On the (in)effectiveness of LTV regulation in a multiconstraint framework

Similar documents
Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

A Policy Model for Analyzing Macroprudential and Monetary Policies

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Reforms in a Debt Overhang

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

Macroprudential Policy Implementation in a Heterogeneous Monetary Union

Asset Prices, Collateral and Unconventional Monetary Policy in a DSGE model

Housing Tax Policy: Comment. Hamed GHIAIE Jean-François ROUILLARD

Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

A MODEL OF SECULAR STAGNATION

Bank Capital, Agency Costs, and Monetary Policy. Césaire Meh Kevin Moran Department of Monetary and Financial Analysis Bank of Canada

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

House Prices, Credit Growth, and Excess Volatility:

Cahier de recherche/working Paper Inequality and Debt in a Model with Heterogeneous Agents. Federico Ravenna Nicolas Vincent.

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles

On the Merits of Conventional vs Unconventional Fiscal Policy

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Spillovers, Capital Flows and Prudential Regulation in Small Open Economies

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

DSGE model with collateral constraint: estimation on Czech data

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Discussion of Gerali, Neri, Sessa, Signoretti. Credit and Banking in a DSGE Model

Structural Reforms in a Debt Overhang

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 15 Problem 3 / 15 Problem 4 / 20 Problem 5 / 25 TOTAL / 100

Money and monetary policy in Israel during the last decade

Leaning Against the Credit Cycle

Debt Covenants and the Macroeconomy: The Interest Coverage Channel

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Housing Taxation and Financial Intermediation. Hamed GHIAIE Jean-François ROUILLARD

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Fiscal Multipliers and Financial Crises

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

The Expansionary Lower Bound: A Theory of Contractionary Monetary Easing *

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Comments on Assessing Policies to Revive Credit Markets

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom

Final Exam Solutions

Samba: Stochastic Analytical Model with a Bayesian Approach. DSGE Model Project for Brazil s economy

Shadow Banking and Regulation: A Quantitative Assessment

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

A MODEL OF SECULAR STAGNATION

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

Financial frictions, financial regulation and their impact on the macroeconomy

Probably Too Little, Certainly Too Late. An Assessment of the Juncker Investment Plan

Health Care Reform or Labor Market Reform? A Quantitative Analysis of the Affordable Care Act

Monetary Policy Rules in the Presence of an Occasionally Binding Borrowing Constraint

The Basic New Keynesian Model

Balance Sheet Recessions

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Spillovers: The Role of Prudential Regulation and Monetary Policy in Small Open Economies

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Non-standard monetary policy, asset prices and macroprudential policy in a monetary union. L. Burlon, A. Gerali, A. Notarpietro and M.

Capital-goods imports, investment-specific technological change and U.S. growth

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand

The Role of the Net Worth of Banks in the Propagation of Shocks

2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic. 3. Capital, labor account for small fraction of output drop,

Government spending shocks, sovereign risk and the exchange rate regime

Output Gaps and Robust Monetary Policy Rules

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis

Monetary Policy in Pakistan: Confronting Fiscal Dominance and Imperfect Credibility

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

Macroeconomic Modelling at the Central Bank of Brazil. Angelo M. Fasolo Research Department

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model

Basel I, II, and III: A Welfare Analysis using a DSGE Model

Lecture 15 Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

A Real Intertemporal Model with Investment Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Credit Disruptions and the Spillover Effects between the Household and Business Sectors

Monetary Economics. Lecture 11: monetary/fiscal interactions in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

CAPITAL FLOWS AND FINANCIAL FRAGILITY IN EMERGING ASIAN ECONOMIES: A DSGE APPROACH α. Nur M. Adhi Purwanto

The amortization requirement s effect on Swedish house prices

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Princeton University. Updates:

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration

ECON 3020: ACCELERATED MACROECONOMICS. Question 1: Inflation Expectations and Real Money Demand (20 points)

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

Tax Benefit Linkages in Pension Systems (a note) Monika Bütler DEEP Université de Lausanne, CentER Tilburg University & CEPR Λ July 27, 2000 Abstract

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation

The Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence is Zero

D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME P UNISH S AVERS?

Transcription:

On the (in)effectiveness of LTV regulation in a multiconstraint framework Anna Grodecka February 8, 7 Abstract Models in the macro-housing literature often assume that borrowers are constrained exclusively by the loan-to-value (LTV) ratio. I explore an alternative arrangement where borrowers are constrained by the feasibility of repayment, but choose a house of maximum permissible size conditional on the LTV restriction. This assumption, which is arguably more consistent with mortgage lending practices in countries with multiple borrowing constraints, yields results that disagree with much of the existing literature. In particular, I find that policy designed to lower the maximum permissible LTV ratio may actually increase house prices in equilibrium and leave the debt-to-gdp ratio unchanged. Keywords: Borrowing constraints; Household indebtedness; Macroprudential measures; House prices JEL-Classification: E, E3 Sveriges Riksbank, e-mail: anna.grodecka@riksbank.se.

Introduction Is stricter loan-to-value (LTV) regulation effective in reducing household indebtedness? Policymakers in Sweden or Canada, where household indebtedness, along with housing prices, have been skyrocketing in the past decades, consider tightening the admissible LTV ratio as a macroprudential measure aimed at lowering the stock of debt in the economy. For Sweden, Chen and Columba (6) and Finocchiaro, Jonsson, Nilsson, and Strid (6) find that tighter LTV ratios reduce household indebtedness and are accompanied by lower housing prices. Similar conclusions are reached by Alpanda, Cateau, and Meh (4) for Canada. In this paper, using a simple real business cycle model with long-term debt, I argue that in a multiconstraint framework, tighter LTV regulation may have no effect on household indebtedness and may actually lead to an increase in housing prices. Specifically, borrowers in Canada (see Crawford, Meh, and Zhou, 3), Sweden (see Sveriges Riksbank, 4), but also e.g. Estonia (see Eesti Pank, 4) or Brasil (see de Carvalho, Castro, and Costa, 4) are subject to a debt-service-to-income (DSTI) constraint and to an LTV constraint at the same time. In Sweden, this DSTI constraint takes the form of a discrectionary income limit, and is applied to borrowers by banks, not by the regulator. In such an environment, the maximum debt limit is determined by the DSTI constraint, and the LTV constraint merely determines the housing choice of borrowers. Households first get to know their borrowing limit, and then, conditional on the LTV requirement, buy a house. Thus, lowering LTV is a very ineffective policy in such an economy, if the aim is to reduce debt to income or debt to GDP. Stricter LTV policy in a multiconstraint framework not only does not influence debt ratios at all (since debt is not a function of LTV), but it also drives house prices up in the equlibrium. Ceteris paribus, if the debt level is determined by a DSTI limit and one unit of housing can pledge less collateral, its value has to increase if it has to collateralize the same amount of debt. 3 The observation that the LTV limit can determine the housing choice of an individual and not their debt is crucial for the analysis of macroprudential policies in countries with multiple constraints. It may be relevant even for countries without an established DSTI limit, if borrowers impose such a limit on themselves. In the following, I present the benchmark model with DSTI and LTV constraints and contrast its implications with results from a LTV only model. Of course, in reality not all households choose to borrow up to the maximum. For the purpose of the paper, we assume that they do. In a setup with an LTV constraint only, the loan process is different. Household first makes the housing choice, and then pledges it as collateral. 3 A similar mechanism is described in an example in a recent paper by Greenwald (6). It presents a model for the U.S. in which new borrowing is determined by an LTV and a payment to income constraint. Borrowers switch between being bound by each of constraints. This is different from the setup presented in this paper, in which agents are limited by both constraints at the same time.

Model Consider an economy populated by firms and households that differ in their degree of impatience. Firms operate in a competitive market and are profit maximizers. They use labor to produce the final good. Households derive utility from leisure, consumption and housing. Patient households ( savers ) provide long-term adjustable-rate loans to impatient households. In the following, I present the borrrower s problem (savers and firms first-order-conditions (FOCs) are standard).. Borrowers Borrowers get utility from goods (c B ) and housing (h B ) consumption, as well as leisure. They provide labor (l B ) to firms and borrow from savers subject to two constraints. max c B t,hb t,lb t E t= The budget constraint of borrowers is: β B,t ( log c B t + j t log h B t lb t η B η B ). () c B t + q t (h B t ( δ h )h B t ) + (R s,t + κ)sb t = b t + w B t l B t, () where δ h is the depreciation of the housing stock, q t denotes the housing price, R s,t = + i t is the interest rate, κ is the amorization rate, sb t is the stock of debt, b t is new borrowing, and wt B lt B is labor income. Debt evolves according to: Substituting for the evolution of the stock of debt, we get sb t = ( κ)sb t + b t (3) c B t + q t (h B t ( δ h )h B t ) + R s,t sb t = sb t + w B t l B t. (4) The stock of debt is limited by a DSTI constraint: sb t (R s,t + κ ) DST Iw B t l B t (5) Given that new borrowing b t is determined by equation 3, the LTV limit determines the housing choice of the household: b t = sb t ( κ)sb t LT V q t (h B t ( δ h )h B t ), (6) 3

where LT V determines the LTV ratio for borrowers. is the La- The FOCs are (λ B B t is the Lagrangian multiplier on the LTV constraint and λ a t grangian multiplier on the DSTI constraint): w.r.t. sb t c B t ( ) = β B Rs,t E t + λ B c B t E t β B λ B t+( κ) + E t β B λ B a,t+(r s,t+ + κ ) (7) t+ w.r.t. h B t q t c B t = β B E t ( ( δh )q t+ c B t+ + ( δ h )λ B t+lt V q t+ ) + j t h B t λ B t LT V q t, (8) w.r.t. L B t w B t = L B t η B c B t DST Iw B t λ B a,t, (9) In equilibrium, sb is determined by (5), b by (3), h B by (6), while (8) and (7) determine the values of Lagrangian constraints. In the LTV-economy, (5) does not exist, b is determined by (6), sb by (3), and h B by (8).. Market clearing conditions The housing stock is fixed to : = h S t + h B t, () where h S denotes savers housing stock. c S t + c B t + i h = y t, () where c S t is savers consumption, and i h = δ h q t is investment in the housing stock. 3 Equilibrium and dynamic implications of multiple borrowing constraints 3. Calibration The model is calibrated to the Swedish data (see Table ). Housing depreciation rate is chosen to match the average LTV in the Swedish data: 65% (UC credit data). The values for DSTI and κ result in a debt to GDP ratio of 56%, similar to the value used in Finocchiaro et al. (6). Borrowers preference for housing J is chosen to match the debt to GDP ratio in the 4

Parameter Range β S savers discount factor.99 β B borrowers discount factor.98 δ h housing depreciation rate.76 LT V LTV ratio for new loans.85 DST I DSTI ratio for households.3 κ quarterly amortization rate. α savers wage share.85 η savers labor supply aversion η borrowers labor supply aversion J savers weight on housing. J borrowers weight on housing.55 Table : Benchmark calibration of the model LTV scenario. The remaining parameter values are fairly standard. 3. Equilibirum comparison Table presents equilibrium implications of two experiments: lowering LTV from 85% to 8% and the annual interest rate from 4.4% to % (through a change in savers discount factor) in the benchmark model and a model with LTV constraint only. In the benchmark model, lowering LTV has no effect on the debt to GDP or debt to income ratio, and it increases house prices in the equilibrium. In the LTV model, under lower LTV, debt to GDP and debt to income go down, and so do house prices. In the benchmark model, debt to income in the steady state is: SB W B L B = DST IW B L B (RS + κ )W B L B = In the LTV model, the same ratio is represented by: DST I RS + κ () SB W B L B = LT V QHB δ h κw B L B (3) It is clear from equation that in an environment, in which the debt limit is determined by a DSTI-constraint and LTV merely affects the housing choice of the household, lowering LTV is a very ineffective policy, if the aim is to reduce debt to income or debt to GDP. Similarly, lowering interest rates will push indebtedness up much more in such an environment than in a purely LTV-driven economy, in which the effect of interest rates on debt comes only indirectly through the effect on house prices. Stricter LTV policy in a multiconstraint framework not only 5

Variable LTV.85.8 Annual int.rate 4.4% % Benchmark model LTV model Benchmark model LTV model Debt to GDP/income % -7.66% +33.78% +9.97% House prices +.85% -.56% +37.69% +33.9% Output +.3% -.3% +.76% +.65% Borrowers housing +4.45% -.36% -.5% -8.37% Table : Long-term effects of lower LTV and interest rates does not influence debt ratios at all, but it also drives house prices up in the equlibrium. Ceteris paribus, if one unit of housing can pledge less collateral, its value has to increase if it has to collateralize the same amount of debt. 3.3 Model dynamics To investigate dynamic properties of the benchmark model, I consider a positive technology shock of % and an LTV shock that reduces LTV by %. Shocks are AR() processes with a persistence of 95%. Figure presents impulse responses to a positive technology shock. Households wage income increases, so they can reduce their labor supply. In the benchmark model, higher income from working enables borrowers to borrow more, so the stock of debt and their housing consumption increase, crowding out their goods consumption, more so than in an LTV model. With a relatively lower increase in aggregate consumption and similar house price dynamics, the output response in the benchmark model is less positive than in an LTV economy, and debt to GDP increases. Figure presents impulse responses to a negative LTV shock. In the benchmark economy, the change in LTV has almost no effect on the borrowing and debt to GDP (borrowing increases only slightly due to a decrease in interest rates). Lower LTV increases borrowers demand for housing, so house prices rise (similar to the equilibrium effect described in section 3.). Given increased housing consumption, borrowers consume less consumption goods and the output falls. In the LTV economy, a lower LTV drives the indebtedness down. Borrowers consume less housing, but more goods. With lower demand for housing, house prices fall. The analysis of the dynamic behaviour of benchmark and LTV economies shows that while the output response to different shocks may be similar, the behavior of borrowers in both economies is strikingly different. As such, while analyzing the role of the LTV constraint in a multiconstraint framework, it is crucial to account for other possible constraints that the borrowers might face. 6

. Impulse responses of the benchmark and LTV model to a technology shock house prices output aggregate consumption borrowers consumption...8.6.8.6.8.6.4.4.4 3... 4 borrowers housing stock borrowers labor supply stock of mortgage loans.5 debt to gdp.5.5.5.5 benchmark model LTV model 3 Notes: The impulse responses are measured in percentage deviations from steady state. Figure : Impulse responses after the technology shock 7

.5 Impulse responses of the benchmark and LTV model to an LTV shock house prices output aggregate consumption borrowers consumption..4.5..5....5...5..3.4 borrowers housing stock. borrowers labor supply stock of mortgage loans.. debt to gdp.5....4..4.4.5.6.6.6 benchmark model LTV model..8.8 Notes: The impulse responses are measured in percentage deviations from steady state. Figure : Impulse responses after the LTV shock 8

4 Conclusion I use a DSGE model with borrowers facing multiple constraints to show that the LTV limit can determine housing choices of individuals, and not their borrowing. If the actual debt is determined by a DSTI constraint and a LTV constraint is present, the latter becomes a residual condition, which takes debt limit as given. In such an economy, tighter LTV regulation will be ineffective in reducing households debt. It will increase house prices in equilibrium and not change the stock of debt at all. Interest rate movements will have a stronger impact on house prices and debt ratios in such environments, which may overturn some of the conclusions about the effectiveness of monetary vs LTV policy in addressing household indebtedness. Acknowledgement: I would like to thank Peter van Santen, Isaiah Hull and Daria Finocchiaro for comments. The views expressed in this paper are solely the responsibility of the author and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of Sveriges Riksbank. References ALPANDA, S., G. CATEAU, AND C. MEH (4): A Policy Model to Analyze Macroprudential Regulations and Monetary Policy, Bank of Canada Staff Working Papers. CHEN, J. AND F. COLUMBA (6): Macroprudential and Monetary Policy Interactions in a DSGE Model for Sweden, IMF Working Papers. CRAWFORD, A., C. MEH, AND J. ZHOU (3): The Residential Mortgage Market in Canada: A Primer, Bank of Canada Financial System Review, December. DE CARVALHO, F. A., M. R. CASTRO, AND S. M. A. COSTA (4): Traditional and matter-of-fact financial frictions in a DSGE model for Brazil: the role of macroprudential instruments and monetary policy, BIS Working Papers. EESTI PANK (4): Requirements for housing loans, Eesti Pank. FINOCCHIARO, D., M. JONSSON, C. NILSSON, AND I. STRID (6): Macroeconomic effects of reducing household debt, Sveriges Riksbank Economic Review. GREENWALD, D. (6): The Mortgage Credit Channel of Macroeconomic Transmission, Society for Economic Dynamics 6 Meeting Papers. SVERIGES RIKSBANK (4): From A to Z: the Swedish mortgage market and its role in the financial system, Sveriges Riksbank. 9