Professor Scholz Posted March 29, 2006 Economics 441, Brief Answers for Problem Set #3 Due in class, April 5, 2006

Similar documents
Professor Scholz Posted November 27, 2006 Economics 441, Problem Set #4 Due in class, Monday, December 11, 2006

Economics 742 Homework #4

Relax. Stop, take a deep breath, and think carefully before you answer any questions. Good luck!

Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle

Professor Scholz Posted March 1, 2006 Brief Answers for Economics 441, Problem Set #2 Due in class, March 8, 2006

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS

Section 9, Chapter 2 Moral Hazard and Insurance

Questions for Review. CHAPTER 17 Consumption

Macro Consumption Problems 33-43

ADVERSE SELECTION AND SCREENING IN INSURANCE MARKETS

The trade-offs associated with getting an education

Problem set 1 ECON 4330

Macro Consumption Problems 12-24

Questions for Review. CHAPTER 16 Understanding Consumer Behavior

Economics 101. Lecture 8 - Intertemporal Choice and Uncertainty

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation

Problem Set 5 Answers. ( ) 2. Yes, like temperature. See the plot of utility in the notes. Marginal utility should be positive.

ECON 581. Introduction to Arrow-Debreu Pricing and Complete Markets. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Ch In other countries the replacement rate is often higher. In the Netherlands it is over 90%. This means that after taxes Dutch workers receive

Lecture XXX: Bank Runs

ECON385: A note on the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). In this note, we will try to understand the permanent income hypothesis (PIH).

International Macroeconomics

Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth

The following content is provided under a Creative Commons license. Your support will help

Real Estate Private Equity Case Study 3 Opportunistic Pre-Sold Apartment Development: Waterfall Returns Schedule, Part 1: Tier 1 IRRs and Cash Flows

MONEY and BANKING: ECON 3115 Fall 2011

Answer Key to Midterm Exam. February

Medicaid Insurance and Redistribution in Old Age

Business Cycles II: Theories

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 2

ECON DISCUSSION NOTES ON CONTRACT LAW. Contracts. I.1 Bargain Theory. I.2 Damages Part 1. I.3 Reliance

ECON MICROECONOMIC THEORY HOMEWORK 5 UNCERTAINTY

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

Nordic Journal of Political Economy

Assignment 1 Answers

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE

Answers To Chapter 14

2015 Social Security Changes Will Hit Couples & Divorced Women Hardest

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Problem 3 Solutions. l 3 r, 1

12.2 Utility Functions and Probabilities

An Improved Application of the Variable Annuity

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Adverse Selection: The Market for Lemons

TOPICS IN RETIREMENT INCOME

Iteration. The Cake Eating Problem. Discount Factors

Problem Set (1 p) (1) 1 (100)

14.41 Public Economics, 2002 Problem Set #4 Solutions

Social Security Comes First The many facets of Social Security Traditionally, retirement has been seen as a three-legged stool with defined benefit pl

1 The Solow Growth Model

Development Economics Part II Lecture 7

Consumption and Savings (Continued)

1 The Rotten Kid Theorem

The following content is provided under a Creative Commons license. Your support

ECON Micro Foundations

Lecture 13: Social Insurance

14.41 Fall 2004 Mock Final Solutions T/F/U

IB Interview Guide: Case Study Exercises Three-Statement Modeling Case (30 Minutes)

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 13 Basic things you need to know about SS. SS is essentially a public annuity, it gives insurance against low

Economics 370 Microeconomic Theory Problem Set 5 Answer Key

Settlement and the Strict Liability-Negligence Comparison

Financial markets in developing countries (rough notes, use only as guidance; more details provided in lecture) The role of the financial system

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

= quantity of ith good bought and consumed. It

The Health Insurance Game

Retirement Income Source Diversification

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Unit 4.3: Uncertainty

Economics 325 Intermediate Macroeconomic Analysis Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Spring 2009

Econ 101A Midterm 1 Th 28 February 2008.

1. [March 6] You have an income of $40 to spend on two commodities. Commodity 1 costs $10 per unit and commodity 2 costs $5 per unit.

ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 6 - Public Finance J. Wissink - Cornell University

Microeconomics 2nd Period Exam Solution Topics

S u =$55. S u =S (1+u) S=$50. S d =$48.5. S d =S (1+d) C u = $5 = Max{55-50,0} $1.06. C u = Max{Su-X,0} (1+r) (1+r) $1.06. C d = $0 = Max{48.

14.03 Fall 2004 Problem Set 2 Solutions

Time Preferences. Mark Dean. Behavioral Economics Spring 2017

Decision Making Under Risk Probability Historical Data (relative frequency) (e.g Insurance) Cause and Effect Models (e.g.

Economics Honors Exam Review (Micro) Mar Based on Zhaoning Wang s final review packet for Ec 1010a, Fall 2013

Each question is self-contained, and assumptions made in one question do not carry over to other questions, unless explicitly specified.

Hello I'm Professor Brian Bueche, welcome back. This is the final video in our trilogy on time value of money. Now maybe this trilogy hasn't been as

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

ECON DISCUSSION NOTES ON CONTRACT LAW-PART 2. Contracts. I.1 Investment in Performance

Chapter 18: The Correlational Procedures

Lecture 12: Introduction to reasoning under uncertainty. Actions and Consequences

Issues in International Finance Benefits of international capital markets. UW Madison // Fall 2018

The Dialogue Podcast Transcript Private Health Insurance

Example: from 15 January 2006 to Rule Result 13 March Y 3 (from 15 January 2006 to 15 January 2009) 2. Count the number of remaining months and

The Role of Physical Capital

Midterm 2 (Group A) U(C; R) =R 2 C. U i (C 1 ;C 2 ) = ln (C 1 ) + ln (C 2 ) p 1 p 2. =1 + r

A simple wealth model

Transcription:

Professor Scholz Posted March 29, 2006 Economics, rief nswers for Problem Set #3 Due in class, pril 5, 2006 ) Each superhero's utility exhibits diminishing marginal returns (you can see this by simply plotting the level of utility against consumption, or by finding that the second derivative is negative). This is equivalent to saying that the individual is risk averse. Since this is true, and since insurance is fair, the price that each type pays for a unit of insurance will be equal to the probability that they get caught - and further, we know from class that risk-adverse individuals (i.e. utility with diminishing marginal returns) will fully insure if insurance is fair. You could also get this result by solving for the optimal level of insurance that each type will choose. For clumsy superheros, the problem would be: Max puaccident + ( p) U Noccident Max.9(00 50 + b.9 b) +.(00.9 b) du (.9)(.7)(.) (.)(.7)(.9) so = = 0.3.3 db (50 +. b) (00.9 b) b = 50 Where b is the amount of insurance the clumsy superhero buys (which is equal to the amount he gets from the insurance company if he is caught). The procedure is similar for skilled superheros. So, to answer the specific questions, CME will charge the clumsy $0.90 for every dollar of insurance and will charge the skillful $0.30. Since they are risk averse and the insurance is priced fairly, they will both purchase $50 of insurance. The clumsy will consume $55 in both the accident and no accident state. The skillful will consume $85 in both states., part a) the maximum amount that each would be willing to pay for insurance is equal the amount that makes him or her exactly as well off with insurance as without. Without insurance, the expected utility of each type is clumsy skillful =.9(00 50) +.(00) 6.28 =.3(00 50) +.7(00) 9.2 Full insurance would mean that the superhero receives full compensation for injury if injured, resulting in complete consumption smoothing across the two possible states (caught or not caught). Hence, his income in each state is simply his full income less insurance costs. So to solve for the maximum each type would be willing to pay for full insurance, solve the following: = 6.28 = (00 X ) X = 5.8 clumsy, no insurance clumsy, FI = 9.2 = (00 X ) X = 6.80 NI FI.7 So the clumsy type is willing to spend 5.8 for full insurance (for a per-unit price of.90) and the skillful type is willing to spend 6.80 (for a per-unit price of.336). Note that each is willing to pay more than the actuarially fair price - this is because their utility function exhibits diminishing marginal returns to consumption (risk aversion):

, part b) If CME is looking for a single market price such that everyone will fully insure, it will have to offer the maximum price that the skillful are willing to pay: 6.80. However, when it does this it will collect 2*6.80=20.6 in revenue for every *.3*50+.9*50=20 it expects to payout - since expected revenue is less than expected payout, CME won't stay in business if it offers this plan. Hence, there's a market failure: we know that each type is willing to pay more than the actuarially fair price for full insurance, and CME is certainly willing to offer insurance at a greater-than-fair price. The problem is that types are unobservable (that is, asymmetric information exists in this insurance market), so this arrangement cannot occur. ecause there are transactions that would occur under full information that would make everyone better off, a market failure exists. c) Now, let's consider the expected utility that each type would receive under each plan: clumsy, Plan Plan =.9(00 50 + 20 7) +.(00 7) 8.77 =.3(00 50 + 20 7) +.7(00 7) 9.32 clumsy, Plan Plan =.9(00 50 + 50 3) +.(00 3) 8.779 =.3(00 50 + 50 3) +.7(00 3) 8.2 Comparing these expected utilities to those without insurance, as calculated in (b, part a), we see that clumsy types prefer plan to plan, and are better off by purchasing insurance than not purchasing insurance. The skillful types prefer plan to plan, and are also better off by purchasing insurance. So if these packages were offered, all the clumsy would purchase type, and all the skillful would purchase plan. CME revenues are *7+ *3=. CME expected payout is *.3*20+.9*50=. CME would make zero economic profit from this package, but since zero economic profit allows the company to earn market rates of return on all factors of production it is willing to offer the insurance. Now everyone has some insurance However, there is still a market failure for the same reason as before - the skillful types still wish to purchase full insurance at actuarially fair prices, and the insurance company would offer insurance for those prices - but due to asymmetric information, this is impossible. The outcome may be more favorable than before, since now everyone gets some insurance, but a market failure still exists. D part a) There might be an incentive here for the skillful type to purchase the test. Consider what happens if the skillful pay for the test and reveal their type: given that there is perfect competition in the insurance market, the skillful will be offered actuarially fair insurance, so they would fully insure. The clumsy type would never purchase the test, because if they do their type will be revealed, and they will receive actuarially fair insurance - which is more expensive than the insurance plan they receive from c! To determine whether the skillful types will purchase the test, consider their expected utility if they do: NoIns Plan test =.3(00 50) +.7(00) 9.2 =.3(00 50 + 20 7) +.7(00 7) 9.32 = (00.3*50) 9.38 Since the skillful are slightly better off by paying $0 for the test, receiving fair insurance and fully insuring, they will be willing to pay for Dr. rain's test. Now, CME will offer two insurance packages. The first will be for those revealed to be who will be able to purchase insurance for a per-unit of 2

coverage cost of.3. The second will be available only to those who haven't revealed themselves with a test (i.e. the clumsy), who will be able to purchase insurance for a per-unit of coverage cost of.9. oth types will fully insure! D, part b) The skillful are better off than in (c), because they are now fully insured. The clumsy are worse off, because although they are still fully insured, they have to pay more in order to be fully insured. D, part c) Now there is no longer a market failure. The presence of the market for blood tests has eliminated the asymmetric information problem, and everyone is fully insured at actuarially fair prices (although the skillful are technically paying more than actuarially fair prices to receive full insurance, since they first have to purchase the test). 2a) Don't get confused because we're thinking about consumption in different periods. Just treat the problem as deciding how much to spend on two goods: consumption today and. consumption tomorrow. The easiest way to solve intertemporal utility maximization is to consider how much the person can consume in the second period, given how much he chose to consume in the first period. So in this example, if the person lives into the second period, his consumption is: C 2 = (l + r) * (l00 C ) =. * (00 - C ). Now just plug this in for C 2, and maximize the expected utility function with respect to C. maxu = ln C+ pln( C2) maxu = ln C+ pln(.(00 C)) 3 3 p 300 00 p = 0 300 3 C = pc C =, C2 =. C 3 00 C 3 + p 3 + p So p=.75 for type s, so C = 80, saving = 20, C 2 = 22. p=.2 for type s, so C = 93.75, saving = 6.25, C 2 = 6.875. Type s are saving more, and hence consuming less in period than s do but more in period 2, because the probability that they will live to see the second period is greater. b) Yes, people would be better off, because annuities provide a higher return on investment. Remember, the price of fair insurance is the probability of payout (i.e. the probability of having an accident). Here, the probability of payout is the probability of living into the second period. Type s only have a 20% chance of reaching the second period, so the price of one unit of annuity payout is.2. Provided the type reaches the second period, the return on his investment is huge- for every dollar he spends on insurance, he gets five dollars if he lives into the second period, for a net return of four dollars. This certainly is greater than his returns from saving. Type s must pay $.75 for $ of coverage, so s receive $.33 for every $ invested if they live into the second period. The return on their annuity investment is 33%, which is again higher than returns from saving. The reason that fair annuities can provide higher returns is because risks are pooled: everyone pays in, but only a fraction receive payment. nnuities are valuable because they assist in consumption smoothing throughout old age. In this simplified two period model, consumption smoothing can be accomplished through private savings, but doing so is inefficient, since each person needs to save on their own, and many people will die before they are able to eat their saving. n actuarially fair annuity market makes it much more efficient to smooth consumption (and hence increase utility). C, part a) The government receives 30T in revenue (since it taxes all 30 people equally), and invests it at an interest rate of 0%, so that it has 30T*. =33T in funds to payout in period two. It pays out.75* in expectation for every type, and pays out.2* in expectation for every type - so in sum, it expects to 3

pay out 20*.75 *+ 0*.2 *= 7. Since the budget must break even at the end of period two, this implies that 33T=7, or the benefits the government pays out to anyone who lives into period two is 33T/7. C, part b) The government is now trying to decide what T to choose to maximize the sum of utilities. In other words, its maximization problem is: 33T 33T max social welfare = 20* ln(00 T ) + *.75*ln + 0* ln(00 T ) + *.2*ln 3 7 3 7 20 5 0 2 700 + + = 0 T = 5.89, = 30.8 00 T T 00 T 3T 07 So each person pays 5.89 in taxes, and receives a benefit in period two of 30.8 (if they survive that long). noss noss SS SS = ln(80) + ln(22) 5 = ln(93.75) + ln(6.875).67 5 = ln(8.) + ln(30.8) 5.29 = ln(8.) + ln(30.8).66 5 is better off with social security than without - this is because it is highly probable that a type reaches the second period, and because the return from "saving" with social security is greater than the returns from private investment. Since =33T/7.9T, one dollar "saved" (taxed) through social security returns.9 dollars if the person reaches the second period, for a return of 9% (which is certainly greater than the 0% return from the private market). From 's perspective, this isn't the optimal social security system -- the optimal system would in fact force more saving through an even higher tax - but because the high return results in high period two consumption, s find this system better than a world with no social security. s, however, are just slightly worse off than before. This is because the tax rate is much higher than what they would've chosen (see answers to the next part). So even though the rate of return is much higher than what private savings yields in the absence of social security, s are worse off because the tax rate is too high. One could view this system as redistributive since it taxes s more than they wish, and these tax revenues are partially redistributed to s since s are more likely to receive social security benefits. C, part c) Now the government chooses T to maximize 's utility: 33T 00 max ' s utility = ln(00 T ) + *.2*ln 0 T 6.25, 2.3 3 7 + = = = = 00 T 5T 6 which implies

SS 2 SS 2 = ln(93.75) + ln(2.3) 5.6 = ln(93.75) + ln(2.3).7 5 Now is better off with this system than without, and is better than the first proposed system. is still better off than without social security (and if you assume that can supplement social security income with additional private savings, 's utility will be higher than 5.6), but is worse off than with the first social security system. This is because the forced savings in this system are lower than the other system - since this system doesn't account for 's preferences whatsoever, but the prior system partially weighted ' s preferences, must be better off with the first social security system. However, assuming can save in addition to social security, is not worse off than without social security - this is because can always save on top of social security at a 0% interest rate, but the returns on some investment (the 6.25 "invested" with taxes) is greater than the market rate of 0%. gain, this system redistributes from s to s - this is because the ratio of expected payout to payin is much higher for s than s. However, s are better off with this sort of redistribution than they are if the social security system didn't exist. D) There are many ways in which the merican social security system is redistributive. For example, since the PI is calculated as a progressive function of the IME, the social security system redistributes from the poor to the rich (the replacement rate for social security benefits is higher for the poor than the rich). What is most relevant from this example, however, is that the system also redistributes from the short lived to the long lived - because if two people are identical except for life expectancy, they'll pay the same amount in taxes, but the short lived person will receive less in benefits than the long lived person will. In merica, women tend to live longer than men, and whites tend to live longer than blacks, and richer people tend to live longer than poorer people - so due to differences in life expectancy, the system is redistributive from the first group to the second (of course, the progressivity of benefit calculations may make the system actually less redistributive from the first to second groups). 3) ( ) = ( )log( w+ 5) + log(5) Remember, utility is invariant to monotonic transformations, so for ease of notation, I dropped the ½. b) The break-even condition dictates the benefit level, b, so w( ) b = 0 b= w. so solve max E( U) max[( )log( w( ) + 5) + log(5 + w)] The first-order conditions are ( ) ( ) w ( ) w ( w) + w= 0 + = 0 w( ) + 5 ( ) 5 5 w w + + 5+ w = w( ) + 5 = 5 + w = b= w( ) w( ) + 5 5 + w c) Yes there are welfare gains. These occur because, due to the log utility, the workers are risk averse 5

and therefore value the insurance provided by the workers compensation system. d) If U=C then the workers are no longer risk averse and therefore they do not value insurance. There is no welfare gain to introducing workers compensation. e) ( ) = ( )log( w+ 5) + log( kw+ 5) f) max E( U) max[( )log( w( ) + 5) + log( kw+ 5 + w)] The first-order conditions are ( ) ( ) w ( ) w ( w) + w= 0 + = 0 w( ) + 5 ( ) 5 kw 5 w w + + + kw + 5+ w = w( ) + 5 = kw+ 5 + w = ( k) b= w( k)( ) w( ) + 5 kw + 5 + w g) Yes, there are gains, but they are smaller than in part c). They are smaller because spousal employment is already providing some insurance against injury. 6