NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES RETHINKING THE ROLE OF FISCAL POLICY. Martin S. Feldstein. Working Paper

Similar documents
NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES U.S. GROWTH IN THE DECADE AHEAD. Martin S. Feldstein. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CAPPING INDIVIDUAL TAX EXPENDITURE BENEFITS. Martin Feldstein Daniel Feenberg Maya MacGuineas

The 2006 Economic Report of the President

Did Wages Reflect Growth in Productivity?

Normalizing Monetary Policy

Chapter 25 Fiscal Policy Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

THE EFFECT OF SOCIAL SECURITY ON PRIVATE SAVING: THE TIME SERIES EVIDENCE

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHY IS THE DOLLAR SO HIGH? Martin Feldstein. Working Paper

THE INFLUENCE OF MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY ON AGGREGATE DEMAND

The Lack of an Empirical Rationale for a Revival of Discretionary Fiscal Policy. John B. Taylor Stanford University

Econ 102 Exam 2 Name ID Section Number

The Tax Reform Act of 1986: Comment on the 25th Anniversary

Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy

CHAPTER 8 FISCAL POLICY: COPING WITH INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT

Disclaimer: This resource package is for studying purposes only EDUCATION

THE INFLUENCE OF MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY ON AGGREGATE DEMAND

International Journal of Business and Economic Development Vol. 4 Number 1 March 2016

The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit

Week 11 Answer Key Spring 2015 Econ 210D K.D. Hoover. Week 11 Answer Key

Macroeconomics, Spring 2007, Final Exam, several versions, Early May

BALANCING THE FEDERAL BUDGET: ECONOMIC RATIONALE AND ISSUES

The Professional Forecasters

FACT SHEET CBO BUDGET OUTLOOK FY

Feel No Pain: Why a Deficit In Times of High Unemployment Is Not a Burden

FISCAL POLICY* Chapt er. Key Concepts

General Economic Outlook Recession! Will it be Short and Shallow?

the Federal Reserve to carry out exceptional policies for over seven year in order to alleviate its effects.

SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN *

Lecture 7. Unemployment and Fiscal Policy

Overview. Martin Feldstein

Chapter 7. Fiscal Policy. These slides supplement the textbook, but should not replace reading the textbook

Expansions (periods of. positive economic growth)

Tools of Budget Analysis (Chapter 4 in Gruber s textbook) 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

William C Dudley: A bit better, but very far from best US economic outlook and the challenges facing the Federal Reserve

Use the following to answer question 15: AE0 AE1. Real expenditures. Real income. Page 3

The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand

15 th. edition Gwartney Stroup Sobel Macpherson. First page. edition Gwartney Stroup Sobel Macpherson

Economic Policy in the Crisis. Lars Calmfors Jönköping International Business School, 2 November 2009

Economy Check-In: Post 2008 Crisis Market Update Special Report

AGEC 105 Test 3 Spring 2012

A. What is the value of the tax increase multiplier if the MPC is.80? B. Consumption changes by 400 and disposable income by 100. What is the MPC?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ARE GOVERNMENT SPENDING MULTIPLIERS GREATER DURING PERIODS OF SLACK? EVIDENCE FROM 20TH CENTURY HISTORICAL DATA

Joseph S Tracy: A strategy for the 2011 economic recovery

Answers and Explanations

Economics 1012A: Introduction to Macroeconomics FALL 2007 Dr. R. E. Mueller Third Midterm Examination November 15, 2007

Observation. January 18, credit availability, credit

Keynesian Fiscal Policy and the Multipliers

1. When the Federal government uses taxation and spending actions to stimulate the economy it is conducting:

Debt vs Growth: Correlation or Causation

AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AGGREGATE DEMAND, AND INFLATION: PUTTING IT ALL TOGETHER Macroeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Objectives for Chapter 24: Monetarism (Continued) Chapter 24: The Basic Theory of Monetarism (Continued) (latest revision October 2004)

Notes Numbers in the text and tables may not add up to totals because of rounding. Unless otherwise indicated, years referred to in describing the bud

Sample Exam 1: QEII Labor Market Rescue?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CAN AN INCREASED BUDGET DEFICIT BE CONTRACTIONARY? Martin Feldstein. Working Paper No. l43)4

2. Suppose a family s annual disposable income is $8000 of which it saves $2000. (a) What is their APC?

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Government Budget and Fiscal Policy CHAPTER

Econ 102 Final Exam Name ID Section Number

Obama s Plan to Create or Save Jobs: A Promise Unfulfilled

Economics Chapters Duke Unit III Measuring Economic Performance

Parkin/Bade, Economics: Canada in the Global Environment, 8e

Ryerson University Department of Economics ECN 204 MidtermTwo W12. Name: Student No:

Progress Evaluation of the Transformation of China's Economic Growth Pattern 1 (Preliminary Draft Please do not quote)

THE NEW ECONOMY RECESSION: ECONOMIC SCORECARD 2001

The text was adapted by The Saylor Foundation under the CC BY-NC-SA without attribution as requested by the works original creator or licensee

Volume Title: The American Economy in Transition. Volume Author/Editor: Martin Feldstein, ed. Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 13. Fiscal Policy

Macroeconomics Robert J. Gordon Twelfth Edition

Macroeconomics, Spring 2007, Exam 3, several versions, Late April-Early May

Introduction to Agricultural Economics Agricultural Economics 105 Spring 2018 Third Hour Exam

CRS Report for Congress

Current Economic Conditions and Selected Forecasts

Number 2: The UK Spending Deficit What is it and must it be eliminated now?

ABSTRACT. Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Policy with Income-sensitive Capital Flows. J.O.N. Perkins, University of Melbourne

Macroeconomic Effects from Government Purchases and Taxes. Robert J. Barro and Charles J. Redlick Harvard University

WHAT THE REALLY HAPPENED...

Econ 102 Final Exam Name ID Section Number

FRONT BARNETT ASSOCIATES LLC

TD Economics Special Report

Macroeconomics: Principles, Applications, and Tools

CHAPTER TWENTY-SEVEN BASIC MACROECONOMIC RELATIONSHIPS

THE INFLUENCE OF MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY ON AGGREGATE DEMAND

The Economic Crisis: Is there a Middle Ground? II

Part VIII: Short-Run Fluctuations and. 26. Short-Run Fluctuations 27. Countercyclical Macroeconomic Policy

Creating a Fiscal Turnaround in the United States Maya MacGuineas New America Foundation

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DID THE 2008 TAX REBATES STIMULATE SPENDING? Matthew D. Shapiro Joel B. Slemrod

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 13. Fiscal Policy

Macroeconomics, Spring 2011, Final Exam, several versions

CRS Report for Congress

THE IMPACT OF AGING BABY BOOMERS ON LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION

LETTER. economic COULD INTEREST RATES HEAD UP IN 2015? JANUARY Canada. United States. Interest rates. Oil price. Canadian dollar.

Practice Problems

chapter: Solution Fiscal Policy

How We're Doing: What s Blocking the Recovery

Gauging Current Conditions: The Economic Outlook and Its Impact on Workers Compensation

Name: Days/Times Class Meets: Today s Date:

ASSESSING THE RISK OF A DOUBLE-DIP RECESSION: KEY INDICATORS TO MONITOR

Archimedean Upper Conservatory Economics, October 2016

1 of 15 12/1/2013 1:28 PM

An Assessment of the President s Proposal to Stimulate the Economy and Create Jobs. John B. Taylor *

Transcription:

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES RETHINKING THE ROLE OF FISCAL POLICY Martin S. Feldstein Working Paper 14684 http://www.nber.org/papers/w14684 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 January 2009 The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peerreviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. 2009 by Martin S. Feldstein. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including notice, is given to the source.

Rethinking the Role of Fiscal Policy Martin S. Feldstein NBER Working Paper No. 14684 January 2009 JEL No. E6,E62,H3 ABSTRACT As recently as two years ago there was a widespread consensus among economists that fiscal policy is not useful as a countercyclical instrument. Now governments in Washington and around the world are developing massive fiscal stimulus packages, supported by a wide range of economists in universities, governments, and businesses. Why has this change occurred? What are the principles for designing a potentially useful fiscal stimulus? And what will happen if the current fiscal stimulus fails? Martin S. Feldstein President Emeritus NBER 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138-5398 and NBER msfeldst@nber.org

Rethinking the Role of Fiscal Policy Martin Feldstein As recently as two years ago there was a widespread consensus among economists that fiscal policy is not useful as a countercyclical instrument. Now governments in Washington and around the world are developing massive fiscal stimulus packages, supported by a wide range of economists in universities, governments, and businesses. Why has this change occurred? What are the principles for designing a potentially useful fiscal stimulus? And what will happen if the current fiscal stimulus fails? I. The Rise and Fall of Fiscal Activism Despite a wide array of government programs introduced by the Roosevelt administration during the depression of the 1930s, the unemployment rate remained at double digit levels until 1941 when the government began massive military spending for the lend lease program and the start of World War II. Economists saw this favorable effect of the military spending on employment and economic activity as a clear example of the power of Keynesian fiscal policy. After the war, most American macroeconomists focused on the potential contribution of Keynesian fiscal policy to preventing unemployment. For some, the new Professor of Economics, Harvard University, and President Emeritus of the National Bureau of Economic Research. This paper was prepared for presentation at the January 2009 meeting of the American Economic Association. 1

econometric models held out the hope of eliminating or at least significantly damping the business cycle. But further analysis and experience soon raised doubts about the efficacy of these new tools. Empirical research indicated that the Keynesian multiplier was much smaller than earlier analyses had assumed, reduced by a crowding out of interest sensitive spending caused by an induced increase in the demand for money and by the effect of the larger national debt on long term interest rates. The leakage of demand through imports and the effect of the fiscal expansion on the exchange rate further reduced the multiplier. Despite improvements in data and in econometric techniques, it remained difficult for economists to assess the current state of the business cycle and even harder to discern where the economy was heading and how much it would be affected by a fiscal stimulus. The resulting uncertainty implied that an activist fiscal policy could actually increase cyclical volatility. Moreover, the long lags between decisions to raise spending or cut taxes and the subsequent fiscal flows often meant that the stimulus occurred after the trough in activity, adding undesirable increases in demand to a rapidly expanding economy. The simultaneous rise in both inflation and unemployment in the 1960s made it clear that the Keynesian fiscal strategy was not working. The focus of countercyclical policy therefore shifted from fiscal policy to monetary policy. Economists recognized that monetary policy could be adjusted more rapidly and that changes in the interest rate could be effective in modulating aggregate demand through a variety of channels. The low inflation rate since the early 1980s and the decreased cyclical volatility both reinforced the case for relying on monetary policy. 2

II. The Recent Revival of Fiscal Policy Why then the recent revival of interest in fiscal stimulus? By the fall of 2007 it became clear to many economists that the current downturn is different from previous recessions and that monetary policy would not be effective in bringing us back to full employment. Past recessions generally began after the Federal Reserve had raised interest rates sharply to counter excess inflation. When the Fed felt that it had succeeded, it reversed policy and lowered the interest rate. That was enough to trigger a recovery, driven in large part by the responsiveness of housing starts to lower interest rates. In contrast, the current downturn was not due to high interest rates and therefore could not be fixed by a reversal of Fed policy. The seeds of this recession were sown in the underpricing of risk and the resulting excessive leverage. A sharp rise in defaults on subprime mortgages alerted market participants that risk had been mismeasured and therefore underpriced. The resulting general repricing of risk caused sharp falls in the prices of mortgage backed securities, of share prices, and of the values of homes. The massive destruction of household wealth led to a sharp decline in consumer spending, followed by falls in business investment and commercial real estate values. The continuing declines in the value of mortgage backed securities and of the derivatives based on them reflected the fear of an increasing future volume of mortgage defaults. This eroded the capital of financial institutions, undermining their willingness to make loans. The result was a dysfunctional credit market that no longer provided credit or responded to changes in interest rates. 3

The Federal Reserve therefore could not reverse the downturn by lowering interest rates. Although it reduced the federal funds rate substantially, mortgage rates and corporate bond rates remained high. Even if mortgage rates had come down, the continuing sharp decline in house prices would have prevented a rise in housing starts. By the end of 2007, an anticipation of the Fed s inability to prevent a serious recession caused some of us to advocate a fiscal stimulus. A temporary one time tax rebate was chosen as something that could get bipartisan support and be implemented quickly. We recognized that both economic theory and much past experience implied that most of a one time tax cut would be saved rather than contributing to consumer spending. But we were encouraged by the stronger response to the 2001 tax cut even though we recognized that that was technically more than a one time tax change. The Congress quickly passed a tax rebate of $80 billion and the money was in the hands of taxpayers by May and June. Unfortunately, consumer spending responded only very weakly. I presented evidence in the Wall Street Journal (August 6, 2008) that consumer spending in the second quarter rose by only $12 billion. The monthly personal income and expenditure data confirmed this picture, with consumer spending in May and June rising a total of only $11 billion. More recently, Stephen Miran and I estimated a consumer expenditure equation using monthly data from January 1980 through November 2008. While the marginal propensity to consume out of real per capita disposable income is estimated to be 0.70, the estimated MPC from the corresponding rebate variable is only 0.13 (standard error 0.05). (The other variables in the equation are the unemployment rate, the 10 year interest rate, 4

and a quadratic time trend.) A variety of short distributed lag specifications confirms this result and indicate that there is no delayed impact of the rebate; all of the monthly lag coefficients are completely insignificant and their sum is negative. In recent months, the Federal Reserve and the Treasury have taken a variety of steps to help the credit markets. These policies have succeeded in preventing a further meltdown of credit availability in banks, money market mutual funds, and in the ability of firms to issue commercial paper. But these measures have neither expanded total credit nor dealt with the fundamental problem of a dysfunctional credit market caused by the foreclosures that result from the rising loan to value ratios on non recourse mortgage loans. Although fixing the credit market is necessary for long run sustained growth, would not be sufficient to reverse the downward spiral of aggregate demand. II. Designing the Current Fiscal Package This brings us to the current situation and the perceived need for a large fiscal package. The fall in the stock market and in the value of owner occupied real estate has depressed household wealth by about $10 trillion. The estimated wealth effects imply a decline of annual consumer spending by $400 billion or more. That reduction in consumer spending implies reduced production, lower incomes, and therefore further reductions in consumer spending. This could reduce aggregate demand by an additional $200 billion a year or more. Automatic stabilizers i.e., the reductions in personal and corporate taxes and the increases in unemployment insurance and other transfers probably offsets about one third of this, leaving a net GDP gap of about $400 billion. 5

The current decline in demand is different from typical past business cycles in which demand recovers as inventories and excess capacity is absorbed. So that is the challenge: how to increase domestic spending by some $400 billion a year in 2009 and 2010, and perhaps further into the future. Some of that may come from a more competitive dollar, although the increased competitiveness of the dollar may only be enough to offset the decline in export demand that results from the reduced level of foreign incomes. So it falls to fiscal policy to support the increase in aggregate spending. Some of the past problems in using fiscal policy to stimulate demand may be less of an impediment in the current circumstances. Government borrowing to finance fiscal deficits will not be offset by higher interest rates since the current environment is characterized by very easy money and a dysfunctional credit market. The delays in starting infrastructure projects and the long tail in that spending are not likely to be as much of a problem now because the current downturn is likely to last much longer than previous ones. In the past, the average recession lasted only 12 months from peak to trough. This recession has already lasted 12 months and probably will last a good deal longer. I believe we will be lucky if we see the recession end in 2009. Once the recovery begins, the upturn will be very slow because households need to increase their saving i.e., to consume less to rebuild their wealth for retirement and other purposes. So fiscal policy is likely to be useful even if it is not strongly effective in 2009. It is not likely to overheat the economy if it continues to add significantly to demand in 2010 and 2011. Although a one time tax cut may not be effective, other forms of tax cutting can increase aggregate demand. During his campaign, candidate Obama promised a permanent 6

tax cut of $500 per employed person. That would generate an annual tax cut of about $70 billion and would probably raise annual consumer spending by about $50 billion. Experience confirms that some form of investment tax credit could stimulate business investment, especially if it is not recaptured later. A larger R&D tax credit could help to offset the currently predicted decline in private R&D spending. And lowering the corporate tax rate to that of other industrial countries would encourage more business investment and job creation in the United States. The president elect announced that he would postpone increasing the tax rate on high income individuals until 2011. But taxpayers, especially higher income ones, look ahead. The future tax rise reduces the present value of their lifetime income and that can be expected to reduce current spending. A statement now by the president elect that he will postpone those tax increases indefinitely would raise aggregate spending now. Finally, the taxes on dividends and capital gains are also scheduled to rise in the near future. A promise to leave those tax rates unchanged would raise share prices, offsetting some of the fall in the stock market, which would lead to more consumer spending and increased business investment. But while good tax policy can contribute to ending the recession, the heavy lifting will have to be done by increased government spending. To be effective, that spending should be big, quick, and targeted at increasing aggregate activity and employment. How big depends on the form of the spending and the timing. 7

The speed of the outlays is an important consideration. A project that begins in 2009 but continues to spend at a high level in 2011 and 2012 is not likely to be as useful as a countercyclical instrument as one that spends quickly and is then finished. Bottlenecks are also a potential problem that could reduce the effectiveness of a spending program. While there is no doubt a need to rebuild bridges and other infrastructure, there are limited numbers of design engineers and other bridge builders. III. Spending Priorities The Obama campaign has identified five priority areas for increased spending: health, energy, education, infrastructure, and support for the poor. Some of that spending would be by the federal governments but much of it would be delegated to the states and local governments. Although these are important areas that can benefit from increased spending, there are other parts of the budget that could also be useful as part of the stimulus package. Since the defense budget is as large as all of the other discretionary spending combined, it is surprising that defense is not proposed as a part of the overall stimulus package. It is surprising also to read in the press that there will be reductions in military spending because, according to those stories, of the weakness of the economy. That logic is exactly backwards. The overall weakness of demand in the economy implies that the next two years are a time when all forms of government spending can be expected to rise as a way of stimulating an economic recovery. 8

The actions of the military in Iraq and Afghanistan have depleted supplies and increased the wear and tear on equipment. Both supplies and equipment will eventually need to be replaced. It would be more cost effective to do that in the next two years when there is substantial slack in the industrial economy. More generally, the large extent of unused industrial capacity imply that the real resource cost of maintenance and replacement in both the military and civilian departments of the government are lower now than they will be when the economy returns to full employment. Military recruiting and training could be expanded in response to the larger than usual numbers of unemployed young men and women. Raising the military s annual recruitment goal by 15 percent would provide jobs for an additional 30,000 young men and women in the first year. It would also be possible to depart from the military s traditional enlistment rules and bring in recruits for a short two year period of training followed by a return to the civilian economy. As a minimum, this would provide education in a variety of technical skills electronics, equipment maintenance, computer programming, nuclear facility operations, etc that would lead to better civilian careers for this group. It would also provide a larger reserve force that could be called upon if needed by the military in the future. A 10 percent increase in defense outlays for procurement and for research would contribute about $20 billion a year to the overall stimulus budget. A 5 percent rise in spending on operations and maintenance would add an additional $10 billion. That spending could create about 300,000 additional jobs. And raising the military s annual 9

recruitment goal by 15 percent would provide jobs for an additional 30,000 young men and women in the first year. The intelligence community and the FBI are also apparently facing potential budget cuts at a time of increasing terrorism and greater crime rates. A temporary increase in funding for these agencies could fill important gaps in training and facilities. Another important omission in the current stimulus plan is funding for research. Government spending for research is projected to fall in 2009 even though additional research grants from the NIH and NSF could allow universities and hospitals to expand a wide range of useful research activities that are now unfunded because of limited grant budgets. No doubt there are other important areas of government spending in which outlays can be raised rapidly on useful activities that would also raise incomes and employment IV. What if it fails? It is of course possible that the planned surge in government spending will fail. Two or three years from now we could be facing a level of unemployment that is higher than today and that shows no sign of coming down. While it is too soon to examine in detail what might then be done, it is useful to consider the three possibilities. First, the level of government spending could be increased even more. To know whether this would help, it is important to study in detail the effectiveness of each of the different components of the spending surge. Second, the fiscal stimulus could shift from increased spending to a substantial permanent reduction in 10

personal and corporate taxes. If this strategy is chosen, changes in spending policies would have to be adopted to limit the growth of the national debt. The third way out would be a fall in the value of the dollar, either spontaneous or planned, that is large enough to eliminate today s large trade deficit, thus boosting exports and substituting American made goods and services for imports from the rest of the world. While these possibilities should be kept in mind, we can only hope that the new program of tax changes and government spending in combination with mortgage market reforms will be sufficient to return the economy to full employment. Cambridge MA 11