is the fiscal balance adjusted for the effects of the economic cycle; see, for example, A. Fedelino. A. Ivanova and M. Horton Computing Cyclically Adjusted Balances and Automatic Stabilizers IMF Technical Guidance Note No. 5, http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/tnm/2009/tnm0905.pdf. 11