Economics 101A (Lecture 25) Stefano DellaVigna

Similar documents
Economics 101A (Lecture 26) Stefano DellaVigna

Economics 101A (Lecture 25) Stefano DellaVigna

Economics 101A (Lecture 24) Stefano DellaVigna

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

Market Failure: Asymmetric Information

Insurance, Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Asymmetric Information

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 8: Insurance Markets

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 17 Sections 17.1 and 17.2 Asymmetric information can cause a competitive equilibrium allocation to be inefficient.

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Final Exam Suggested Solutions

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Moral Hazard Example. 1. The Agent s Problem. contract C = (w, w) that offers the same wage w regardless of the project s outcome.

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

UNCERTAINTY AND INFORMATION

Asymmetric Information and the Role of Financial intermediaries

JEFF MACKIE-MASON. x is a random variable with prior distrib known to both principal and agent, and the distribution depends on agent effort e

Chapter Eleven. Chapter 11 The Economics of Financial Intermediation Why do Financial Intermediaries Exist

Lecture 26 Exchange Rates The Financial Crisis. Noah Williams

Mohammad Hossein Manshaei 1394

Economics 101A (Lecture 21) Stefano DellaVigna

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

How do we cope with uncertainty?

The role of asymmetric information

Chapter 9 THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Revision Lecture. MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

EXAMPLE OF FAILURE OF EQUILIBRIUM Akerlof's market for lemons (P-R pp )

A brief introduction to economics

Economics 101A (Lecture 21) Stefano DellaVigna

Practice Problems. w U(w, e) = p w e 2,

Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Practice Problems. U(w, e) = p w e 2,

A brief introduction to economics. Outline. Reading reminder. Risk attitude example (take 3): antivirus software. Notes. Notes. Notes. Notes.

Noncooperative Market Games in Normal Form

Lecture 6 Dynamic games with imperfect information

Economics Honors Exam Review (Micro) Mar Based on Zhaoning Wang s final review packet for Ec 1010a, Fall 2013

Moral Hazard. Economics Microeconomic Theory II: Strategic Behavior. Instructor: Songzi Du

The Economics of Public Policy 7. Market Failures due to Asymmetric Information

ASHORTCOURSEIN INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS WITH CALCULUS. allan

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Section 9, Chapter 2 Moral Hazard and Insurance

Intermediate Macroeconomics

Uncertainty. The St. Petersburg Paradox. Managerial Economics MBACatólica

Principal-agent examples

II. Determinants of Asset Demand. Figure 1

Where do securities come from

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Lecture 25 Unemployment Financial Crisis. Noah Williams

Microeconomics (Uncertainty & Behavioural Economics, Ch 05)

Optimal Auctions. Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham

ECON Microeconomics II IRYNA DUDNYK. Auctions.

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Comprehensive Exam

Answer Key: Problem Set 4

Introduction to Economics I: Consumer Theory

The Financial System. Instructor: Prof. Menzie Chinn UW Madison

Financial markets in developing countries (rough notes, use only as guidance; more details provided in lecture) The role of the financial system

Market for Lemons. Market Failure Asymmetric Information. Problem Setup

CONTRACT THEORY. Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont. The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England

Lecture Note: Monitoring, Measurement and Risk. David H. Autor MIT , Fall 2003 November 13, 2003

Recap First-Price Revenue Equivalence Optimal Auctions. Auction Theory II. Lecture 19. Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 1

Efficiency Wage. Economics of Information and Contracts Moral Hazard: Applications and Extensions. Financial Contracts. Financial Contracts

Economics 502 April 3, 2008

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information

w E(Q w) w/100 E(Q w) w/

Price Theory Lecture 9: Choice Under Uncertainty

Problem Set 5 Answers

Concentrating on reason 1, we re back where we started with applied economics of information

Sequential-move games with Nature s moves.

Introductory to Microeconomic Theory [08/29/12] Karen Tsai

Microeconomics I. Undergraduate Programs in Business Administration and Economics

1. The precise formula for the variance of a portfolio of two securities is: where

Moral Hazard. Economics Microeconomic Theory II: Strategic Behavior. Shih En Lu. Simon Fraser University (with thanks to Anke Kessler)

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 7: Moral Hazard. Patrick Legros

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Agenda. Asymmetric information. Asymmetric information. TIØ4285 Produkjons- og nettverksøkonomi. Lecture 7

Maximizing the value of the firm is the goal of managing capital structure.

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives

Efficient provision of a public good

Prof. Bryan Caplan Econ 812

CASE FAIR OSTER PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS E L E V E N T H E D I T I O N. PEARSON 2012 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

Lecture Notes - Insurance

Mock Examination 2010

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

Solution Problem Set 2

Lecture 3 ( 3): April 20 and 22, 2004 Demand, Supply, and Price Stiglitz: pp

Noncooperative Oligopoly

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 6. Separation of Ownership and Control

4 Rothschild-Stiglitz insurance market

978 J.-J. LAFFONT, H. OSSARD, AND Q. WONG

Dynamic games with incomplete information

Lecture 1 Definitions from finance

Transcription:

Economics 101A (Lecture 25) Stefano DellaVigna April 29, 2014

Outline 1. Hidden Action (Moral Hazard) II 2. The Takeover Game 3. Hidden Type (Adverse Selection) 4. Evidence of Hidden Type and Hidden Action

1 Hidden Action (Moral Hazard) II Back to Principal-Agent problem Solve problem in three Steps, starting from last stage (backward induction) Step1(Effort Decision). Given contract ( ) what effort is agent going to put in? Step2.(Individual Rationality) Given contract ( ) and anticipating to put in effort does agent accept the contract? Step3.(Profit Maximization) Anticipating that the effort of the agent (and the acceptance of the contract) will depend on the contract, what contract ( ) does principal choose to maximize profits?

Step 1. Solve effort maximization of agent: + 2 2 2 ( ) Solution: 0 ( ) = If assume ( ) = 2 2 = Check comparative statics With respect to What happens with more pay-for-performance? With respect to What happens with higher cost of effort?

Step 2. Agent needs to be willing to work for principal Individual rationality condition: ( ( )) ( ) 0 Substitute in the solution for and obtain + 2 2 2 ( ) 0 Will be satisfied with equality: = + 2 2 2 + ( )

Step 3: Owner maximizes expected profits max [ ] = [ ( )] = Substitute in the two constraints: 0 ( ) = (Step 1) and = + 2 2 2 + ( ) (Step 2) Obtain [ ] = µ + 2 2 2 + ( ) 0 ( ) = + 2 2 2 ( ) 0 ( ) = + 0 ( ) 2 ³ 0 ( ) 2 2 ( ) 0 ( ) = 2 ³ 0 ( ) 2 2 ( ) Profit maximization yields f.o.c. 1 0 ( ) 2 00 ( ) 0 ( ) =0

and hence 0 ( )= 1 1+ 2 00 ( ) Notice: This implies 0 ( ) 1 Substitute ( ) = 2 2 to get = 1 1 1+ 2 Comparative Statics: Higher risk aversion... Higher variance of output... Higher effort cost...

Also, remember = 0 ( )= and hence = = 1 1 1+ 2 = 1 1+ 2 Notice 0 1: Agent gets paid increasing function of output to incentivize Does not get paid one-on-one ( =1) because that would pass on too much risk to agent (Remember = + = + + ) Comparative Statics: what happens to if = 0 or =0?Interpret

Consider solution when effort is observable This is so-called first best since it eliminates the uncertainty involved in connecting pay to performance (as opposed to effort) Principal offers a flat wage = as long as agent works Agent accepts job if ( ) 0 Principal wants to pay minimal necessary and hence sets = ( ) Substitute into profit of principal max [ ] = [ ( )] = = ( ) Solution for : 0 ( )=1or =1

Compare above and in first best With observable effort (first best) agent works harder

Summary of hidden-action solution with risk-averse agent: Risk-incentive trade-off: Agent needs to be incentivized ( 0) or will not put in effort Cannot give too much incentive ( too high) because of risk-aversion Trade-off solved if Action observable OR No risk aversion ( =0)OR No noise in outcome ( 2 =0) Otherwise, effort in equilibrium is sub-optimal Same trade-off applies to other cases

Example 2: Insurance (Not fully solved) Two states of the world: Loss and No Loss Probability of Loss is ( ) with 0 ( ) 0 Example: Careful driving (Car Insurance) Example: Maintaining your house better (House insurance) Agent chooses quantity of insurance purchased Agent risk averse: ( ) with 0 0 and 00 0

Qualitative solution: No hidden action Full insurance: = Hiddenaction Trade-off risk-incentives Only Partial insurance 0 Need to make agent partially responsible for accident to incentivize Do not want to make too responsible because of risk-aversion

2 Takeover Game The Takeover Game (Samuelson and Bazerman, 1985) See hand-out

3 Hidden Type (Adverse Selection) Nicholson, Ch. 18, pp. 671-672. Solution of Take-over game When does seller sell? If bid profitable ( ) Profit of buyer? 1 5 BUT: Must take into account strategic behavior of seller Solution: [ ( )] = ( [1 5 ] ) Pr( ) = µ1 5 2 Pr( ) = 25 Pr( ) Derive First order condition Solution: =0!

No market for take-overs, despite clear benefits. Why?

First type of asymmetric information problems: Hidden Action (Moral Hazard) Manager can shirk when she is supposed to work hard. Second type of asymmetric information problems: HiddenType(AdverseSelection) Informational problem: one party knows more than the other party. Example 1: wisdom teeth extraction (Doctors are very prone to recommend extraction. Is it necessary? Or do they just want to make money. Likely too many wisdom teeth extracted.) Example 2: finding a good mechanic. (Most people don t have any idea if they are being told the truth. People can shop around, but this has considerable cost. Because of this, mechanics can sometimes inflate prices)

Lemons Problem Classic asymmetric information situation is called Lemons Problem (Akerlof, 1970) on used car market Idea: Ifyou resoanxioussoselltomedoi really want to buy this? Simple model: The market for cars has two types, regular cars (probability ) and lemons (probability 1 ). To seller, regular cars are worth $1000, lemons are worth $500. To potential buyer, regular cars are worth $1500 and lemons worth $750.

Which cars should be sold (from efficiency perspective)? All cars should be sold since more valuable to buyer. BUT: buyers do not know type of car, sellers do know Solve in two stages (backward induction): Stage 2: Determine buyers willingness to pay Stage 1: Determine selling strategy of sellers Stage 2. What are buyers WTP? Expected car value = 1500 + (1 )750 = 750 + 750 Notice: is expected probability that car sold is regular (can differ from )

Buyer willing to pay up to =750+ 750 Stage 1. Seller has to decide which car to sell Sell lemon if 500 = 750 + 750 YES for all Sell regular car if 1000 =750+ 750 1 3 Two equilibria 1. If 1 3: Sell both types of cars = 1 3 =750+ 750 2. If 1 3: Sell only lemons = 0 =750 Market for cars can degenerate: Only lemons sold

Conclusion: the existence of undetectable lemons may collapse the market for good used cars Basic message: If sellers know more than buyers, buyers must account for what a seller s willingness to trade at a price tells them about hidden information Same issues apply to: Car Insurance. If offer full insurance, only bad drivers take it Salary. If offer no salary incentives, only lowquality workers apply

4 Evidence of Hidden Type and Hidden Action Consider asymmetric information in lending market (Karlan-Zinman, 2007) Lenders offer different borrowing rates High interest rates Adverse selection: Tend to select bad borrowers Moral Hazard: Borrowers have incentive to defaultonloan Both forms of asymmetric information lead to defaults Separate the two:

Randomize high and low credit offer To some (randomized) high-offer consumers, lower rate ex-post To some (randomized) high-offer consumers, offer incentives to keep good credit (can keep loan ex post if repay in time

Timing: Results:

Substantial effect of incentives to keep good credit (moral hazard) Some effect of adverse selection Importance of field experiment: Can do controlled test of theory

Summary of how to separate moral hazard and adverseselectionincreditcardborrowing Adverse Selection. Compare two groups Offered rate and gets Offered rate and gets This holds constant final offer ( )andvaries initial offer Adverse Selection Moral Hazard. Compare two groups Offered rate and gets Offered rate and gets This holds constant initial offer ( )andvaries final offer Moral hazard