Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

Similar documents
Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model

Enlargement of filtration

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems

Lecture 9: Practicalities in Using Black-Scholes. Sunday, September 23, 12

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

3.1 Itô s Lemma for Continuous Stochastic Variables

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Risk Neutral Pricing. to government bonds (provided that the government is reliable).

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Lévy models in finance

Monte Carlo Simulations

The Black-Scholes Model

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

1 The continuous time limit

Lecture 3. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6

Option Pricing Models for European Options

STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY AND OPTION PRICING

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

TEST OF BOUNDED LOG-NORMAL PROCESS FOR OPTIONS PRICING

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Fractional Brownian Motion as a Model in Finance

Stochastic Modelling in Finance

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Mathematics and Finance: The Black-Scholes Option Pricing Formula and Beyond

Multi-Asset Options. A Numerical Study VILHELM NIKLASSON FRIDA TIVEDAL. Master s thesis in Engineering Mathematics and Computational Science

The Black-Scholes Equation

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

The stochastic calculus

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Advanced topics in continuous time finance

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

CRRAO Advanced Institute of Mathematics, Statistics and Computer Science (AIMSCS) Research Report. B. L. S. Prakasa Rao

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee

Non-semimartingales in finance

Financial Engineering MRM 8610 Spring 2015 (CRN 12477) Instructor Information. Class Information. Catalog Description. Textbooks

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Computer Exercise 2 Simulation

Modeling via Stochastic Processes in Finance

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

5. Itô Calculus. Partial derivative are abstractions. Usually they are called multipliers or marginal effects (cf. the Greeks in option theory).

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Near-expiration behavior of implied volatility for exponential Lévy models

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

The Uncertain Volatility Model

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

A Continuity Correction under Jump-Diffusion Models with Applications in Finance

European call option with inflation-linked strike

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Beyond the Black-Scholes-Merton model

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

King s College London

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

SOME APPLICATIONS OF OCCUPATION TIMES OF BROWNIAN MOTION WITH DRIFT IN MATHEMATICAL FINANCE

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

A new Loan Stock Financial Instrument

Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 8 Option Pricing in Continuous Time

King s College London

Numerical schemes for SDEs

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

Stochastic Volatility

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes

Replication strategies of derivatives under proportional transaction costs - An extension to the Boyle and Vorst model.

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Applications of Lévy processes

An Explicit Example of a Shadow Price Process with Stochastic Investment Opportunity Set

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Transcription:

Chapter 1 Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance In this chapter, we give an overview of basic concepts in mathematical finance theory, and then explain those concepts in very simple cases, namely in the single-term finite market. 1.1 Price Processes Price processes of financial assets are usually modeled as stochastic processes. So mathematical finance theory is based on probability theory, particularly on the theory of stochastic processes. The price process of an underlying asset is generally denoted by S t in this book. The process S t is usually assumed to be positive and is expressed in the following form S t = e Zt. (1.1) The time parameter t usually runs in [0, T ], T > 0, or [0, ), and sometimes we consider the discrete time case (t = 0, 1,..., T ). 1.2 No-arbitrage and Martingale Measures In mathematical finance theory, properties of the market where the financial assets are traded are vitally important. If the market works well, then the economy should work well, but if the market does not work well, then the economy shouldn t work. An important property of the market is its efficiency. This is the noarbitrage or no free lunch assumption in mathematical finance theory. A brief definition of arbitrage is: an arbitrage opportunity is the possibility to 1

2 Option Pricing in Incomplete Markets make a profit in a financial market without risk and without net investment of capital (see Delbaen and Schachermayer [30] p.4). The no-arbitrage assumption means that a market does not allow any arbitrage opportunity. The theory which is constructed on the no-arbitrage assumption is called arbitrage theory. In arbitrage theory, the martingale measure plays an essential role. 1.3 Complete and Incomplete Markets If the market has enough commodities, then a new commodity should be a replica of old ones, and we don t need other new commodities. This concept of sufficient commodities in the market is the meaning of completeness in the market. 1.4 Fundamental Theorems The two concepts introduced above are characterized by the concept of the martingale measure. The following two theorems are well known. (See Delbaen and Schachermayer (2006) [30] or Björk (2004) [9] for details.) Theorem 1.1. (First Fundamental Theorem in Mathematical Finance). A necessary and sufficient condition for the absence of arbitrage opportunities is the existence of the martingale measure of the underlying asset process. Theorem 1.2. (Second Fundamental Theorem in Mathematical Finance). Assume the absence of arbitrage opportunities. Then a necessary and sufficient condition for the completeness of the market is the uniqueness of the martingale measure. If the market is arbitrage-free and complete, then the price of a contingent claim B, π(b), is determined by π(b) = E Q [e rt B], (1.2) where Q is the unique martingale measure and r is the interest rate of the bond. In the case where the market satisfies the no-arbitrage assumption but does not satisfy the completeness assumption, then the price π(b) is

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance 3 supposed to be in the following interval: [ π(b) inf E Q[e rt B], Q M ] sup E Q [e rt B], (1.3) Q M where M is the set of all equivalent martingale measures. (See Theorem 2.4.1 in Delbaen and Schachermayer [30].) 1.5 The Black Scholes Model The most popular and fundamental model in mathematical finance is the Black Scholes model (geometric Brownian motion model). The explicit form of the underlying asset process of this model is given by S t = S 0 e (µ 1 2 σ2 )t+σw t, (1.4) or equivalently in the stochastic differential equation (SDE) form ds t = S t (µdt + σdw t ), (1.5) where µ is a real number, σ is a positive real number, and W t is a Wiener process (standard Brownian motion). The risk-neutral measure (= martingale measure) Q is uniquely determined by Girsanov s theorem. Under Q the process W t = W t + (µ r)σ 1 t is a Wiener process and the price process S t is expressed in the form ( S t = S 0 e (r 1 2 σ2 )t+σ W t or ds t = S t rdt + σd W ) t, (1.6) where r is the constant interest rate of a risk-free asset. The price of an option X is given by e rt E Q [X]. The theoretical Black Scholes price of the European call option, C(S 0,, T ), with the strike price and the fixed maturity T is given by the following formula: C = C(S 0,, T ) = e rt E Q [(S T ) + ] = S 0 N(d 1 ) e rt N(d 2 ), (1.7) where N(d) is the normal distribution function and d 1 = log S0 σ2 + (r + 2 )T S0 σ log, d 2 = T + (r σ2 2 )T σ T = d 1 σ T. (1.8)

4 Option Pricing in Incomplete Markets 1.6 Properties of the Black Scholes Model We summarize the basic properties of the Black Scholes model as follows. 1.6.1 Distribution of log returns The log return is the increment of the logarithm of S t, log S t = log S t+ t log S t = (µ 1 2 σ2 ) t + σ W t, (1.9) and the log return process is (µ 1 2 σ2 )t + σw t. The distribution of the log return (or the log return process) of the Black Scholes model is normal. This is convenient for the calculation of the option prices. For example, we have obtained the explicit formula of the price of European call options. However, it is said that the distributions of the log returns in the real market usually have a fat tail and asymmetry. These facts suggest the necessity of considering another model. 1.6.2 Historical volatility and implied volatility Under the setting of the Black Scholes model, the historical volatility of the process is defined as the estimated value of σ based on the sequential data of the price process S t. We denote it by σ. On the other hand, the implied volatility is defined in the following way. Suppose that the market price of the European call option with the strike, say C (m) were given, then the value of σ which satisfies the equation S 0 N(d 1 ) e rt N(d 2 ) = C (m) (1.10) is the implied volatility, and this value is denoted by σ (im). It should be noted that the implied volatility σ (im) depends on the strike value but, on the contrary, that the historical volatility σ does not depend on. We first consider the case where the market value of options obeys the Black Scholes model, and so the market price C (m) is equal to the theoretical Black Scholes price C. In this case the solution of the equation for the implied volatility is equal to the original σ and it holds true that σ (im) = σ = constant. This means that if the market exactly obeys the Black Scholes model, then the implied volatility σ (im) should be equal to the historical volatility σ. But in the real world this is not true. It is well known that the implied volatility is not equal to the historical volatility, and the implied volatility

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance 5 is sometimes a convex function of, and sometimes a combination of a convex part and a concave part. These properties are the so-called volatility smile or smirk properties. σ (im) 1.7 Generalization of the Black Scholes Model The Black Scholes model is a complete market model, but it is said that the real market is incomplete in general. So we have to construct a suitable model for the incomplete market. 1.7.1 Geometric Lévy process models We start from the explicit form of geometric Brownian motion: S t = S 0 e (µ 1 2 σ2 )t+σw t. (1.11) It is a natural idea to replace the Wiener process with a more general Lévy process Z t and consider the process S t = S 0 e Zt. (1.12) The processes of this type are called the geometric Lévy processes (GLP) or exponential Lévy processes. The [GLP & MEMM] pricing models, which are explained in Chapter 7, are of this type of generalization of Black Scholes model. The class of Lévy processes is very diverse and the distributions of S t may have a at tail and may be asymmetric, and the geometric Lévy process models are generally incomplete market models. These models are studied in Chapter 2. 1.7.2 Stochastic volatility models We start from the SDE form of the Black Scholes model, ds t = S t (µdt + σdw t ). (1.13) When we randomize the volatility σ and consider the equation ds t = S t (µdt + σ t dw t ), (1.14) where σ t is a stochastic process, then we obtain the so-called stochastic volatility model.

6 Option Pricing in Incomplete Markets This model is a very natural one when we think the volatility is dependent on the economic environment. (See Chapter 15 of Cont and Tankov (2004) [25] for this model.) Notes For a general introduction to mathematical finance theory, see the following books: Björk, T. (2004) [9], Föllmer, H. and Shied, A. (2004) [38], Jeanblanc, M., Yor, M. and Chesney, M. (2009) [59], aratzas, I. and Shreve, S.E. (1998) [64], Pliska, R.S. (1997) [101], Shiryaev, A.N. (1999) [116], Shreve, S.E. (2003) [117], Shreve, S.E. (2004) [118]. For a study on elementary probability theory there are many books, for example: Feller, W. (1966) [37], Williams, D. (1991) [120].