An Extrapolative Model of House Price Dynamics

Similar documents
Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information

Momentum Crashes. The Q -GROUP: FALL SEMINAR. 17 October Kent Daniel & Tobias Moskowitz. Columbia Business School & Chicago-Booth

Interpreting factor models

The 52-week High and Momentum Investing

Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis

Economic Fundamentals, Risk, and Momentum Profits

Aggregate Earnings Surprises, & Behavioral Finance

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

Discussion of: Asset Prices with Fading Memory

Momentum Crashes. Society of Quantitative Analysts SQA Fall Seminar 16 October Kent Daniel & Tobias Moskowitz

Unpublished Appendices to Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information. Market Reactions to Different Types of Information

Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries

Stock Returns, Aggregate Earnings Surprises, and Behavioral Finance

PROFITABILITY OF CAPM MOMENTUM STRATEGIES IN THE US STOCK MARKET

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed

Momentum Crashes. Kent Daniel. Columbia University Graduate School of Business. Columbia University Quantitative Trading & Asset Management Conference

Abnormal Trading Volume, Stock Returns and the Momentum Effects

One Brief Shining Moment(um): Past Momentum Performance and Momentum Reversals

EXPLANATIONS FOR THE MOMENTUM PREMIUM

CHAPTER 2. Contrarian/Momentum Strategy and Different Segments across Indian Stock Market

Discussion Paper No. DP 07/02

PRICE REVERSAL AND MOMENTUM STRATEGIES

Stock Returns, Aggregate Earnings Surprises, and Behavioral Finance

ALTERNATIVE MOMENTUM STRATEGIES. Faculdade de Economia da Universidade do Porto Rua Dr. Roberto Frias Porto Portugal

Notes. 1 Fundamental versus Technical Analysis. 2 Investment Performance. 4 Performance Sensitivity

Risk-managed 52-week high industry momentum, momentum crashes, and hedging macroeconomic risk

BUSFIN 4224 Behavioral Finance Fall 2017 August 22, October 10, 2017

Ulaş ÜNLÜ Assistant Professor, Department of Accounting and Finance, Nevsehir University, Nevsehir / Turkey.

Behavioral Finance. Nicholas Barberis Yale School of Management October 2016

Chris Brightman, CFA, Feifei Li, Ph.D., FRM, and Xi Liu, CFA

Absolute Momentum: a Simple Rule-Based Strategy and Universal Trend-Following Overlay

Momentum and Credit Rating

Systematic liquidity risk and stock price reaction to shocks: Evidence from London Stock Exchange

Alpha Momentum and Price Momentum*

The Factors That Matter

Economics of Behavioral Finance. Lecture 3

The 52-Week High and Momentum Investing

Corporate disclosure, information uncertainty and investors behavior: A test of the overconfidence effect on market reaction to goodwill write-offs

Discussion of "Yield Curve Premia" by Brooks and Moskowitz

Momentum and Market Correlation

The Trend is Your Friend: Time-series Momentum Strategies across Equity and Commodity Markets

REVIEW OF OVERREACTION AND UNDERREACTION IN STOCK MARKETS

Price and Earnings Momentum: An Explanation Using Return Decomposition

Profitability of CAPM Momentum Strategies in the US Stock Market

A Market Microsructure Theory of the Term Structure of Asset Returns

Diverse Beliefs and Time Variability of Asset Risk Premia

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009

Anomalous Price Behavior Following Earnings Surprises: Does Representativeness Cause Overreaction?

Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information

April 13, Abstract

Time-varying exposure to permanent and short-term risk and stock price momentum

Investment Opportunities in Zombie Stocks?

B Asset Pricing II Spring 2006 Course Outline and Syllabus

Agent Based Trading Model of Heterogeneous and Changing Beliefs

Momentum in Imperial Russia

Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less?

Working Papers Series

Momentum, Business Cycle, and Time-varying Expected Returns

Optimal Financial Education. Avanidhar Subrahmanyam

Testing behavioral finance models of market underand overreaction: do they really work?

Do individual investors drive post-earnings announcement drift? Direct evidence from personal trades

Comparison of Disposition Effect Evidence from Karachi and Nepal Stock Exchange

Momentum and Downside Risk

Temporary movements in stock prices

Do Investors Overvalue Firms With Bloated Balance Sheets?

Time-Varying Momentum Payoffs and Illiquidity*

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Hedging Factor Risk Preliminary Version

Momentum and the Disposition Effect: The Role of Individual Investors

Can Technical Analysis Boost Stock Returns? Evidence from China. Stock Market

Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information

Trading Behavior around Earnings Announcements

A Prospect-Theoretical Interpretation of Momentum Returns

Underreaction, Trading Volume, and Momentum Profits in Taiwan Stock Market

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

When to Pick the Losers: Do Sentiment Indicators Improve Dynamic Asset Allocation? 1

Common Factors in Return Seasonalities

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010

Time-Varying Momentum Payoffs and Illiquidity*

Reconcilable Differences: Momentum Trading by Institutions

Vayanos and Vila, A Preferred-Habitat Model of the Term Stru. the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Momentum Life Cycle Hypothesis Revisited

Corporate Innovation and its Effects on Equity Returns

Housing prices and transaction volume

Loss Aversion and Seller Behavior: Evidence from the Housing Market

Time-Series Momentum versus Technical Analysis

Does Disposition Drive Momentum?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES NEGLECTED RISKS: THE PSYCHOLOGY OF FINANCIAL CRISES. Nicola Gennaioli Andrei Shleifer Robert Vishny

What Drives Anomaly Returns?

Momentum Crashes. Kent Daniel and Tobias Moskowitz. - Abstract -

Heterogeneous Beliefs and Momentum Profits

ANALYZING MOMENTUM EFFECT IN HIGH AND LOW BOOK-TO-MARKET RATIO FIRMS WITH SPECIFIC REFERENCE TO INDIAN IT, BANKING AND PHARMACY FIRMS ABSTRACT

Momentum Crashes. Kent Daniel and Tobias Moskowitz. - Abstract -

The Role of Industry Effect and Market States in Taiwanese Momentum

Extrapolation of the Past: The Most Important Investment Mistake? Nicholas Barberis. Yale University. November 2015

The Efficient Market Hypothesis

Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information Revisited

Do Retail Trades Move Markets? Brad Barber Terrance Odean Ning Zhu

The Interaction of Value and Momentum Strategies

Time-Varying Momentum Payoffs and Illiquidity*

Transcription:

Discussion of: An Extrapolative Model of House Price Dynamics by: Edward L. Glaeser and Charles G. Nathanson Kent Daniel Columbia Business School and NBER NBER 2015 Summer Institute Real Estate Group Meeting 22 July, 2015

Motivating question Much like other asset classes, returns to real estate investments exhibit momentum at horizons out 1-2 years, and reversals at longer horizons What underlying mechanism is responsible for the observed return predictability?

Autocorrelations and Prices The autocorrelation structure (negative for short lags, positive for longer lags) implies an impulse response to price shocks of the form: 0.4 0.8 0.2 0 0.7 0.6 with Attribution Bias without Attribution Bias correlation 0.2 0.4 Average Price 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.6 0.2 0.8 0.1 1 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 horizon 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 period So to reproduce this impulse response, we need some mechanism that generates a slow initial response, overshooting, and then finally correction.

Rational Risk Premia? Asness, Moskowitz, and Pedersen (2013) demonstrate almost exactly the same pattern of momentum at horizons of 1 year, and value/reversals at horizons of 3-5 years in: Cross-sectional equities in US, UK, Europe, Japan markets. Global equities. Currencies Commodities Bond market strategies. A return strategy that takes advantage of the returns in each of these asset classes yields an annualized Sharpe ratio of 1.59 From Hansen and Jagannathan (1991), this implies σ M >156%. Moreover the correlations of these strategies and plausible marginal utility proxies are low.

Model Continuous time risk-neutral agents. Exogenous fixed risk-free rate r Buyer observes her current dividend D i,t : D i,t = D t + a i, a i N (0, σ 2 a) with a (common) city-wide component D t and an (i.i.d.) individual-specific component a i. The growth rate of the city-wide component follows an AR(1) process: where dw D t dw g t. dd t = g t dt + σ D dwt D dg t = λg t dt + σ g dw g t

Model All transaction prices are assumed to occur at the buyer s valuation, which equals the expected utility flow plus the sale price. [ T ] p i,t = E i,t D i,τ dτ + e r(t τ) p T (T t) Poisson(µ) t Holding D i,t = D t + a i constant, a higher D t pushes up p i,t via an increased p T (expected sale price). A higher growth rate g t pushes up the price via both increased utility flow and higher forecast sale price. However, the buyer does not directly observe either D t or the current growth rate g t, and must infer these.

Model Lemma 1 shows that, given all buyers believe that their views reflect average views: p t = 1 ( r r r + µ Davg t + µ ) r + µ D t + A g ĝ t where is the actual average dividend D t and ĝ t are the average beliefs about the dividend and dividend growth rates. However, buyers performing naive inference believe that other agents set prices ignoring dividend growth: D avg t p j,t = D j,t r In this case, buyers infer the values of D t & g t using a Kalman filter applied to values of D avg t based on: D avg t = r p t Intuitively, this will lead to increasing over-reactions to shocks to g t, Kent and Daniel eventual Columbia corrections.

Model Lemma 1 shows that, given all buyers believe that their views reflect average views: p t = 1 ( r r r + µ Davg t + µ ) r + µ D t + A g ĝ t However, buyers performing naive inference believe that other agents set prices ignoring dividend growth: p j,t = D j,t r In this case, buyers infer the values of D t & g t using a Kalman filter applied to values of D avg t based on: D avg t = r p t Intuitively, this will lead to increasing over-reactions to shocks to g t, and eventual corrections.

$30,000 Impulse Response $15,000 p t = 1 ( r r r + µ Davg t + µ ) r + µ D FIGURE 2 t + A gĝ t Evolution of Prices and Beliefs After a Demand Shock a) Prices Observable Rational Naive $30,000 Observable Rational Naive 0 $15,000 5 0 5 10 15 20 25 Years After Shock 0 b) Level Beliefs 5 0 5 10 15 20 25 Years After Shock c) Growth Beliefs $30,000 $30,000 b) Level Beliefs Observable Rational Observable Naive Rational Naive $30,000 $30,000 c) Growth Beliefs Observable Rational Naive Observable Rational Naive $15,000 $15,000 $15,000 $15,000 0 0 5 0 5 10 15 20 25 Years After Shock 5 0 5 10 15 20 25 Years After Shock 0 0 Notes: We plot impulse responses from a one standard deviation shock to demand. The figures plot the average di erence 5 between 10 the 15 simulated model 20 with 25 and without the shock. 5Panel (a) displays 0 transaction 5 prices, 10 and (b) 15is 5 0 20 25 the component Years After of Shock prices related to beliefs about the level of demand Dt and (c) is the price component Years After corresponding Shock to beliefs about the growth rate of demand gt. This decomposition appears in (9). Observable denotes the model in which buyers can observe the current state of demand, Rational denotes the model in which demand is unobservable but the buyers apply a rational filter, and Naive denotes the model in which buyers apply a naive filter. Notes: We plot impulse responses from a one standard deviation shock to demand. The figures plot the average di erence between the simulated Kent model Daniel with Columbia and without thegn shock. Extrapolation Panel (a) displays & Housetransaction Price Dynamics prices, and (b) is

Asset-Pricing Models of Momentum & Reversal Given the similarities of the momentum & reversal effects in so many different markets, it seems plausible that similar mechanisms are generating the observed price patterns. Could the hypothesis proposed here apply to other asset classes? There are a now a number of asset pricing models that attempt to explain momentum and reversal (and other) effects within a unified framework: Barberis, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998), Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (1998), Hong and Stein (1999) There are a number of others designed to explain a single anomaly (e.g., momentum): Grinblatt and Han (2005), George and Hwang (2004), Eyster, Rabin, and Vayanos (2013). How can we discriminate between these competing theories?

Discriminating Between Models In the asset pricing literature, some research has focused on refining our understanding of which variables forecast future price changes: Daniel and Titman (2006) show that, at longer horizons, price moves unrelated to fundamental information reverse not those linked to fundamental information Novy-Marx (2015) argues that the opposite is true for momentum The vast majority of momentum is the continuation of the returns that can be linked to earnings announcements. It would be straightforward to see if the same findings hold up in real-estate. Are the findings consistent with this model s predictions?

Discriminating Between Models For US common stocks, Daniel and Titman (2006) decompose past 5-year returns in a component that is linked to fundamental accounting information, and a resdiual. Fundamental information explains about 60% of the cross-sectional variance in returns. log(p t ) Total Return Intangible Return log(p ^ t ) Tangible Return log(p t 5 ) log(p t 5 ) t 5 Figure 1: Graphical illustration of the breakdown of a firm s past return into tangible and intangible returns. t

Discriminating Between Models are not a perfect proxy for intangible information--other factors also influence a firm's issuance decision (whether they issue or repurchase, and if so, how much). This suggests that both our intangible return proxies and the composite issuance chosen by the manager should forecast future returns. To test this possibility, in Table V we add d(t - 5, t) to our earlier regressions of returns on accounting returns and various measures of intangible returns. The intangible exhibits strong reversal the tangible component does not. These regression estimates show that t(t - 5, t) and intangible returns are both significant when the two variables are included in the same regression, suggesting that indeed these variables have independent effects on returns. Table V Fama-MacBeth Regressions of Monthly Returns on Past Tangible and Intangible Returns and Composite Issuance The table presents the results of a set of Fama-MacBeth coefficients and t-statistics for regressions of monthly returns on lagged fundamental-to-price ratios, accounting returns, intangible returns, and composite issuance. The forecasting regressions reported in this table are identical to those in Table IV, with the exception that we also include composite issuance as an explanatory variable. The time period is 1968:07-2003:12. All coefficients are x 100. Fama-MacBeth t-statistics are in parentheses. Regression Number Constant (t - 5, t) 1 1.210-0.658 (4.72) (-4.39) Constant bmt-5 rb (t - 5, t) ri(b) t(t - 5, t) 2 1.225 0.080-0.057-0.331-0.514 (4.93) (1.26) (-0.95) (-3.71) (-4.16) Constant spt-5 rs (t - 5, t) rl(s) W(t - 5, t) 3 1.106 0.082 0.061-0.311-0.513 (4.47) (1.83) (1.25) (-4.05) (-3.87) Constant cpt-5 rc (t - 5, t) ri(c) W(t - 5, t) 4 1.335 0.060-0.041-0.455-0.451 (5.53) (1.00) (-1.03) (-4.64) (-3.80) Constant ept-5 re (t - 5, t) ri(e) W(t - 5, t) 5 1.308 0.050 0.004-0.439-0.451 (5.50) (0.88) (0.13) (-4.41) (-3.89) Constant rt(tot)(t - 5, t) ri(tot) L(t - 5, t) 6 1.272-0.105-0.441-0.489 (5.38) (-1.67) (-4.24) (-3.73)

Case-Shiller Evidence Case, Shiller, and Thompson (2012) review the Case-Shiller homebuyer survey evidence over the 2003-2012 period. Consistent with the model and findings here, they find that homebuyers have a good sense of recent price changes. They also find that the expected one-year growth rate is strongly correlated with the lagged price growth. However, CST emphasize the disconnect between the shortand long-term forecasts, and argue for the importance of the long-term forecasts in price formation.

Survey Evidence & Model Predictions 276 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2012 Case, Shiller, and Thompson (2012): Table 3. Short- and Long-Term Home Price Expectations, by Survey Location and Year, 2003 12 Mean response (percent) a Survey year Alameda County Middlesex County Survey location Milwaukee County How much of a change do you expect there to be in the value of your home over the next 12 months? b Orange County 2003 7.6 4.4 5.5 9.4 2004 9.3 7.6 6.4 13.1 2005 9.6 6.3 6.6 8.7 2006 7.4 1.9 5.9 6.0 2007 4.9 2.9 6.1 0.1 2008 1.6 0.7 2.4 2.6 2009 2.4 2.0 1.5 0.7 2010 4.4 2.2 3.7 3.8 2011 2.3 2.3 1.7 0.3 2012 4.4 2.3 2.3 3.6 On average over the next ten years how much do you expect the value of your property to change each year? c 2003 12.3 8.9 7.1 11.5 2004 14.1 10.6 10.4 17.4 2005 11.5 8.3 11.9 15.2 2006 9.4 7.5 9.9 9.5 2007 10.7 5.3 8.1 12.2 2008 7.9 6.4 7.2 9.4 2009 8.5 6.2 8.2 6.9 2010 9.8 5.0 7.3 5.7 2011 7.6 4.1 4.7 7.1 2012 5.4 3.1 3.1 5.0 Source: Authors surveys. a. Means are 10 percent trimmed means; that is, we dropped the highest and lowest 5 percent of responses before calculating the mean. b. Survey question Kent Daniel 6. Columbia

Survey Evidence & Model Predictions Case, Shiller, 296 and Thompson Brookings (2012) Papers on Economic heterogeneity: Activity, Fall 2012 Figure A.2. Distributions of Expected One-Year and Ten-Year Home Price Growth Percent of respondents One-year expectations 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 Expected growth g (%) g > 20 10 < g 20 5 < g 10 0 < g 5 g 0 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Ten-year expectations (annualized) Percent of respondents 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 Expected growth g (%) g > 20 10 < g 20 5 < g 10 0 < g 5 g 0 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Source: Authors Kent Daniel calculations from Columbia homebuyers survey GN data. Extrapolation & House Price Dynamics

Michigan Consumer Survey Evidence Piazzesi and Schneider (2009) use data from the Michigan Survey of Consumers. 16 19 18 17 housing price-dividend ratio Generally speaking, do you 15 think now is a good time or a early late bad time to buy a house? 14 phase Why do you say so? 13 respondents give up to two reasons, which are grouped. phase 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 20 1 19 good time to buy 18 housing price-dividend ratio 0.8 17 0.6 16 0.4 good credit 15 14 early late phase phase 0.2 current price low future price high 13 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 0 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 1

13 Does Survey Evidence Line up with Predictions? 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 20 1 good time to buy 19 0.8 18 housing price-dividend ratio 17 0.6 16 0.4 good credit 15 14 early late phase phase 0.2 current price low future price high 13 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 0 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 Interestingly, good time theto buy peak of housing prices was not uniformly 14 good credit viewed as the best time to buy! 73% of those say give credit conditions as a reason for buying. The fraction saying prices are going up peaks at 20% in 2005. But there is considerable heterogeneity. current future price low price high

Transaction Volume? One dramatic feature of real-estate markets is the link between transaction volume and past returns. Genesove and Mayer (2001) provide a disposition-effect explanation of this feature Their model relies on disagreement, which seems to be a key feature of the survey data.

Solving the Model GN argue that a full solution of the model may be beyond the capabilities of most homebuyers. However, it seems less plausible that: agents need to fully understand the model to make better pricing decisions. Many agents couldn t do a quite bit better than the naive inference model. Survey evidence suggests that while buyers were strongly optimistic, a number of agents were paying attention to the variables that forecast housing returns.

References I Asness, Clifford S., Toby J. Moskowitz, and Lasse Heje Pedersen, 2013, Value and momentum everywhere, The Journal of Finance 58, 929 895. Barberis, Nicholas, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny, 1998, A model of investor sentiment, Journal of Financial Economics 49, 307 343. Case, Karl E., Robert J. Shiller, and Anne K. Thompson, 2012, What have they been thinking? homebuyer behavior in hot and cold markets, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. Daniel, Kent D., David Hirshleifer, and Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, 1998, Investor psychology and security market under- and over-reactions, Journal of Finance 53, 1839 1886. Daniel, Kent D., and Sheridan Titman, 2006, Market reactions to tangible and intangible information, Journal of Finance 61, 1605 1643. Eyster, Erik, Matthew Rabin, and Dimitri Vayanos, 2013, Financial markets where traders neglect the informational content of prices, University of California, Berkeley working paper. Genesove, David, and Christopher Mayer, 2001, Loss aversion and seller behavior: Evidence from the housing market., Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, 1233 1260. George, Thomas J., and Chuan-Yang Hwang, 2004, The 52-week high and momentum investing, The Journal of Finance 59, 2145 2176. Grinblatt, Mark, and Bing Han, 2005, Prospect theory, mental accounting and momentum, Journal of Financial Economics 78, 311 339. Hansen, Lars P., and Ravi Jagannathan, 1991, Implications of security market data for models of dynamic economies, Journal of Political Economy 99, 225 262.

References II Hong, Harrison, and Jeremy C. Stein, 1999, A unified theory of underreaction, momentum trading and overreaction in asset markets, Journal of Finance 54, 2143 2184. Novy-Marx, Robert, 2015, Fundamentally, momentum is fundamental momentum, Rochester University Working Paper. Piazzesi, Monika, and Martin Schneider, 2009, Momentum traders in the housing market: Survey evidence and a search model, American Economic Review 99, 406 411.