"FOREIGN" BEHAVIOR FOR THE U.S.? Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer 1988 Kickoff Breakfast Greater St. Louis U.S. Savings Bonds Drive March 2, 1988

Similar documents
"FOREIGN" BEHAVIOR FOR THE U.S.? Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer Rotary Club of Paducah September 14, 1988

TRUE FACTS AND FALSE PERCEPTIONS ABOUT FEDERAL DEFICITS" Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer Rotary Club of Springfield, Missouri December 6, 1988

THE SHRINKING CURRENT ACCOUNT DEFICIT: Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer St. Louis Society of Financial Analysts St. Louis, Missouri May 28, 1992

The Benefits of World Capital Flows

Trade deficits and the US economy Part I

FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS*

18 INTERNATIONAL FINANCE* Chapter. Key Concepts

Normalizing Monetary Policy

Helpful Hint Fiscal Policy and the AS-AD Model

Economic Barometer. Mixed Signals. Labor Market Improvement Household Demand Household Demand Continued Business Demand

10 Chapter Outline What is Keynesianism?

Rebalancing Toward Sustainable Growth. Thomas M. Hoenig President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

HOW CAN THE FED INFLUENCE INTEREST RATES AND SUSTAIN GROWTH? Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer President, Federal Reserve Bank of St.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES U.S. GROWTH IN THE DECADE AHEAD. Martin S. Feldstein. Working Paper

Masaaki Shirakawa: The transition from high growth to stable growth Japan s experience and implications for emerging economies

Small Business Lending Roundtable Committee on Small Business United States House of Representatives

Lecture #8: How Scary is the US Trade Deficit?

DEFICITS DEBT AND DEFICITS: WHAT ARE THEY? . i:

THE NEW ECONOMY RECESSION: ECONOMIC SCORECARD 2001

The Federal Reserve and Monetary Policy 1

INCREASING THE RATE OF CAPITAL FORMATION (Investment Policy Report)

Ewart S Williams: Understanding the Heritage and Stabilisation Fund

JAPAN s CURRENT FINANCIAL & ECONOMIC CRISIS. AContrarianView?

Monetary Policy and Economic Outcomes *

International Finance

DEBT-EQUITY SWAPS. Euromoney-Mexico Debt to Equity Conversion and Investment Conference. Mexico City, May 26-27, 1987.

HOMEWORK 7 (NATIONAL INCOME ACCOUNTING) ECO41 FALL 2013 UDAYAN ROY

How Is Global Trade Financed? (EA)

AND INVESTMENT * Chapt er. Key Concepts

Some Observations on Fiscal Imbalances and Monetary Policy

CHINA IN THE WORLD PODCAST. Host: Paul Haenle Guest: Yukon Huang

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 4

Appropriate monetary policy and the strong economy Before the Committee on Banking and Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives July 23, 1997

DEBTS AND DISPUTES. Understanding Debt. What to do?

The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit

In our recent discussion of the Common Market we stated that. economic and political factors often are just as important as military

FED POLICY POST OCTOBER 6. Remarks by. David P. Eastburn. President. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. Before the. Philadelphia Chapter

Lyle E. Gramley MEMBER, BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM. Conrnunity Leaders in Seattle

Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments

Understanding Inflation: Getting Back to Basics

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

Remarks by James K. Galbraith at the Economists for Peace and. Security Bernard Schwartz Symposium on Jobs, Investment and Energy.

Welcome again to our Farm Management and Finance educational series. Borrowing money is something that is a necessary aspect of running a farm or

Ian J Macfarlane: Payment imbalances

William C Dudley: A bit better, but very far from best US economic outlook and the challenges facing the Federal Reserve

Policy Note 2000/6 Drowning In Debt

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

MONEY. Economics Unit 4 Macroeconomics Just the Facts Handout

This is The Whole Truth about Trade Imbalances, chapter 3 from the book Policy and Theory of International Finance (index.html) (v. 1.0).

The U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy. Esther L. George President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

Haruhiko Kuroda: Japan s economy and monetary policy

The fiscal adjustment after the crisis in Argentina

Lars Nyberg: Developments in the property market

ECO403 Macroeconomics Solved Online Quiz For Midterm Exam Preparation Spring 2013

Answer each question. For full credit, provide an explanation or show work.

Flows between sectors. Over a given period of time, income flows and spending flows run within each sector and between sectors.

GOVERNMENT DEFICITS, MONETARY POLICY, AND INFLATION Remarks by Darryl R. Francis, President. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

From The Collected Works of Milton Friedman, compiled and edited by Robert Leeson and Charles G. Palm.

Are we on the road to recovery?

A Look at the Regional and National Economies

Monetary Policy in the Wake of the Crisis Olivier Blanchard

Ch. 2 AN OVERVIEW OF THE FINANCIAL SYSTEM

What Should the Fed Do?

The Social Security Protection Plan

Data Brief. Dangerous Trends: The Growth of Debt in the U.S. Economy

Short run prospects in Europe and the United States

An old stock market saying is, "Bulls can make money, bears can make money, but pigs end up getting slaughtered.

FAQ: Money and Banking

Micro versus Macro PP542. National Income Accounts. Micro versus Macro (cont.) National Income Accounts: GNP. National Income Accounts: GNP (cont.

Separating European Austerity Fact from Fiction A Lesson for the U.S. on Why Budget Cutting Works

How costly is for Spain to be in the EURO?

Japan's Economy and Monetary Policy

Economy In Crisis: How Global Financial Crisis Affects India & The World?

Answers to Questions: Chapter 5

Precarious to prosperous: Tackling income volatility in Canada. Bharat Masrani Group President and Chief Executive Officer, TD Bank Group

Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy

This is Policy Effects with Floating Exchange Rates, chapter 10 from the book Policy and Theory of International Finance (index.html) (v. 1.0).

A News and Notes Exclusive

On Financial Crisis and Economic Recovery Plan. delivered 24 September 2008

Gauging Current Conditions:

Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit

THE NEW, NEW ECONOMICS AND MONETARY POLICY. Remarks Prepared by Darryl R. Francis, President. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Economics of Money, Banking, and Fin. Markets, 10e (Mishkin) Chapter 3 What Is Money? 3.1 Meaning of Money

Joseph S Tracy: A strategy for the 2011 economic recovery

2. Suppose a family s annual disposable income is $8000 of which it saves $2000. (a) What is their APC?

I don't understand the argument that even though inflation is not accelerating, the world nevertheless suffers from "global excess liquidity":

by David P. Eastburn President, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia before THE PHILADELPHIA JAYCEES at the "First Thursday Luncheon"

DEFICITS AND DEBT Macroeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Stock Market Behavior Models for the Day

The Great Depression: An Overview by David C. Wheelock

International Monetary Policy

MINISTRY OF EDUCATION AND SCIENCE OF UKRAINE NATIONAL TECHNICAL UNIVERSITY KHARKIV POLYTECHNIC INSTITUTE

Answers to Problem Set #6 Chapter 14 problems

Financing the U.S. Trade Deficit

Objectives for Chapter 24: Monetarism (Continued) Chapter 24: The Basic Theory of Monetarism (Continued) (latest revision October 2004)

Lower prices. Lower costs, esp. wages. Higher productivity. Higher quality/more desirable exports. Greater natural resources. Higher interest rates

Student Name(Please print):

102 FEDERAL RESERVE BULLETIN FEBRUARY 1938

Macroeconomics: Principles, Applications, and Tools

13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Chapter. Key Concepts

Transcription:

SAVING: "FOREIGN" BEHAVIOR FOR THE U.S.? Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer 1988 Kickoff Breakfast Greater St. Louis U.S. Savings Bonds Drive March 2, 1988 I am pleased to have this opportunity to say a few words about the general importance of saving and why we, as a nation, need to increase our savings at the present time. Throughout history, saving has been characterized as truly virtuous behavior. In recent years, however, I am sorry to say, savings behavior in the U.S. has not been all that virtuous. Since 1982, as a nation, we have saved, on average, about 2.3 percent of our income each year. Our national net savings rate is not only down sharply from its 6.6 percent average rate in the late 1970s; it is also abysmally low when compared to national net savings rates in other industrialized countries. For example, in recent years, national savings rates in Japan have run about 17 percent; in England, they have been about 20 percent. While these rates may be a bit overstated due to differences in measurement, there is still a whopping imbalance. Now, it might be easy to say "so what?" when we are confronted with comparisons showing how low this nation ranks in terms of its savings. After all, we are now entering the sixth year of the current expansion. Since 1982, more than 15 million new jobs have been created; and over this period, our real output growth has averaged better than four percent per year. However, such a quick-and-easy dismissal of our failure to save more would be a serious mistake. Our lack of saving in this decade has come to be viewed with alarm by many people for reasons that relate closely to our national self-interest.

- 2 - The problem we face is simple to state, but difficult to solve satisfactorily as long as our savings rate remains low. Our problem is where to find the funds to provide for private investment, on the one hand, and to cover our federal deficit, on the other. As you well know, investment is vital to maintaining economic growth and, thereby, providing for continued expansion of jobs and income in this country. The record of continuing growth since 1982 could not have been achieved if, in recent years, we had not spent about 16 percent of our GNP on gross private domestic investment. gross investment totalled nearly $720 billion. Last year, for example, This year, we will need to spend even more if our expansion is to continue into the future. Another activity that absorbs funds is our federal deficit. When government spending exceeds its tax receipts and other revenues, the additional funds must come from someone. During the 1980s, federal deficits have grown to substantial proportions. Last year, for example, the federal deficit exceeded $150 billion the sixth triple-digit deficit in a row. And, despite all our good intentions to the contrary, it appears that large federal deficits will be with us for some time still to come. Whether federal deficits are "good" or "bad" per se is not important to the point 1 want to make. My point is simply that someone is going to have to provide the funds to cover them someone is going to have to buy those government bonds. And given the sheer size of our federal deficits, a shortfall in funding could "squeeze out" private investment to a significant extent.

- 3 - Now, "the $870 billion dollar question," to use last year's total gross investment and federal deficit figure, is who is going to provide the funds necessary to finance these requirements? There are only three potential sources of funds available for this purpose: our own domestic savings, the savings of foreigners, and government bond purchases by the Federal Reserve System. Does it matter to us who provides these funds? The only way to answer this is to look at the consequences of each of these sources of financing. Let's start with our own domestic savings. People save by spending less on consumption goods than they earn in income. We save for a variety of reasons: to provide for retirement, in anticipation of those nasty "rainy days", to purchase big-ticket items like cars and houses, and to leave bequests. Saving is a conscious effort to spend less now so that we can spend more in the future. Last year, our personal savings totalled $120 billion, about 2.7 percent of our GNP. This is less than 14 percent of the funds that were spent on investment and the federal deficit. Thankfully, there are other sources of domestic savings in addition to our personal savings. Gross business savings contributed more than $550 billion; state and local government surpluses added another $45 billion. Thus, in total, we saved about $720 billion of the $870 billion that was spent to fund U.S. investment and the federal deficit last year. Now, "where in the world" did the other $150 billion come from? That is exactly where the rest of the world. When people in one nation save more than their own current investment spending and government

- 4 - deficits, these additional savings will flow to where the demand for them is the greatest. Because we do not save enough to fund our own investment and government deficits, we have had to rely on the savings of our friends abroad. Last year, foreigners bought, on net, about $150 billion of U.S. securities, equities and government bonds. But the process of attracting foreign savings is not costless; nor, can it last forever. To purchase dollar-denominated securities, bonds and equities, foreigners first had to acquire these dollars. In the process, they bid up the dollar's value. The increased value of the dollar encourages more imports and discourages exports the trade deficit that ensues provides the necessary dollars for foreign investment in the U.S. Thus, for every dollar of foreign savings we attracted, our trade deficit increased by one dollar. Last year alone, our trade deficit reached approximately $150 billion. This figure is no coincidence. It represents precisely the $150 billion worth of our investment and government deficit that was financed by foreigners. Now, should we worry if foreigners want to channel their savings into the U.S.? Perhaps, as long as this flow of foreign savings continues unabated, we don't have to be overly concerned. It's true, of course, that import-competing and export industries suffer a reduction in output and employment, but other industries pick up the slack. Certainly, this is what has happened since 1982; despite our large trade deficits in recent years, our output and employment have grown at historical rates and our unemployment rate has declined substantially.

- 5 - So why worry? Well, like all borrowing, our foreign debt eventually must be repaid. Currently, we owe foreigners, on net, around $450 billion, and this amount is rising rapidly. When it comes time to repay our debt, we as a nation, like all such debtors, will have to tighten our belts; we'll have to consume less in order to repay. This means, as we repay our foreign debt, that our standard of living will be significantly lower than it would have been otherwise. Whether our economy will be forced to undergo a period of very low growth to repay these debts depends on how productively we have used these foreign borrowings. One thing, however, is certain; repayment will not be painless. And, unless we can start to reduce the pace of growth of our foreign indebtedness, the pain will be all the more severe. A third possible source of financing is the Federal Reserve. The Fed, in the normal course of conducting monetary policy, purchases and sells government securities. This process is called open market operations. It represents the day-in and day-out manner by which the Federal Reserve adjusts the nation's bank reserves and the money stock. Occasionally, someone or other suggests that the Federal Reserve should buy even larger amounts of government debt and thus reduce the amount of domestic and foreign saving that is necessary. The chief problem with this "solution" is that, when the Fed buys government securities, it pays for these securities with newly-created money. If this "monetizing the deficit" were done on the scale necessary to impact meaningfully our need for savings, the result would be both perfectly predictable and catastrophic in the extreme. In no time at all, we would have high inflation, high interest rates and a general collapse of domestic financial markets. "Chaotic" would be a mild description of the consequence of such actions.

- 6 - Now, I'm not trying to scare you into saving more by threatening financial ruin if we don't raise our savings rate. All available evidence suggests that the Federal Reserve has not followed a policy of monetizing the deficit in the past, and we are certainly not going to do so in the future for the very reasons that I've just mentioned. My purpose for listing the potential options is to convince you how important it is for us, as a nation, to save more and to start to do so now. Let us review the possibilities. We can allow our investment to decline drastically and forego economic growth far into the future. Clearly, that is not desirable and is something to be avoided at all costs. We can reduce the government deficit. But that does not seem to be probable given our experience of the past several years. Thus, it seems that we have to assume that the rate of investment and the deficit are given, and the real options are to finance it through domestic or foreign savings. Financing these expenditures through foreign savings implies a continuous trade deficit and ultimately an adjustment problem which may arise now or sometime in the future. It seems to me that the adjustment problem has already begun. Foreigners have become more reluctant to lend to us. This reluctance is clearly demonstrated by the decline in the dollar exchange rate since 1985 and by the decline of private foreign investment in the U.S. In the past year, about a third of our trade deficit was financed by foreign central banks in their attempt to prevent the dollar from declining even further. What if even the central banks become reluctant? The dollar would fall more precipitously and real interest rates would have to rise.

- 7 - The rise in interest rates would ultimately increase savings, but it would also reduce investment and add to the volatility of financial markets. There is no doubt that market forces will eventually solve the savings and investment problem, and there is no doubt that eventually the savings disparity and the international balance would be resolved. But at what cost? On the other hand, if we were to save more at current interest rates, or foreigners were to save less, much of the adjustment pain could be alleviated. The dollar would stabilize, interest rates would not have to rise, and investment would not have to be curtailed. Thus, while we have always looked upon saving as an individual virtue, at this time it has become a national priority. We simply must increase our domestic savings. And buying savings bonds is a good way to do so. And now is a good time to start.