For Online Publication Only. ONLINE APPENDIX for. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market

Similar documents
For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market. June 2017

Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market

Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market

Learning from Peers Stock Prices and Corporate Investment

II. Competitive Trade Using Money

Credit Card Competition and Naive Hyperbolic Consumers

Momentum and Asymmetric Information

Online Appendix. Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: Do Dynamic Incentives Matter? by Aron-Dine, Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen

Test 1. ECON3161, Game Theory. Tuesday, September 25 th

Organizing the Global Value Chain: Online Appendix

1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is. x + F (q) y. where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not

Subsidization to Induce Tipping

Some Notes on Timing in Games

Mean-Variance Analysis

Coordination and Bargaining Power in Contracting with Externalities

Switching Costs, Relationship Marketing and Dynamic Price Competition

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Comprehensive Exam

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

Intergenerational Bargaining and Capital Formation

Lectures on Trading with Information Competitive Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium (Grossman and Stiglitz AER (1980))

Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and

Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

Online Appendix for The E ect of Diversi cation on Price Informativeness and Governance

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

Equilibrium Asset Returns

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

UCLA Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Exam Micro-Economic Theory

Optimal Acquisition Strategies in Unknown Territories

A feedback e ect from stock market trading to innovations in a Bertrand duopoly

Lecture Notes 1

Dynamic games with incomplete information

Central bank credibility and the persistence of in ation and in ation expectations

Problem Set 2 Answers

Strategic information acquisition and the. mitigation of global warming

WORKING PAPER NO OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY IN A MODEL OF MONEY AND CREDIT. Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Australian National University

Public Signals, Voluntary Disclosures, and Security Prices

Ex post or ex ante? On the optimal timing of merger control Very preliminary version

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation

Herding and Bank Runs

Distinguishing Rational and Behavioral. Models of Momentum

Banking Concentration and Fragility in the United States

The Irrelevance of Corporate Governance Structure

Ownership Concentration, Monitoring and Optimal Board Structure

Collusion in a One-Period Insurance Market with Adverse Selection

Micro Theory I Assignment #5 - Answer key

Security Design Under Routine Auditing

Internal Financing, Managerial Compensation and Multiple Tasks

Feedback E ects and the Limits to Arbitrage

Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation

Introducing nominal rigidities.

What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? Supplementary Online Appendix

A Bayesian Approach to Real Options:

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

(1 p)(1 ε)+pε p(1 ε)+(1 p)ε. ε ((1 p)(1 ε) + pε). This is indeed the case since 1 ε > ε (in turn, since ε < 1/2). QED

Opting out of publicly provided services: A majority voting result

10.1 Elimination of strictly dominated strategies

Are more risk averse agents more optimistic? Insights from a rational expectations model

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so

Chapter 21 - Exchange Rate Regimes

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market

Auction Theory for Undergrads

Math 5621 Financial Math II Spring 2016 Final Exam Soluitons April 29 to May 2, 2016

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

Good Disclosure, Bad Disclosure

Electoral Manipulation via Voter-Friendly Spending: Theory and Evidence

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Sequential Decision-making and Asymmetric Equilibria: An Application to Takeovers

Herding and Bank Runs

sheets and structural reforms

The Economics of State Capacity. Weak States and Strong States. Ely Lectures. Johns Hopkins University. April 14th-18th 2008.

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

Factor Endowments. Ricardian model insu cient for understanding objections to free trade.

Search, Welfare and the Hot Potato E ect of In ation

Optimal Information Disclosure: Quantity vs. Quality

D S E Dipartimento Scienze Economiche

Liquidity and Growth: the Role of Counter-cyclical Interest Rates

The Economics of State Capacity. Ely Lectures. Johns Hopkins University. April 14th-18th Tim Besley LSE

Is shareholders strategic default behavior priced? Evidence from the international cross-section of stocks

The role of asymmetric information

Trade and Synchronization in a Multi-Country Economy

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOME PRODUCTION, MARKET PRODUCTION AND THE GENDER WAGE GAP: INCENTIVES AND EXPECTATIONS. Stefania Albanesi Claudia Olivetti

The Timing of Analysts Earnings Forecasts and Investors Beliefs 1

Acquisition and Disclosure of Information as a Hold-up Problem

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

Managing Consumer Referrals on a Chain Network

Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010

Revision Lecture. MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

ECON Financial Economics

Determinants of Ownership Concentration and Tender O er Law in the Chilean Stock Market

What Drives Anomaly Returns?

Emissions Trading in Forward and Spot Markets of Electricity

Statistical Evidence and Inference

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Solutions to Problem Set # 2

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

Some Problems. 3. Consider the Cournot model with inverse demand p(y) = 9 y and marginal cost equal to 0.

MS-E2114 Investment Science Exercise 4/2016, Solutions

Transcription:

For Online Publication Only ONLINE APPENDIX for Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market By: Thierry Foucault (HEC, Paris) and Laurent Frésard (University of Maryland) January 2016 This appendix contains the proofs and additional analyses that we mention in paper but that we decided not to report there to preserve space. The appendix is organized as follows. Section A proves Corollary 2. Section B proves that the stock market equilibrium is unique in our model. Section C replicates the results in Tables 2 and 3 of the paper using stock return co-movement to measure di erentiation instead of the text-based measure of product di erentiation developed by Hoberg and Phillips (2015). Section D documents a negative association between a rm s overall degree of product di erentiation (or uniqueness) and the informativeness of its stock price. Section E reports rm-level tests instead of the rm-pair level tests presented in the paper. 1

A Proof of Corollary 2. Case 1. First consider the case in which rm A chooses the common strategy. Consider a speculator who buys information about this strategy. The expected pro t of the speculator in rm j 2 f1; :::; ng if she learns that the common strategy is good is j (+1; G) given in eq.(20). By symmetry, the expected pro t of the speculator in rm j 2 f1; :::; ng if she learns that the common strategy is bad is j ( 1; B) = j (+1; G). Thus, the ex-ante expected gross pro t of receiving information about the common strategy and trading on this information in inculbent rm j is: ( c ) = 1 2 j(+1; G) + 1 2 j( 1; B) = j (+1; G) (1) where the last equality follows from eq.(20). = (1 (n; c)) (2 c (r(s c ; n) r(s c ; n + 1)); (2) 2 A speculator who is informed about the type of the common strategy can also use her information to speculate in the stock market of rm A. If she learns that the common strategy is good the speculator buys one share of stock A in equilibrium. In this case, the speculator can make a pro t only if the order ow of all rms (including A) does not reveal that the common strategy is good, that is, if the stock price of rm A is p M A2 (S c) = r(s c ; n + 1; G)=2. This happens with probability (1 (n; c )). In this case, if the manager privately learns the type of the strategy then he will implement the strategy because it is good. Otherwise the manager abandons the strategy. Thus, in this case, the speculator s expected return on her position is r(s c ; n + 1; G) p M A (S c) = r(s c ; n + 1; G)=2. Hence, the speculator s expected pro t on buying one share of rm A when (i) rm A chooses the common strategy and (ii) this strategy is good is A (+1; G) = (1 (n; c ))r(s c ; n + 1; G)=2: (3) A similar reasoning yields A ( 1; B) = A (+1; G). Thus, the ex-ante expected gross pro t of receiving information about the common strategy and trading on this information in the 2

stock market of rm A is: A ( c ) = (1 (n; c)) (r(s c ; n + 1) + c 1). 2 A speculator who receives information about the common strategy can pro tably trade in all stocks of rms following this strategy. Thus, her total expected pro t is: (n; c ) = n( c ) + A ( c ). (4) It is immediate that (n; c ) decreases with c and is equal to zero when c = 1. Thus, there is no equilibrium in which c = 1 if C > 0. Moreover, if (n; 0) > C then c = 0 cannot be an equilibrium since it would then be optimal for at least one speculator to buy information on the type of the common strategy. When 0 < C < (n; 0), the equilibrium mass of speculators informed about the common strategy, c(n), is such that (n; c(n)) = C so that a speculator is just indi erent between getting information or not. Moreover, this equation has a unique solution in (0; 1) because (n; c ) decreases with c. In this case, using eq.(2), (3), and (4), we deduce that c(n), must be such that: (1 (n; c(n))) = 2C n(2 c (r(s c ; n) r(s c ; n + 1))) + (r(s c ; n + 1) + c 1), (5) when rm A chooses the common strategy at date 1 and 0 < C < (n; 0). Case 2. Now suppose that rm A chooses the unique strategy and consider a speculator who buys information on the type of this strategy. The ex-ante expected pro t of this speculator can be computed as for a speculator who buys information on the common strategy. The only di erence is that the speculator can only use her information to speculate in the stock market of rm A (the rm choosing the unique strategy). Following the same steps as when rm A follows the common strategy, we deduce that the speculator s expected pro t if she buys information on the unique strategy is: A ( u ) = (1 u) (r(s u ; 1) + u 1): (6) 2 3

Following the same step as in Case 1, we deduce that if C A (0), we have u = 0 and if 0 < C < A (0) then u solves A ( u) = C, i.e. (using eq.(6)): Now, suppose that C < (1 (1 u) = 2C (r(s u ; 1) + u 1). (7) (n;c)) 2 (2 c (r(s c ; n) r(s c ; n + 1)) so that C < (n; 0). This condition implies that c > 0 and therefore (n; c) > 0. If C A (0), we have u = 0 and then (n; c) > u for any n. If C < A (0), then c and u solve eq.(5) and eq.(7), respectively. We have u (n; c) i (1 u) (1 (n; c)). Using eq.(5) and (7), we deduce that this is the case if and only if: (r(s u ; 1) + u 1) n(2 c (r(s c ; n) r(s c ; n + 1))) + (r(s c ; n + 1) + c 1); (8) i.e., if and only if n > n where: n = (r(s u; 1) r(s c ; n + 1) + u c ). (2 c (r(s c ; n) r(s c ; n + 1)) B Equilibrium Uniqueness We show that when rm A chooses the common strategy, the stock market equilibrium given in Lemma 1 is the unique equilibrium of our model. We omit the analysis of the case in which rm A chooses the unique strategy (Lemma 2) because the proof that the stock market equilibrium is unique in this case as well follows exactly the same steps. Step 1. We rst show that, in any equilibrium, informed speculators trading strategy is such that x ij (G) = +1, x ij (B) = 1, and x ij (?) = 0. Let j (bs(s c )) be a speculator s estimate of rm j s payo when her signal is bs(s c ) 2 f?; G; Bg. To shorten notations, let (G) =Pr(I = 1 js m =?; t Sc = G) and (B) =Pr(I = 1 js m =?; t Sc = G). For incumbent rms, we have: j (G) = ( + (1 )(G))r(S c ; n + 1; G) + (1 )(1 (G))r(S c ; n; G); (9) j (B) = (1 )(B)r(S c ; n + 1; B) + (1 )(1 (B))r(S c ; n; B): (10) 4

As r(s c ; n; G) > r(s c ; n + 1; G) > r(s c ; n; B) > r(s c ; n + 1; B) (Assumption A.4), we deduce from eq.(9) and eq.(10) that j (G) > j (B). An uninformed speculator has no information about the type of the common strategy. Thus, her valuation for an incumbent rm must be equal to the unconditional expected payo of this rm, or, by the Law of Iterated Expectations: j (?) =E(ep j2 ) for j 2 f1; :::; ng: The expected pro t of a speculator with signal bs(s c ) is: j (x ij ; bs(s c )) = x ij ( j (bs(s c )) E(ep j2 jbs(s c )) ; for j 2 f1; :::; ng: Thus, j (x ij ;?) = 0. Hence, x ij = 0 is optimal if a speculator receives the signal bs(s c ) =?. Equilibrium stock prices must be such that j (B) ep j2 j (G). Otherwise, there would exist cases in which the market maker of rm j is willing to buy (resp., sell) the asset at price strictly larger than the largest (smallest) possible valuation of the asset by an informed speculator. Such transactions would result in an expected loss, violating the condition that market makers expect zero pro t on each transaction in equilibrium. We deduce that: (B) E(ep j2 jbs(s c )) (G); (11) for S c 2 fg; Bg. Thus, in any equilibria, x ij (G) = +1 and x ij (B) = 1 are weakly dominant strategies for informed speculators and these strategies are strictly dominant if the inequalities in eq.(11) are strict. This must be the case since c < 1. Indeed, suppose not (to be contradicted) and let b c < c be the fraction of informed speculators who trade when they receive an informative signal. Then, as explained in the text, realizations of orders ows such 1 + b c < f min and f max < 1 b c are such that trades are completely uninformative. Thus, p j2 = E(ep j2 ) when 1 + b c < f min and f max < 1 b c. The probability of this event is not zero since b c < c < 1. This implies that there exist realizations of p j2 strictly within (B) and (G). Thus, (B) < E(ep j2 jbs(s c )) < (G), is a contradiction. Thus, in any equilibria, x ij (G) = +1 and x ij (B) = 1 for j 2 f1; :::; ng are strictly dominant strategies for informed speculators. For rm A, one can show in the same way that in any equilibria, x ia (G) = +1 and x ia (B) = 1 is a strictly dominant strategy for informed speculators while x ia (?) = 0 5

is weakly dominant. The only di erence is that the expressions for A (G) and j (B) are di erent from those given in eq.(9) and eq.(10). Step 2. In step 1, we have shown that, in any equilibria, it must be the case that informed speculators buy all stocks (including A) if they learn that the common strategy is good and sell all stocks if they learn that the common strategy is bad. Moreover, in any equilibria, speculators who receive no signal optimally do not trade. It follows that in any equilibria, order ows reveal that the common strategy is good if f max > 1 c, that it is bad if f min < 1 + c, and contain no information if 1 + c < f min and f max < 1 c. All these events have a strictly positive probability when 0 < c < 1. This feature has implications for equilibrium stock prices. Consider the determination of the price in stock A. Any equilibrium prices of stock A when f max > 1 c (denoted p H A ) must satisfy Condition (5), i.e., p H A = E(V A3 (I ( 3 ; S A ); S A ) j f max > 1 c ); = ( + (1 )Pr(I = 1 s m =?; p A = p H A )(r(sc ; n + 1; G) 1); where, for the second line, we have used the facts that (i) f max > 1 c reveals that t Sc = G and (ii) therefore, market makers must anticipate that if he has private information, the manager will implement his strategy. When 1 + c < f min and f max < 1 c, any equilibrium price of stock A (denoted p M A ) must satisfy (Condition (5) again): p M A = E(V A3 (I ( 3 ; S A ); S A ) j 1 + c < f min and f max < 1 c ); = (r(s c ; n + 1; G) 1)=2 + (1 )Pr(I = 1 sm =?; p A = p M A )(r(sc ; n + 1) 1); where, for the second line, we have used the facts that if 1 + c < f min and f max < 1 c then (i) market makers have no information on the type of the common strategy but (ii) they know that if the manager has no private information, he will base his decision on the observation that the stock price of rm A is p M A. When f min < 1 + c, any equilibrium 6

price of stock A (denoted p L A ) must satisfy (Condition (5) again): p L A = E(V A3 (I ( 3 ; S A ); S A ) j f min < 1 + c ); = (1 )Pr(I = 1 sm =?; p A = p L A )(r(sc ; n + 1) 1); where, for the second line, we have used the facts that (i) f min < 1 + c reveals that t Sc = B and (ii) therefore, market makers must anticipate that if he has private information, the manager will not implement his strategy. As r(s c ; n + 1) > 0, we deduce that, in any equilibria, p H A > pm A > pl A. 1 < 0 (Assumption A.3) and Thus, in any equilibria, there are at least three di erent realizations for the equilibrium price, one for each possible range of order ows, i.e., (i) f max > 1 c, (ii) 1 + c < f min and f max < 1 c and (iii) f min < 1 + c. There cannot be more realizations. Indeed, suppose that this is not the case (to be contradicted). This implies that there are at least two realizations of order ows in the same range that leads to two di erent prices (e.g., for f max > 1 c, there are two di erent realizations of f max that leads to two di erent equilibrium stock prices). This is not possible since these two prices have exactly the same informational content (they reveal in which range are the realizations of the order ows that lead to these prices) and should therefore lead to exactly the same decisions for the manager of rm A. As a result, the expected value of rm A must be the same for these two prices and therefore market makers zero pro t condition (Condition (5)) imposes that these prices are identical. In sum, in any equilibria, there are exactly three possible realizations, p H A, pm A, pl A for the equilibrium stock price of rm A when 0 < c < 1, such that p H A > pm A > pl A. We can proceed in a similar way to show that in any equilibria, there are exactly three possible realizations of equilibrium stock prices for incumbent rms and they must be such that p H j > p M j > p L j. Step 3. Suppose that the manager does not receive private information at date 3. It follows from Step 2 that when he observes p A = p H A, the manager of rm A can infer that t Sc = G. Thus, I = 1 if p A = p H A. If p A = p L A, the manager of rm A can infer that t S c = B. It follows from A.2 that I = 0. If p A = p M A, the beliefs of the manager of rm A are equal to his unconditional beliefs. Hence, A.3 implies that I = 0. 7

In sum, in any equilibria, the manager and speculators must behave as described in Parts 1 and 4 of Lemma 1. Moreover, in any equilibria, there are only three possible realizations for stock prices for each rm when 0 < c < 1: (i) one when f max > 1 c, (ii) one when 1 + c < f min and f max < 1 c, and (iii) one when f min < 1 + c. These conditions, combined with Conditions (6) and (5), uniquely pin down equilibrium stock prices for all rms. Thus, the equilibrium in Lemma 1 is unique. C Stock Return Co-movement As an alternative measure of strategic di erentiation, we use stock return co-movement. The idea is that stock returns of rms that follow less di erentiated strategies should co-move more. 1 We compute co-movement, denoted i;j, between every two rms i and j in the TNIC network. Speci cally, we estimate for each rm-pair-year the following speci cation: r i;w;t = 0 + m;t r m;w;t + i;j;t r j;w;t + i;w;t, (12) where r i;w;t is the (CRSP) return of rm i in week w of year t, r m;w;t is the market return (CRSP value-weighted index), and r j;w;t is the return of rm j. Hence, the estimate of i;j;t measures the return co-movement between rms i and j in year t, after controlling for i and j exposure to market wide changes in prices. We interpret a higher value of i;j;t as indicating that rms i and j follow less di erentiated strategies. 2 [Insert Tables IA.1 and IA.2 about here] Table IA.1 replicates the baseline results of Table 2 (in paper). We obtain similar results when we measure di erentiation between rms i and j using return co-movement ( i;j ) between these rms. Column (1) reveals a negative coe cient on indicating an overall decrease in return co-movement between rm-pairs over time. Moreover, in column (2), we 1 Note that this is the case in the model. The stock returns of rms that follow the common strategy are perfectly positively correlated. In contrast, the stock return of rm A and the stock return of established rms are uncorrelated if rm A follows the unique strategy. 2 Consistent with this interpretation, the correlation between i;j and i;j is 0:29 across all rm-pairyears of our sample. 8

report a signi cantly negative coe cient on T reated, which con rms that treated rms become relatively more di erentiated after their IPOs. The remaining columns corroborate the robustness of this result. Table IA.2 report the results of the cross-sectional tests based on proxies for managers private information () and peers stock prices informativeness ((n; c )) when we rely on co-movement to measure di erentiation. In columns (1) and (2), we observe that the increase in di erentiation post-ipo increases signi cantly with the intensity of insider trading, but not with the pro tability of insiders trades. Columns (3) to (6) we nd that the increase in product di erentiation for IPO (relative to counterfactual pairs) is signi cantly smaller when the stock price of peer rms is more informative, with the exception of analyst coverage where we observe a smaller decrease in i;j when the established peers of newly-public rms have more informative prices. D Di erentiation and Prices Informativeness The "conformity e ect" highlighted by our model partly relies on the conjecture that the informativeness of the stock market about the common strategy is higher than the informativeness of the stock market about the unique strategy (Corollary 1). We provide empirical evidence that supports this claim by looking at the correlation between the uniqueness of a rm s product (i.e. its overall di erentiation) and the informativeness of its stock price. We measure the overall di erentiation of a given rm i in a given year t (present in the TNIC network) as the average (or median) value of i;j;t across all peers j, which we label as i;t. To measure the relationship between di erentiation and price informativeness we estimate the following speci cations. For the three proxies of price informativeness for which we have rm-year observations (PIN, ERC, and Coverage), we estimate the following model: i;t = 0 + 1 i;t + 2 log(a i;t ) + 3 MB i;t + 3 Age i;t + t + " i;t (13) where i;t is one of the proxy for the stock price informativeness of rm i used in Section 4.2.2 (PIN, ERC, and Coverage), A is rm i s total assets, MB its market-to-book ratio, 9

and Age its public age (i.e., time since its IPO). The t s are year- xed e ects. For the proxy taken from Bai, Philipon, and Savov (2014) where we do not have a rm-year level measure we instead estimate the following interacted speci cation: E i;t+k A i;t = 0 + 1 MB i;t + 2 (MB i;t i;t ) + 3 E i;t A i;t + t + " i;t (14) where E i;t+k is rm i s earnings in year t + k. We focus on three horizons k: one-, two-, and year-year ahead earnings (k = 1; 2; 3). [Insert Table IA.3 about Here] Table IA.3 reports the results of these estimations. Panel A con rms that overall di erentiation is negatively related to price informativeness. This relationship holds across all speci cations, and is statistically signi cant in ve out of six estimations. Firms that have more di erentiated products appear to have notably less informative stock prices. This result also appears in Panel B. We observe negative and signi cant coe cients on the interaction term MB i;t i;t across all speci cations, indicating that the current stock prices of more di erentiated rms have a lower ability to forecast future earnings they are less informative. E Firm-level Tests Using the same measure of overall rm di erentiation ( i;t ), we estimate the baseline speci cation (17) (in the paper), but focus on rm-year observations instead of rm-year-pair observations. To do so, we compute i;t for each IPO rms and their initial established peers over the ve years post-ipo ( = 0; 1::::; 5), selected as described in the paper. We assign IPO rms to the treated group, and their initial established peers in the non-treated group, and estimate the following speci cation: i;;t = i + 0 + 1 ( T reated i;;t ) + t + X i;;t + " i;;t (15) 10

where the subscripts i refers to rm i, t is calendar time, and 2 f0; :::; 5g is event-time (i.e., the time elapsed since the entry of rm i in the sample). The rm xed e ects ( i ) control for any time-invariant rm characteristics, and the calendar time xed e ects ( t ) control for common time-speci c factors a ecting the level of di erentiation across all rms. 3 The vector X controls for time-varying characteristics of rm i, namely its size (measured by total assets) and market-to-book ratios. We allow the error term (" i;;t ) to be correlated within pairs. By design, for every IPO rm we have several non-treated established rms. We estimate eq.(15) on a sample that includes all rm-year observations (for all IPO and established rms), and also on a restricted sample that eliminates duplicated established rms (i.e., a rm that can be a peer of several IPO rm in a given calendar year). [Insert Table IA.4 about Here] Table IA.4 present the results of the rm-level tests. Similar to the results we obtain using rm-pairs, we see that the coe cients on T reated are positive and signi cant. This indicates that IPO rms increase their overall degree of di erentiation in the ve years that follow their IPO signi cantly more than their established peers. Notably, we remark that the coe cients on are positive and mostly signi cant. Overall, rms become more di erentiated more unique over their lifetime. 3 Using rm i xed e ects instead of pair xed e ects yield qualitatively similar results. 11