The theory of taxation/2 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.14 Rosen)) Taxation and economic efficiency

Similar documents
Application: The Costs of Taxation

2007 Thomson South-Western

Lecture 8. Application: the cost of taxation

Application: The Costs of Taxation

The theory of taxation/3 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.15 Rosen) Desirable characteristics of tax systems (optimal taxation)

Any book of Microeconomics can be useful: Microeconomics and Behavior, R. H. Frank Microeconomic Analysis (H. Varian) 2/22/2016 1

Public Economics (ECON 131) Section #4: Labor Income Taxation

Application of Welfare Analysis: The Costs of Taxation

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS

Application: The Costs of Taxation

Soojae Moon Fall 2009 <Oct. 6>

SOLUTIONS TO TEXT PROBLEMS:

The theory of taxation (Stiglitz ch. 17, 18, 19; Gruber ch.19, 20; Rosen ch.13,14,15)

10.11 CONCEPTUAL PROBLEMS IN MEASURING SURPLUS. Consumer surplus is an ad-hoc measure, not derived from a welfare measure

Module 10. Lecture 37

Application: The Costs of Taxation

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Recitation #6 Week 02/15/2009 to 02/21/2009. Chapter 7 - Taxes

Microeconomics. Application: The Costs of Taxation. N. Gregory Mankiw. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich update C H A P T E R

The Effects of a Tax. Review from Chapter 6: The Effects of a Tax. The Effects of a Tax P. Application: The Costs of Taxation

Practice Questions and Answers from Lesson I-8: Taxes. Practice Questions and Answers from Lesson I-8: Taxes

The analysis of government intervention (Stiglitz ch.10; Gruber ch.2)

CASE FAIR OSTER PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS E L E V E N T H E D I T I O N. PEARSON 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

why how price quantity

Application: The Costs of Taxation P R I N C I P L E S O F. N. Gregory Mankiw. Review from Chapter 6

Econ Principles of Microeconomics - Assignment 2

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 1 with Solutions

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 2, Question 1

Incidence of Taxation

Chapter 12: Design of the Tax System. Historical Context

I. Taxes and Economic Welfare

Public Finance: The Economics of Taxation. The Economics of Taxation. Taxes: Basic Concepts

CHAPTER 17: PUBLIC CHOICE THEORY AND THE ECONOMICS OF TAXATION

Econ 551 Government Finance: Revenues Winter 2018

ECON 340/ Zenginobuz Fall 2011 STUDY QUESTIONS FOR THE FINAL. x y z w u A u B

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 7: Externalities, the Marginal Cost of Public Funds, and Imperfect Competition

Chapter 16: Equilibrium

Chapter 12 TAXES AND TAX POLICY Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin et al.)

Application: The Costs of Taxation

Figure a. The equilibrium price of Frisbees is $8 and the equilibrium quantity is six million Frisbees.

Optimal Taxation : (c) Optimal Income Taxation

Intermediate Microeconomics

MACROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH. 6 - INTRODUCTION TO TAXES.

The Economics of Public Policy 11. Tax Incidence and the Excess Burden of Taxation

PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM Welfare Analysis

2. 4. Market failures and the rationale for public intervention (Stiglitz ch.4, 7, 8; Gruber ch.5,6,7, Rosen 5,6)

AS/ECON 4070 AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2001

1 of 32. Market Efficiency and Government Intervention. Economics: Principles, Applications, and Tools O Sullivan, Sheffrin, Perez 6/e.

PRACTICE QUESTIONS CHAPTER 5

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

EQ: What is Price Elasticity of Supply?

Chapter 6. MODERN PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS Third Edition

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY: COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

Chapter 4. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work- Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization. Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

PBAF 516 YA Prof. Mark Long Practice Midterm Questions

Lecture 12: Taxes. Session ID: DDEE. EC101 DD & EE / Manove Taxes & International Trade p 1. EC101 DD & EE / Manove Clicker Question p 2

Quiz #1 Week 03/01/2009 to 03/07/2009

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

ECON 1001 B. Come to the PASS workshop with your mock exam complete. During the workshop you can work with other students to review your work.

2. 4. Market failures and the rationale for public intervention (Stiglitz ch.4, 7, 8; Gruber ch.5,6,7, Rosen 5,6)

2. 4. Market failures and the rationale for public intervention (Stiglitz ch.4, 7, 8; Gruber ch.5,6,7, Rosen 5,6)

Tax Incidence ADE Fall

THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE

Lab #7. Chapter 7 Growth, Productivity, and Wealth in the Long Run

SOLUTIONS. ECO 100Y L0201 INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS Midterm Test # 1 LAST NAME FIRST NAME STUDENT NUMBER. University of Toronto June 22, 2006

Leandro Conte UniSi, Department of Economics and Statistics. Money, Macroeconomic Theory and Historical evidence. SSF_ aa

Fiscal Consolidation Strategy: An Update for the Budget Reform Proposal of March 2013

Tax of $1. Quantity of wine

Lecture # 6 Elasticity/Taxes

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Taxes: Equity vs. Efficiency Part I The only difference between death and taxes is that death doesn't get worse every time Congress meets.

Answers To Chapter 7. Review Questions

market forces fail to achieve economically efficient outcomes.

Technical Appendix to "The Carbon Tax: Welfare Triangle, or Welfare Obelisk?" J. Huston McCulloch Beacon Blog (blog.independent.org) August 6, 2016

Sample Exam Questions/Chapter 7

CHAPTER 2 The Theory of Individual Labor Supply

Chapter 6. Introduction. Learning Objectives. Funding the Public Sector. Distinguish between average tax rates and marginal tax rates

Lecture 3: Tax Incidence and Efficiency Costs of Taxation

Learning Objectives. Chapter 6. Funding the Public Sector. Introduction

Economics 11: Solutions to Practice Final

Estimating the Distortionary Costs of Income Taxation in New Zealand

The Deadweight Loss of Taxation

The Principles of Taxation

MARKING SCHEME Section A: Microeconomics

UTILITY THEORY AND WELFARE ECONOMICS

Cal Poly Pomona, EC Bruce Brown NAME (please clearly print your family name with all capital letters)

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Basics of Economics. Alvin Lin. Principles of Microeconomics: August December 2016

Introductory Economics of Taxation. Lecture 1: The definition of taxes, types of taxes and tax rules, types of progressivity of taxes

ECONOMICS EXAMINATION OBJECTIVES

Economics Lecture Sebastiano Vitali

Chapter 12. The Design of the Tax System. Introduction. Introduction. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

Test Canvas. Question 1 Multiple Choice 10 points Modify Remove

Practice Test 1: Multiple Choice

Eastern Mediterranean University Faculty of Business and Economics Department of Economics Fall Semester. ECON 101 Mid term Exam

Lecture 6 Notes. Maria Zhu Duke University. November 16, 2016

1. Consider a small country (Thailand) with the following demand and supply curves for steel:

AP Microeconomics Chapter 16 Outline

1 Excess burden of taxation

Transcription:

The theory of taxation/2 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.14 Rosen)) Taxation and economic efficiency 1

Taxation and economic efficiency Most taxes introduce deadweight losses because they alter relative prices and the allocation of resources (example: the window tax in 17 century Britain induced the construction of windowless houses!!; or tax on finished houses in Cyprus ). Only Lump sum taxes are non distortionary because they are fixed and do not depend on alterable characteristics such as wealth or income or individuals/firms behaviour. An example of non distortionary tax is a retroactive tax on last year income. But it works only once, otherwise it may affect expectations and it becomes distortionary. Lump sum taxes are very difficult to implement in practice and often have negative equity effects. They represent a benchmark to analyse the efficiency effects of taxation. Also corrective taxes, levied to correct market failures, such as negative externalities (pollution taxes, taxes on cigarettes, ) rise revenue (and thus reduce the reliance on other taxes) and improve economic efficiency (double dividend). 2

Examples of Tax Avoidance (Gruber) The inefficiency of any tax is determined by the extent to which consumers and producers change their behavior to avoid the tax. EXAMPLES OF TAX AVOIDANCE 1. A British boat designer lived in a home he constructed from a floating bridge. When the Britain s tax collectors attempted to collect property tax on the home, he began sailing it up and down the river. By the time he was done, he had collected so many different addresses that the Inland Revenue gave up their attempts. 2. An Englishman visiting Cyprus in the early 1980s asked a tour guide why so many of the houses seemed to have steel reinforcement bars jutting out from their top floors. The guide informed him that Cyprus had a building tax that applied only to finished structures. Owners of those houses could thus claim that they were still in the process of finishing the roof. 3. The Thai government levies a tax on signs in front of businesses. The tax is levied only on external signs and the rate depends on whether the sign is completely in Thai (low), in Thai and English (medium), or completely in English (very high). Thus in Bangkok many businesses hang English signs with a small amount of Thai writing in the upper-right-hand corner. Some manage to avoid the tax entirely by printing the message on curtains that are hung in the front window, rendering the sign internal and thus tax-exempt. 3 of 30

Taxation and Deadweight Loss/1 The DEADWEIGHT LOSS (DWL) measures the magnitude of the distorsions created by non lump sum taxes: Behavioural effects : deadweight loss is caused by individuals and firms making inefficient consumption and production choices in order to avoid taxation. Affected choices relate also to labour supply, education, savings, investment. Financial effects : transactions forms are affected because they are treated differently (example: fringe benefit or firms financial structure) Organisational effects : family formation and distribution of well being within families, firms organisation General equilibrium effects: indirect effects of taxes on wages or on the returns of capital Announcement effects: usually adjustment to a new tax is slow, but announcements on future taxes may affect expectations and alter the behaviour of economic individuals and firms. 4

Deadweight Loss of a commodity tax Adding a per unit tax T (on the producer or the consumer) increases the price and reduces the quantity traded. The efficiency loss (DWL) of the tax is determined by the reduction in quantity traded. The loss affects both consumers and producers. The Consumer surplus falls for two reasons: a) the consumer pays a higher price for the units still consumed, this loss is area B b) the tax rises the price higher then the willingness to pay for some units that were previously consumed, so these units are not purchased and consumer surplus falls by area C The Producer surplus falls because the quantity sold are lower than before (area E) and the price he gets for the units produced is lower (area D). 5

DWL of a commodity tax The total loss of consumers and producers in the market is the area (B+C+E+D) This is not the overall loss for society, because the area (B +D) is government revenue from the tax (given by the amount of the unit tax multiplied by the quantity sold in the market when the tax is in place). The DWL is the area C+E 6

Welfare loss with a sales tax on production increasing price above the competitive price p*: Consumers pay p 1 and producers get p 0 p c p1 A Consumer surplus: D from ( A + B + C) to A S after tax DWL= C + E tax p* p 0 a B D F C E S pre-tax Tax Revenues: B + D Producer surplus: from (D + E + F) to F 0 Q 1 Q* Q 7

How a Tax Affects Welfare

What determines whether the deadweight loss from a tax is large or small? The magnitude of the deadweight loss depends on how much the quantity supplied and quantity demanded respond to changes in the price. That, in turn, depends on the price elasticities of supply and demand. The greater the elasticities of demand and supply: the larger will be the decline in equilibrium quantity and, the greater the deadweight loss of a tax. 9

DWL and demand and supply elasticities The DWL is higher the higher are demand and supply elasticities. If the demand curve is inelastic, consumers will buy the same quantity of the taxed good regardless of its price and changes of prices do not distort consumption decisions. There is no DWL, because there is no change in quantity consumed. Similarly if the supply curve is inelastic, the quantity produced is fixed and not affected by changes in prices and no distortions occur If one of the curve is inelastic there is no DWL because there is no change in the quantity exchanged in the market: If supply is completely inelastic (vertical curve), the elasticity of demand is irrelevant If demand is inelastic, the elasticity of supply is irrelevant. 10

DWL of a commodity tax: Elasticities Determine the size of the DWL (Tax Inefficiency) J. Gruber (2007), Public finance and public policies, Fig. 20-2

Taxation and DWL: the DWL captures the substitution effect of taxation. A tax has two effects on the quantity demanded of the taxed good/ service/ production factor : a) an income effect leading to a decline in the demand of all goods/services. This effect is present also with lump sum taxes and does not generate DWL because is compensated by increased tax revenues b) a substitution effect which induces a decline in the consumption of the taxed good relative to others, due to changes in relative prices. The DWL captures the substitution effect of taxation. Example If you always buy 50 apples and their price rises by 1 euro due to a tax, it s like losing 50 euro, which go to the government. But even if the 50 euro are returned to you, you will probably still buy fewer apples than before because their price is now higher relative to other fruit. 12

Example: income and substitution effect of a sales tax on beer Total effect: from Q 0 to Q 1. Q other goods Budget after tax F A Q 1 Q E Q 0 E E** Income effect: from Q 0 to Q (from E to E ). Substitution effect: from Q to Q 1 (from E to E*). AE* tax revenue generated by the sales tax. E*F extra tax revenue that would be generated by a lump sum tax. This is the deadweight loss of adopting a sales tax instead of a lump sum tax. We could get the same tax revenue AE*, leaving the consumer on a higher utility curve at point E** Budget constraint before tax Q beer 13

Taxation and DWL A tax that alters relative prices lowers the individual utility more than it is necessary to raise the given amount of government revenues. In the figure above we can get the same tax revenue AE* leaving the consumer on a higher indifference curve (with only an Income effect). The DWL measures the excess burden of the tax and its inefficiency. For a tax on a commodity, both the income and substitution effects lead usually to a reduction in the consumption of that commodity 14

Taxation and DWL: Tax on labour income and effects on labour supply/1 A tax on labour income reduces net wages with an effect on labour supply that depends on the relative size of the income and the substitution effects: the income effect increases labour supply, the substitution effect reduces labour supply, since the price of leisure (opportunity cost) is the income forgone for not working, this declines when net wage declines and thus more leisure is demanded and less time is supplied in the labour market. If the substitution effect is larger than the income effect, taxation may have a disincentive effect on labour supply, reducing it. This effect is more likely at higher income levels. Empirical evidence shows differences between men and women: for men the two effects are of the same magnitude and the net effect is null or very small (inelastic labour supply); for women the substitution effect is higher than the income effect and a decline in net wage reduces their participation to the labour market (elastic labour supply). 15

Disincentive effects of taxes on wages income E E 0 Income effect: from E 0 to E (less leisure, more labour supply); Substitution effect: from E to E 1 (more leisure and less labour supply). Net effect: from E 0 to E 1: lower labour supply The net effect depends on individual preferences (i.e. on the relative size of income and substitution effects). In this case the net effect is a reduction in labour supply: SE > IE. Post-tax Budget constraint L 1 L 0 E 1 Pre tax budget constraint Leisure 16

Taxation and DWL: Tax on labour income and effects on labour supply/2 Some economists argue that labor taxes are highly distorting and believe that labor supply is more elastic. Some examples of workers who may respond more to incentives: Workers who can adjust the number of hours they work Families with second earners Elderly who can choose when to retire Workers in the underground economy (i.e., those engaging in illegal activity) 17

Determinants of DWL /1 If the demand and supply curves are straight lines, the DWL can be approximated by the area of the triangle with base t and height ΔQ =(Q*-Q 1 ) DWL =-1/2 dqdt. We can express the DWL in terms of elasticities. With perfect competition the elasticiy of supply is infinite and the only relevant elasticity is that of demand. In this case the DWL is: DWL = - (½) t 2 η d QP and the marginal deadweight loss is the marginal increase in DWL per unit increase of the tax and raises with the tax rate: MDWL = t η d Q More generally the formula for the DWL is: 18

Determinants of DWL /2 The DWL of a tax thus depends on three variables: 1. the square of the commodity tax rate t: the DWL rises with the square of the tax rate. The increase in DWL per unit increase in the tax,(i.e. the marginal DWL) rises with the tax rate: doubling the tax rate more than doubles the DWL. High tax rates are more distortionary than low tax rates and large fluctuations in tax rates produce higher DWL than tax smoothing.. 2. the elasticity (or flatness) of demand and supply which measures how much the quantity demanded or supplied of a good/service change when its price changes. Deadweight loss increases with the absolute value of the elasticities (note that if either elasticity is zero, there is no DWB). 3. the size of the market for the taxed good/services: Q 19

The Marginal DWL raises with the Tax rate J. Gruber (2007), Public finance and public policies, Fig. 20-3 20

DWL increases with absolute value of elasticies 21

Implications for tax policy With many goods the most efficient (keeping DWL as low as possible) way to raise tax revenue is: to tax relatively more the inelastic goods. E.g. medical drugs, food. But equity issues to spread the taxes across all goods so as to keep tax rates relatively low on all goods (because DWB increases with the square of the tax rate) 22

Deadweight loss and tax revenue as taxes vary As the size of a tax increases, its deadweight loss quickly gets larger. By contrast, tax revenue first rises with the size of a tax, but then, as the tax gets larger, the market shrinks so much that tax revenue starts to fall.

Copyright 2004 South-Western As the size of a tax increases, its deadweight loss quickly gets larger. Deadweight Loss (a) Deadweight Loss Figure 7 How Deadweight Loss and Tax Revenue Vary with the Size of a Tax 0 Tax Size

The Laffer Curve and Supply-side Economics The Laffer curve illustrates the relationship between tax rates and tax revenue. Supply-side economics refers to the views of Reagan and Laffer who proposed that a tax cut would induce more people to work and thereby have the potential to increase tax revenues.

Copyright 2004 South-Western The Laffer Curve Tax Revenue (b) Revenue (the Laffer curve) 0 Tax Size

A Tax System s Efficiency Is Affected by a Market s Preexisting Distortions: The case of a pre-existing negative externality J. Gruber (2007), Public finance and public policies, Fig. 20-4 27

Summary A tax on a good reduces the welfare of buyers and sellers of the good, and the reduction in consumer and producer surplus usually exceeds the revenues raised by the government. The fall in total surplus the sum of consumer surplus, producer surplus, and tax revenue is called the deadweight loss of the tax.

Summary Taxes have a deadweight loss because they cause buyers to consume less and sellers to produce less. This change in behavior shrinks the size of the market below the level that maximizes total surplus.

Summary As a tax grows larger, it distorts incentives more, and its deadweight loss grows larger. Tax revenue first rises with the size of a tax. Eventually, however, a larger tax reduces tax revenue because it reduces the size of the market.

Tax smoothing In order to avoid the negative effects on the MDWL of increasing tax rates over time, government efficiency in taxation over time is maximized by tax smoothing, maintaining a relatively constant tax rate over time rather than high taxes in some periods and low taxes in others. 31

EXAMPLE: The Deadweight Loss of Taxing Wireless Communications Hausman (2000) estimated the deadweight loss from a particularly dynamic sector : wireless communications services. In 1999, the state and federal tax burden on wireless communication was in most states 14.5%, although the rate was 25% in high-tax states. Hausman estimated that for every dollar the government raised in taxes, social welfare was reduced by 53. This figure is high for three reasons: High elasticity of demand: demand for wireless communications is fairly price sensitive. There is already a large preexisting distortion in this market. The taxes are fairly high, and the marginal deadweight loss rises with the tax rate. Hausman estimated that the marginal deadweight loss caused by an additional tax on wireless services ranged from 72 to 90 per dollar raised. 32 of 30