POLICY BRIEF. Making Work Pay for Public Housing Residents Learning from the Jobs-Plus Demonstration

Similar documents
The Employment Experiences of Public Housing Residents

Promoting Work in Public Housing

MDRC Working Papers on Research Methodology

Federal Minimum Wage, Tax-Transfer Earnings Supplements, and Poverty

Post-TANF Food Stamp and Medicaid Benefits: Factors That Aid or Impede Their Receipt

A DECADE OF WELFARE REFORM: FACTS AND FIGURES

POVERTY AND WELFARE: THE GAO REPORT

PaycheckPLUS: Early Lessons from Testing an Earnings Supplement for Single Adults. Caroline Schultz, MDRC

Housing Assistance and the Effects of Welfare Reform

WAYS THAT STATES CAN SERVE FAMILIES THAT REACH WELFARE TIME LIMITS. by Liz Schott

HUD Seeks Significant Improvements to Moving to Work Demonstration, But Additional Changes Needed

Funding Bill and Carryover Funding Should Enable Agencies to Issue More Housing Vouchers in 2019

WORKING P A P E R. The Returns to Work for Children Leaving the SSI- Disabled Children Program RICHARD V. BURKHAUSER AND MARY C.

The Self-Sufficiency Project at 36 Months: Effects of a Financial Work Incentive on Employment and Income Executive Summary

The Ins and Outs of Delinking: Promoting Medicaid Enrollment of Children Who are Moving In and Out of the TANF System. March 1999.

FOOD STAMP USE AMONG FORMER WELFARE RECIPIENTS. Cynthia Miller Cindy Redcross Christian Henrichson. February 2002

Poverty in Our Time. The Challenges and Opportunities of Fighting Poverty in Virginia. Executive Summary. By Michael Cassidy and Sara Okos

Two Steps Forward and Three Steps Back The Cliff Effect Colorado s Curious Penalty for Increased Earnings

It is estimated that more than 20,000 Individual

The Earned Income Tax Credit, Welfare Reform, and the Employment of Low Skill Single Mothers

EID Frequently Asked Questions 2013

WikiLeaks Document Release

MORE THAN HALF OF BLACK AND HISPANIC FAMILIES WOULD NOT BENEFIT FROM BUSH TAX PLAN. by Isaac Shapiro, Allen Dupree and James Sly

INTRODUCTION NEW YORK STATE SURPLUS SPENDING. Continued on page 4. New York State Programmed TANF Surplus (Dollars in millions)

Ensuring NAHMA Members Receive the Latest News and Analysis of Breaking Issues in Affordable Housing

New Federalism National Survey of America s Families

FARM BILL CONTAINS SIGNIFICANT DOMESTIC NUTRITION IMPROVEMENTS By Dorothy Rosenbaum 1

HOW WILL UNINSURED CHILDREN BE AFFECTED BY HEALTH REFORM?

THE BENEFITS PLANNER KEYS TO EFFECTIVE BENEFITS PLANNING, ASSISTANCE AND OUTREACH

Community Investments Vol 15, Issue 3 Reclaiming Native American Tax Dollars

How the Ross Plan Would Raise Rents on HUD-Assisted Households

Does Work Pay? An Analysis of the Work Incentives under TANF

Tracking Report. Trends in U.S. Health Insurance Coverage, PUBLIC INSURANCE COVERAGE GAIN OFFSETS SIGNIFICANT EMPLOYER COVERAGE DECLINE

A $7.25 MINIMUM WAGE WOULD BE A USEFUL STEP IN HELPING WORKING FAMILIES ESCAPE POVERTY by Jason Furman and Sharon Parrott

Between a Rock and a Hard Place: A Closer Look at Cliff Effects in Massachusetts

214 Massachusetts Ave. N.E Washington D.C (202) TESTIMONY. Medicaid Expansion

Multiple Jeopardy? The impacts of the UK Government s proposed welfare reforms on women in Scotland

Welfare Reform Bill 2011

Does It Pay to Move from Welfare to Work? A Comment on Danziger, Heflin, Corcoran, Oltmans, and Wang. Robert Moffitt Katie Winder

Key State TANF Policies Affecting Microenterprise. California

A Working Families Credit for Washington State

by sheldon danziger and rucker c. johnson

What s in the FY 2011 Budget for Health Care?

Why TANF Is Not a Model for Other Safety Net Programs

SENIOR BULLETIN: SSI/GAU. Supplied shelter, clothing or food and its effect on SSI

NCCP is publishing this research brief at a time when a

Economic Insecurity. Implications of Federal Budget Proposals for Low-Income Working Families. Nancy K. Cauthen Kinsey Alden Dinan.

Making Work Pay in Illinois

MEDICAID ELIGIBLE, BUT UNINSURED: THE NEW YORK STATE EXPERIENCE

TRENDS IN FSP PARTICIPATION RATES: FOCUS ON SEPTEMBER 1997

Testimony of Yaida Ford, Staff Attorney. Legal Aid Society of the District of Columbia 1

Eligibility for Child Care Subsidies of Parents with Child Support Income

IWPR R345 February The Female Face of Poverty and Economic Insecurity: The Impact of the Recession on Women in Pennsylvania and Pittsburgh MSA

ISSUES AND OPTIONS FOR STATES

ECONOMIC PROSPECTS Making the Federal Minimum Wage a Living Wage

Fact Sheet. For HUD Assisted Residents Project-Based Section 8. How Your Rent is Determined

Lessons from Welfare-to-Work Experiments and Related Studies. Secretaries Innovation Group November 15, 2016 James A. Riccio

IRELAND. to be fully unemployed for at least 3 days in any period of 6 consecutive days;

Increasing the EITC Will Boost New Jersey s Workers and Their Families

California has one of the largest economies in the world and is home to incredible prosperity,

Health Insurance Coverage in California in 2013 and 2014, After Implementation of the Affordable Care Act, p. 2

The State of the Safety Net in the Post- Welfare Reform Era

CLAIM YOUR CREDIT! Policy Brief

AMERICANS OPPOSE PROPOSALS TO RESTRICT ELIGIBILITY AND CUT FUNDING FOR GOVERNMENT ASSISTANCE PROGRAMS

Chart Book: TANF at 20

MEDI CAR E ISS UE B R I E F

Can the changes to LHA achieve their aims in London s housing market?

FACT SHEET. How Your Rent Is Determined. For Public Housing And Housing Choice Voucher Programs. Office of Public and Indian Housing.

STATE OF WORKING ARIZONA

Estimating the Potential Impacts of the Administration s Fiscal Year 2018 Budget Proposal on Safety Net Programs Using Microsimulation

Analysis of Food Stamp and Medical Assistance Caseload Reductions in Milwaukee County:

The 2014 Rhode Island Standard of Need What it costs to live in Rhode Island and how work supports help families meet basic needs

Tax Policy Issues and Options

The Family Transition Program Implementation and Three-Year Impacts of Florida's Initial Time-Limited Welfare Program

Research & Policy Brief Number 4 December 2009

The Brookings Institution

How a State EITC Could Reduce Economic Hardship in California. A PRESENTATION BY CHRIS HOENE CALIFORNIA BUDGET PROJECT FEBRUARY 2015 cbp.

THE WHITE HOUSE Office of the Press Secretary EMBARGOED FOR 8:00PM EST SATURDAY, JANUARY 17, 2015

THE UNITED STATES 2007

FINANCE COMMITTEE MAKES FLAWED EMPLOYER REQUIREMENT IN HEALTH REFORM BILL STILL MORE PROBLEMATIC

Economic Security Programs Cut Poverty Nearly in Half Over Last 50 Years, New Data Show

Supporting Work in Illinois The Challenges Ahead

mdrc IMPLEMENTATION AND EARLY IMPACTS OF THE WORK ADVANCEMENT AND SUPPORT CENTER (WASC) DEMONSTRATION Cynthia Miller Betsy L. Tessler Mark Van Dok

Pension Wealth Peaks at Age 55 (Figure 1)

TANF at 20: Time to Create a Program that Supports Work and Helps Families Meet Their Basic Needs

Chairman Currie, Vice-Chairman Hogan, and members of the committee:

Making Work Really Pay: Income Support & Marginal Effective Tax Rates Among Low-Income Working Households

Options for Increasing the Incomes of Manitoba EIA Participants

JAPAN. Minimum of 6 months of insured work in the last 12 months, with minimum 20 hours of work per week.

B u d g e t B r i e f

Medicaid Spending: A Brief History

Medicare in Ryan s 2014 Budget By Paul N. Van de Water

REDUCING POVERTY AND PROMOTING SOCIAL INCLUSION

Basic income as a policy option: Technical Background Note Illustrating costs and distributional implications for selected countries

Position Paper on Income and Wages Approved August 4, 2016

Interim Cost-Benefit Analysis of the Compass Family Self- Sufficiency (FSS) Program

Obamacare Tax Subsidies: Bigger Deficit, Fewer Taxpayers, Damaged Economy

Denver Supportive Housing Social Impact Bond Initiative: Housing Stability Outcomes

The Cross-State Study of Time-Limited Welfare Welfare Time Limits: An Interim Report Card. Dan Bloom

Governor Gregoire s Rainy Day Fund Proposal:

Transcription:

Making Work Pay for Public Housing Residents Learning from the Jobs-Plus Demonstration James A. Riccio and Steven Bliss POLICY BRIEF APRIL 2002 JOBSPLUS RESIDENTS of the nation s public housing developments have long suffered disproportionately from perverse disincentives to work. Under traditional public housing policies, their rents were automatically ratcheted up in lock step with any income increase they realized from earnings, even in a low-wage job. Work often promised them little financial gain. But a series of reforms over the past decade in welfare and tax policies, as well as in housing policies have tipped the financial balance more in favor of work, perhaps to a degree that is not fully appreciated by many public housing residents and administrators. Still, some important disincentives remain. This policy brief, one in a continuing series 1 that presents emerging insights from the Jobs-Plus demonstration, discusses innovative attempts to bring public housing rent policies more fully into line with reforms in welfare and tax policies designed to make work pay. 2 The rationale underlying the Jobs-Plus approach is reinforced by a growing body of research on welfare families showing that policies that allow low-wage workers to keep more of their SUMMARY benefits or receive earnings supplements can help raise employment and earnings, reduce poverty, and increase the well-being of young children. Jobs-Plus is an innovative place-based employment initiative for public housing residents that mixes new rent-based work incentives with employment and training services and neighbor-to-neighbor social supports for work. 3 The Jobs-Plus rent reforms build on the non-housing reform policies of the 1990s and push further in this direction. They help to ensure that full-time work will leave a family with more net income than part-time work (which has not always been the case), and that a full-time job will raise income above what that same job would yield under the old rent policies. Jobs-Plus anticipated some of the key reforms of the Quality Housing and Work Responsibility Act, passed by Congress in 1998. The strategies and experiences of the Jobs-Plus sites can thus offer guidance to other public housing authorities as they attempt to implement provisions of the new law. Public Housing Residents Have Historically Faced Strong Disincentives to Work Over the past several decades, many public housing developments became places of high unemployment and concentrated poverty. It is widely believed that traditional public housing rent policies are partly to blame, since they created a disincentive for residents to work. Under those rules, rent was calculated as 30 percent of a family s adjusted income (defined as total income minus certain deductions, or disregards). This income-based rent structure functioned as an implicit tax: as a family s income increased, so did its rent. In addition, under the federal welfare system that operated through 1996 (Aid to Families with Dependent Children, or AFDC), residents on welfare who took jobs saw their cash grants reduced nearly dollar for dollar with any new earnings, a situation exacerbated by the potential loss of Medicaid coverage and increased child care costs. In short, public housing residents who increased their earnings have historically seen a large portion of these new earnings siphoned off by a combination of higher rents, lost welfare benefits, and work-related expenses. Changes in Non-Housing Policies During the 1990s Increased Work Incentives Although Rent-Related Disincentives Remained In the past 10 years, several changes made to non-housing policies have increased the financial benefit that lowincome families including public housing residents derive from increased earnings. In implementing the 1996

2 MDRC POLICY BRIEF APRIL 2002 federal welfare reform legislation, many states put into place policies that prevent recipients from losing all of their welfare benefits when they go to work. Moreover, changes in Medicaid eligibility rules for adults and the inception of the Children s Health Insurance Program expanded the health coverage available to low-income families, including those leaving welfare for work. Perhaps most notably, the federal Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) was made far more generous, and now provides significant financial support for families. As a result of these changes, public housing residents, like other low-income groups, can now benefit more from going to work if they know about and take advantage of all the benefits available to them. Yet, a number of studies have shown that supports like the federal child care subsidy program and the EITC are used by fewer families than are eligible and that many families remain unaware of them altogether. Indeed, in a baseline survey taken of residents of Jobs-Plus housing developments before the demonstration began, only 40 percent said that they had heard of the EITC. It is likely, therefore, that many residents still believe that the economic payoff from low-wage work remains marginal. Even after taking the potential impact of these changes into account, however, traditional rent rules continued to act as a disincentive to employment for families in public housing. Under some circumstances, the rules discouraged residents from taking a full-time rather than part-time job, from taking a job that paid higher wages, or from having a second wage earner in the family. Moreover, the risk that taking a job would result in higher rents remains a matter of particular concern for public housing residents. In the baseline survey, 46 percent of residents said they believed that having their rent raised because of going to work full time would create a pretty big or very big problem for them. New Federal Housing Legislation Passed in 1998 Included Rent Rules Designed to Encourage Employment Among Public Housing Residents Intending to transform public housing developments into mixed-income communities with many more residents, Congress enacted the Quality Housing and Work Responsibility Act (QHWRA) in 1998. Among the legislation s key features are the following new public housing rent policies designed to overcome the work disincentives inherent in traditional rent rules: QHWRA requires public housing authorities to disregard 100 percent of new earnings for one year when calculating rents for certain groups of residents, including those who move from welfare to work. During the next 12 months, housing authorities can increase rents for these groups by only half as much as would be permitted under traditional income-based rules. Housing authorities must also offer a flat-rent option that allows residents to choose whether to pay a rent that remains fixed at a flat rate or a rent based on the traditional formula (that is, 30 percent of income). At their discretion, housing authorities may implement such policies as establishing lower ceiling rents (which cap how high income-based rents can go) and creating further income disregards. Taken together, the QHWRA rent policies represent one of the most ambitious legislative efforts to date to promote employment among public housing residents by increasing their financial incentive to work. Jobs-Plus Is Testing Incentives That Are Consistent With the New Housing Law And Go Even Further Implemented at seven public housing developments in six cities (Baltimore, Chattanooga, Dayton, Los Angeles, St. Paul, and Seattle), 4 Jobs-Plus combines employment and training services, financial work incentives, and a community support for work component in a comprehensive intervention targeted at all -age residents. 5 Although the creation of Jobs-Plus preceded QHWRA by more than one year, the demonstration s focus on increasing employment among public housing residents is consistent with the goals of that legislation. In addition, the Jobs-Plus financial work incentives, which are created primarily by changing the traditional link between income and public housing rents, are congruous with the types of rent incentives contained in QHWRA. The Jobs-Plus incentives go even further than QHWRA in their scope and generosity, placing the demonstration at the forefront of innovation regarding work incentives targeted at public housing residents. Because each site s incentives were designed through the collaboration of

APRIL 2002 MDRC POLICY BRIEF 3 residents, public housing administrators, and other neighborhood entities to reflect local conditions, the Jobs-Plus incentives vary considerably across the demonstration sites (Table 1). Each site s incentives consist of one or more of the following elements. Rent freeze. Rent remains fixed at its current level for a specified period of time as long as the resident is. A rent freeze serves essentially as a 100 percent disregard of new earnings and is designed to benefit families making the transition to employment who often must absorb new work-related expenses, such as clothing and transportation. Flat rents. As is the norm in the private unsubsidized rental housing market, rent is fixed at a specified level for a period of time and does not change as the resident s income changes. Sites with flat-rent incentive plans allow residents to switch to income-based rents if the flat rent creates a financial hardship, such as might occur if the resident s income were to fall due to a job loss. 6 At two sites with flat rents, residents who lose their jobs are allowed to pay minimum rents for one to three months while looking for work. Income-based rents calculated using a lower percentage of adjusted income. As under traditional public housing rent rules, rent is calculated as a percent age of adjusted income. However, this percentage is set lower than the standard 30 percent. Lower ceiling rents. A complement to income-based rents, ceiling rents place a cap on how high a family s rent can go. Jobs-Plus sites with ceiling rents have set them at levels lower than the housing authorities use for their other developments. Incentives beyond basic rent rules. Some Jobs-Plus sites place a portion of residents rent payments into escrow accounts to promote asset accumulation, provide rent credits to reward sustained employment, assist residents with transportation costs, or help residents with health coverage and child care. How Jobs-Plus Rent Incentives Affect Net Income The following case studies illustrate how rent-based incentives developed by one Jobs-Plus site, in combination with other non-housing financial incentives available to tenants, would affect the net income of three prototypical resident families who pursue three common employment scenarios. DeSoto Bass Courts in Dayton, Ohio, has implemented an incentives plan with two flat-rent steps. In the year-long initial step, the participating tenant s rent is set at about TABLE 1 Cross-Site Summary of Jobs-Plus Rent Incentives Features Incentive Baltimore Chattanooga Dayton Los Angeles St. Paul Seattle Rent freeze (or 100% disregard of new earnings) Rent is fixed at its pre-jobs-plus level for a certain period. 100% disregard of all earnings Rent for a certain period is based only on welfare income minus standard disregards. Flat/fixed rent steps Rent is set to a fixed level that does not vary with income and is increased to a new fixed level every year or two. Income-based formula, with rent set to a lower percentage of adjusted income Rent is set to 10% or 20% of adjusted income. Reduced ceiling rent The maximum rent a resident can pay under an income-based formula is reduced. Escrow accounts Part of residents rent payments are deposited into a savings account, which may be interest-bearing. Rent credits Residents receive rent credits for joining Jobs-Plus or for each month they work. Transportation assistance Direct assistance with transportation costs through free or low-cost van programs or a deduction for transportation costs when calculating adjusted income. SOURCE: Jobs-Plus sites incentives plans.

APRIL 2002 MDRC POLICY BRIEF 4 Case#1: Ana is a single mother with two children. She is currently on welfare and is considering taking a job for $6 per hour. Even under traditional rent rules, both part-time and full-time work produce a net income gain for Ana s family thanks in large part to the increased generosity of the EITC and other reforms in non-housing policies discussed above. Jobs-Plus rules, however, expand the advantage of full-time over part-time work because rent does not increase along with her earnings. By full time under Jobs-Plus, Ana s net monthly income would be $141 (14 percent) higher than if she worked the same amount under the traditional rules. Figure 1 Net Monthly Income After Work Expenses and Rent ($) 1400 _ 1200 _ 1000 _ 800 _ 600 _ 400 _ 200 _ 0 _ 1,022 825 Traditional Gain = $141 (14%) 1,163 888 Jobs-Plus Final Step Not part time full time Case#2: Mary is a single mother with two children who recently took a part-time job paying $10 per hour. She is now considering taking a full-time job at the same wage rate. Under traditional rules, Mary would realize a net income gain by taking a part-time job. However, by taking a full-time job, she would end up with less net income than if she worked only part time because of a greater reduction in benefits and jump in rent. Jobs-Plus rules correct this problem, leaving her with more net income if she works full time rather than part time. Furthermore, she would realize $304 (32 percent) more in net monthly income than she would with the same full-time job under traditional rules. Figure 2 Net Monthly Income After Work Expenses and Rent ($) 1400 _ 1200 _ 1000 _ 800 _ 600 _ 400 _ 200 _ 0 _ 997 965 Traditional Gain = $304 (32%) 1,269 1,112 Jobs-Plus Final Step Not part time full time Case#3: Brenda lives with her spouse and two children. Her spouse works full time earning $6 per hour, and the family receives welfare and Food Stamp benefits. Brenda is considering take a job that pays $6 hour. Under traditional rules, net income for Brenda s family would decrease if she went to work either part time or full time. Under Jobs-Plus rules, however, her family s net income would increase though only if Brenda were to take a full-time job. In this scenario, the family s net income would be $398 (37 percent) higher per month than under traditional rules. Although Brenda has a greater incentive to work full time under Jobs-Plus, the lower rent the family would pay under the program s incentives would also make it easier for her or her spouse to stop or to work less without making the family any worse off than they would have been under traditional rent rules. Figure 3 Net Monthly Income After Work Expenses and Rent ($) 2000 _ 1800 _ 1600 _ 1400 _ 1200 _ 1000 _ 800 _ 600 _ 400 _ 200 _ 0 _ 1,215 1,130 1,067 Traditional Gain = $398 (37%) 1,393 1,383 1,465 Jobs-Plus Final Step Second parent not Second parent part time Second parent full time

APRIL 2002 MDRC POLICY BRIEF 5 one-third of the authority-wide flat rent. In the final step, rent increases to about half the authority-wide standard and remains at that level for the balance of the demonstration. The figures below compare what each of the prototypical tenants net monthly income 7 would be under traditional rent rules and under the Jobs-Plus second-step rent rules. As the Dayton case studies illustrate, Jobs-Plus rent policies increase the financial reward for housing authority residents to work more hours and, in many cases, to take better-paying jobs. Although the amounts differ, similar patterns hold across the demonstration sites. Because most Jobs-Plus sites began implementing their financial work incentives only in 2000, the evaluation of these policies is still underway. When completed, it will provide an important account of what it takes to put the different strategies into operation, how residents view and react to the alternative approaches, and how the incentives affect residents employment and earnings. How Jobs-Plus Incentives May Affect Housing Authority Rent Revenues Jobs-Plus will also yield an important lesson about the impact of rent incentives on housing authority revenues. Underlying the Jobs-Plus approach to public housing rent reform is the assumption that housing authorities will lose revenue in the short term as they reduce tenants rents to encourage greater employment, but that those losses will be recouped over the longer term as more residents go to work (and thus pay more rent than they would have paid when not employed). To encourage the housing authorities participating in Jobs-Plus to experiment with Notes 1 Earlier briefs have discussed the relationship between housing and employment and welfare outcomes for welfare recipients (Welfare, Housing, and Employment, May 2001), and provided an overview of the Jobs-Plus strategies being tested and described the communities in which they are being tried (Promoting Employment in Public Housing Communities, November 2001). 2 This policy brief is based on Cynthia Miller and James A. Riccio, 2002, Making Work Pay for Public Housing Residents: Financial-Incentive Designs at Six Jobs-Plus Demonstration Sites, New York: MDRC. 3 The U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD), The Rockefeller Foundation, and other public and private funders listed at the end of this document are sponsoring the demonstration, which is being managed and evaluated by MDRC. 4 Jobs-Plus originally included eight public housing developments in seven cities. The Jobs- Plus site in Cleveland, Ohio, withdrew from the demonstration due to local factors. The Seattle site is also no longer part of the national demonstration because the Jobs- Plus development there is being razed and rebuilt under a federal HOPE-VI grant; however, it is continuing to operate a modified Jobs-Plus program during the redevelopment process. new approaches, the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development is compensating them for any lost revenue caused by the rent incentives over the course of the demonstration. 8 The evaluation will measure cumulatively how much revenue (if any) they actually lose, which is of great importance both for housing authorities and federal policymakers. The Relevance of Jobs-Plus Financial Incentives Extends Beyond Public Housing to Other Self-Sufficiency Efforts Although Jobs-Plus is operating solely in public housing developments, the demonstration s lessons on financial incentives can contribute to a deeper understanding of efforts to make work pay for low-income families. For example, the Jobs-Plus programs have introduced innovative strategies to educate public housing residents about financial work incentives, including an interactive Web-based income calculator that allows users to see how different employment scenarios (varying the hourly wage rate or the number of hours worked per week, for example) would affect their net income when coupled with the available benefits (such as the EITC, Food Stamps, or child care subsidies). Promising outreach and educational strategies for ensuring that families take advantage of these benefits may be applicable to the welfare system and other systems serving low-income families. Findings from Jobs-Plus may also suggest ways in which the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban 5 For a full description of the Jobs-Plus approach, see James A. Riccio, 1999, Mobilizing Public Housing Communities for Work: Origins and Early Accomplishments of the Jobs-Plus Demonstration, New York: MDRC. A detailed analysis of inter-agency and resident collaboration in designing and operating the program at the local level is presented in Linda Y. Kato and James A. Riccio, 2001, Building New Partnerships for Employment: Collaboration Among Agencies and Public Housing Residents in the Jobs-Plus Demonstration, New York: MDRC. 6 Jobs-Plus sites with incomebased rents have a built-in safety net for residents who lose their jobs as their income drops, so does their rent. (continued on next page) 7 These calculations take into consideration earnings, AFDC/TANF payments, Food Stamps, child care subsidies, the accrued monthly value of EITC payments, child care and transportation costs, tax obligations, and rent. Part-time employment is defined as 20 hours per week; full-time employment is defined as 40 hours per week. 8 If a participating housing authority s combination of rent revenues and operating subsidies for its Jobs-Plus development is lower when rents are calculated according to Jobs-Plus rent rules rather than traditional HUD rent rules, HUD reimburses the housing authority for the difference.

6 MDRC POLICY BRIEF APRIL 2002 Development s Section 8 housing assistance program, which currently calculates rents as 30 percent of family income, might use financial incentives to promote employment. Conclusion Enhanced financial work incentives targeted at public housing residents have the potential to increase employment and net income and, even more broadly, to change how families in public housing perceive the real financial rewards of work. Future publications from the Jobs-Plus demonstration will assess whether these ambitious goals are achieved. 16 East 34th Street New York, NY 10016 (212) 532-3200 www.mdrc.org 475 14th Street Oakland, CA 94612 (510) 663-6372 Funders of the Jobs-Plus Demonstration: The U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development and The Rockefeller Foundation, with additional support from the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services and U.S. Department of Labor; the Joyce, James Irvine, Surdna, Northwest Area, Annie E. Casey, Stuart, and Washington Mutual Foundations; and BP. Manpower Demonstration Research Corporation 16 East 34th Street New York, NY 10016 MDRC POLICY BRIEF Making Work Pay for Public Housing Residents Learning from the Jobs-Plus Demonstration JOBSPLUS