Not-for-Publication Appendix to:

Similar documents
Government Spending Multipliers in Good Times and in Bad: Evidence from U.S. Historical Data

UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES

Estimating the effects of fiscal policy in Structural VAR models

ON THE LONG-TERM MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SOCIAL SPENDING IN THE UNITED STATES (*) Alfredo Marvão Pereira The College of William and Mary

Government Spending Shocks in Quarterly and Annual Time Series

New evidence on the effects of US monetary policy on exchange rates

Monetary policy transmission in Switzerland: Headline inflation and asset prices

Misspecification, Identification or Measurement? Another Look at the Price Puzzle

Online Appendix to Do Tax Changes Affect Credit Markets and Financial Frictions? Evidence from Credit Spreads

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

MONETARY ECONOMICS Objective: Overview of Theoretical, Empirical and Policy Issues in Modern Monetary Economics

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for?

Government Spending Shocks in Quarterly and Annual Time Series

The Changing Macroeconomic Response to Stock Market Volatility Shocks *

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions

The Impacts of State Tax Structure: A Panel Analysis

Does the Confidence Fairy Exist?

For Online Publication. The macroeconomic effects of monetary policy: A new measure for the United Kingdom: Online Appendix

ECON : Topics in Monetary Economics

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW LARGE ARE THE EFFECTS OF TAX CHANGES? Carlo Favero Francesco Giavazzi

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Effects of monetary policy shocks on the trade balance in small open European countries

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ARE GOVERNMENT SPENDING MULTIPLIERS GREATER DURING PERIODS OF SLACK? EVIDENCE FROM 20TH CENTURY HISTORICAL DATA

A Singular Achievement of Recent Monetary Policy

BANK LOAN COMPONENTS AND THE TIME-VARYING EFFECTS OF MONETARY POLICY SHOCKS

5. STRUCTURAL VAR: APPLICATIONS

CONFIDENCE AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: THE CASE OF PORTUGAL*

Monetary Policy and Long-term U.S. Interest Rates

Monetary and Fiscal Policy Switching with Time-Varying Volatilities

Incorporate Financial Frictions into a

Central bank losses and monetary policy rules: a DSGE investigation

Econ 210C: Macroeconomic Theory

Credit Spreads and the Macroeconomy

No Matthias Neuenkirch. Monetary Policy Transmission in Vector Autoregressions: A New Approach Using Central Bank Communication

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

IMPACT OF SOME OVERSEAS MONETARY VARIABLES ON INDONESIA: SVAR APPROACH

Bonn Summer School Advances in Empirical Macroeconomics

What Drives Fiscal Multipliers? The Role of Private Debt and Wealth

Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies

Debt and the Effects of Fiscal Policy

Estimating the Economic Impacts of Highway Infrastructure

Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability

Mood Swings and Business Cycles: Evidence from Sign Restrictions

The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 40, No. 4, Winter, 2009, pp

Volume 38, Issue 1. The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis

A Threshold Multivariate Model to Explain Fiscal Multipliers with Government Debt

Government Spending Multipliers under Zero Lower Bound: Evidence from Japan

D6.3 Policy Brief: The role of debt for fiscal effectiveness during crisis and normal times

Interest Rate Peg. Rong Li and Xiaohui Tian. January Abstract. This paper revisits the sizes of fiscal multipliers under a pegged nominal

Are Predictable Improvements in TFP Contractionary or Expansionary: Implications from Sectoral TFP? *

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes

On the new Keynesian model

National Bank of the Republic of Macedonia Working Paper No. 3/2017

Debt Burdens and the Interest Rate Response to Fiscal Stimulus: Theory and Cross-Country Evidence.

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Advanced Macroeconomics

The role of house prices in the monetary policy transmission mechanism in the U.S.

How does an increase in government purchases affect the economy?

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Gernot Müller (University of Bonn, CEPR, and Ifo)

Deposit Interest Rate Ceilings as Credit Supply Shifters: Bank Level Evidence on the Effects of Regulation Q

Online Appendix for The Heterogeneous Responses of Consumption between Poor and Rich to Government Spending Shocks

HONG KONG INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY RESEARCH

Asian Economic and Financial Review SOURCES OF EXCHANGE RATE FLUCTUATION IN VIETNAM: AN APPLICATION OF THE SVAR MODEL

Regional Business Cycles In the United States

SOME PARTICULARITIES OF THE MONETARY TRANSMISSION CHANNELS IN ROMANIA

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Macroeconomic Uncertainty Indices Based on Nowcast and Forecast Error Distributions Online Appendix

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Discussion of DSGE Models for Monetary Policy. Discussion of

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Estimating and Accounting for the Output Gap with Large Bayesian Vector Autoregressions

Topic 3, continued. RBCs

How do stock prices respond to fundamental shocks?

Tax Cuts for Whom? Heterogeneous Effects of Income Tax Changes on Growth and Employment

MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies

Oil Price Shock and Macroeconomic Activities in Nigeria

Web Appendix. Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? Olivier Coibion

), is described there by a function of the following form: U (c t. )= c t. where c t

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MONETARY POLICY AND SECTORAL SHOCKS: DID THE FED REACT PROPERLY TO THE HIGH-TECH CRISIS? Claudio Raddatz Roberto Rigobon

LECTURE 3 The Effects of Monetary Changes: Vector Autoregressions. September 7, 2016

Government Spending Multipliers under the Zero Lower Bound: Evidence from Japan

Appendix for The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model

Monetary Policy and Market Interest Rates in Brazil

Optimal fiscal policy

Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? *

The Liquidity Effect in Bank-Based and Market-Based Financial Systems. Johann Scharler *) Working Paper No October 2007

Learning and Time-Varying Macroeconomic Volatility

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

Risk, Uncertainty and Monetary Policy

WestminsterResearch

Uncertainty and the Transmission of Fiscal Policy

THE volatility of macroeconomic variables has received increasing

Transcription:

Not-for-Publication Appendix to: What Is the Importance of Monetary and Fiscal Shocks in Explaining US Macroeconomic Fluctuations? Barbara Rossi Duke University Sarah Zubairy Bank of Canada Email: brossi@econ.duke.edu Email: szubairy@bankofcanada.ca Phone: (919) 66-181 Phone: (613) 78-81 December, 1 1

This appendix provides a detailed description of the data. It also investigates whether the main findings in the paper (such as the differences in the relative importance of government spending and monetary policy shocks at various frequencies) are robust to sub-sample analysis, the inclusion of taxes, different monetary policy identification schemes, and changes in trend due to the great productivity slowdown. For completeness, Figures 1 and respectively report the impulse responses to both government spending and monetary policy shocks identified in eq. (1) in the main paper. The main results in the paper are robust to changing the order of the variables in X t. 1 Data Description Table 1: Data Series Description and Sources Label Frequency Description Source GDP Q Gross domestic product BEA (Table 1.1.) GCD Q Personal consumption expenditures on durable goods BEA (Table 1.1.) GCN Q Personal consumption expenditures on nondurable goods BEA (Table 1.1.) GCS Q Personal consumption expenditures on services BEA (Table 1.1.) GPI Q Gross private domestic investment BEA (Table 1.1.) GGE Q Government consumption expenditures and gross investment BEA (Table 1.1.) GDPQ Q Real gross domestic product BEA (Table 1.1.6) P16 Q Civilian non-institutional population, over 16 BLS (LNUQ) LBMNU Q Non-farm business hours worked BLS (PRS8633) LBCPU Q Hourly non-farm business compensation BLS (PRS8613) FYFF M Federal funds rate St. Louis FRED GGFR Q Federal tax receipts BEA (Table 3.) GGAID Q Federal grants in aid BEA (Table 3.) GGFTP Q Federal transfer payments to persons BEA (Table 3.) GGFINT Q Federal interest payments BEA (Table 3.) GGSR Q State and local tax receipts BEA (Table 3.3) GGST Q State and local transfer payments to persons BEA (Table 3.3) GGSINT Q State and local net interest payments to persons BEA (Table 3.3) TRARR M Total reserves Federal Reserve Board NONBORTAF M Non-borrowed reserves of depository institutions Federal Reserve Board M1SL M M1 money stock Federal Reserve Board

Table : Data Series in the VAR. Label Description Construction GDPDEF GDP deflator GDPQ/GDP NETTAX Tax receipts net of transfer payments GGFR+GGSR-GGAID-GGFTP-GGFINT-GGSINT G t Real per-capita government spending GGE/(P16*GDPDEF) Y t Real per-capita GDP GDPQ/P16 h t Per-capita hours worked LBMNU/P16 c t Real per-capita consumption (GCN+GCS)/(P16*GDPDEF) i t Real per-capita investment (GPI+GCD)/(P16*GDPDEF) w t Real wages LBCPU/GDPDEF π t Inflation GDPDEF r t Fed Funds rate FYFF T t Real net taxes NETTAX/(P16*GDPDEF) tr t Total reserves TR nbr t Non-borrowed reserves NBR m t M1 money supply M1 Note: the VAR includes all series in log-levels, except for r t, which is in levels. 3

Robustness Analysis A. Sub-sample analysis First, we assess whether our results are robust over time. We divide the data into subsamples identified consistently with the Great Moderation (Stock and Watson, and 3). We impose a structural break in 198:1, the estimated date of the break in the volatility of US GDP growth documented by McConnell and Perez-Quiros (). The results from the spectral decomposition of GDP for the two sub-samples is given in Table 3. Due to the smaller sample size of the two sub-samples, we select the VAR lag length to be one, as suggested by the BIC criterion. In the first sub-sample, the relative importance of government spending shocks at medium cycle frequencies is very high relative to business cycle frequencies, and the difference is much smaller for the second sub-sample. Overall, however, government spending shocks play a larger role at medium cycles relative to monetary policy shocks. In particular, government spending shocks explain a larger percentage of the variance of GDP at medium cycle relative to business cycle frequencies in both sub-samples. On the other hand, the importance of monetary policy shocks has changed over time: they are very important in explaining the variance of GDP at business cycle frequencies in the first sub-sample, similarly to the results previously reported in Section for the full sample, but they play a limited role at both frequencies in the second sub-sample. INSERT TABLE 3 HERE B. Robustness to the inclusion of taxes It is well known from basic macroeconomic models that the intertemporal government budget constraint has to be satisfied, and therefore, it might be important to include taxes in our empirical analysis. Table, Panel A, reports the contribution of the government spending shocks to output fluctuations at both business and medium cycle frequencies when net taxes are added to the baseline VAR. That is, we estimate the same VAR as eq. (1) in the main paper, except that now Z t = (G t, T t, X t, r t ), where T t are tax receipts net of transfers and all other variables are as defined in Section. 1 By comparing Table and Table 1, it is clear that our results for output are unaffected by the addition of taxes, and 1 The tax variable is defined exactly as in Blanchard and Perotti ().

government spending shocks play an important role primarily in explaining medium cycle frequencies. INSERT TABLE HERE C. Other monetary policy identification schemes An additional concern is that we identified the monetary policy shock as a shock to the federal funds rate in a VAR that does not include other monetary variables. We therefore consider alternative VARs that include nonborrowed reserves, total reserves and money supply (M1) following the benchmark recursive identification schemes discussed in Christiano et al. (, Section.). In a first experiment, reported in Table, Panel B(i), we estimate the same VAR as in eq. (1) in the main paper, except that Z t = (G t, X t, r t, tr t, nbr t, m t ), where tr t is total reserves, nbr t is nonborrowed reserves plus extended credit, m t is a measure of money supply (M1), and the other variables are as defined in Section. 3 Following Christiano et al. (), these additional monetary variables are ordered after the federal funds rate (r t ), so that the information set of the monetary authority includes current and lagged values of G t and X t, and lagged values of the other monetary variables. In a second experiment, reported in Table, Panel B(ii), the monetary policy shock is identified as a shock to nonborrowed reserves in a VAR with the following ordering: Z t = (G t, X t, nbr t, r t, tr t, m t ). The results reported in Panel B show that the percentage contribution of the government spending shock at both business and medium cycle frequencies is extremely robust to the inclusion of additional monetary variables. Looking at monetary policy, overall the contribution of the monetary policy shocks identified as shocks to nonborrowed reserves rather than a shock to the federal funds rate is smaller, a finding consistent with Christiano et al. (, Table 3). However, consistently with our previous results, we note that, again, the contribution of the monetary policy shock is more substantial at business cycle than at medium cycle frequencies. D. Alternative de-trending procedures The benchmark VAR specification in Section assumes a linear deterministic time trend. However, linearly de-trending output with a constant time trend might induce low frequency Mertens and Ravn (9) study the effects of tax changes identified on the basis of narrative evidence of Romer and Romer (7), and conclude that tax shocks account for close to % of variation in output at business cycle frequencies. 3 Due to limited data availability for nonborrowed reserves, total reserves and M1, in this sub-section the VAR is estimated for data spanning 199:1-6:.

movements in the presence of a substantial productivity slowdown such as that of 1973. It might be of concern that it is the government shock that captures those low frequency movements, since it is the most important shock at medium cycles. For these reasons, we also consider a VAR estimated with a break in trend: Z t = K + Γ 1 t + Γ d t t + A (L) Z t 1 + B (L) ε R t + u t (1) where d t is a dummy variable equal to one after 1973:1 and zero otherwise. The dummy variable captures the break in trend associated with the great productivity slowdown (see Baily and Gordon, 1988). The contributions of the government spending shock at the business and medium cycle frequencies become.3 and 1.3 respectively, thus showing that our main conclusions are also robust to breaks in trends associated with the productivity slowdown of 1973. References [1] Baily, M.N., and R.J. Gordon (1988), The Productivity Slowdown, Measurement Issues, and the Explosion of Computer Power, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (), 37-. [] Blanchard, O. and R. Perotti (), An Empirical Characterization of the Dynamic Effects of Changes in Government Spending and Taxes in Output, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117-, 139-1368. [3] Christiano, L., M. Eichenbaum and C. Evans (), Monetary Policy Shocks: What Have We Learned and to What End,, in: Taylor, John B. and Woodford, Michael, eds. Handbook of Macroeconomics, Volume 1A. Amsterdam; New York and Oxford: Elsevier Science, North-Holland. [] McConnell, M. and G. Perez-Quiros (), Output Fluctuations in the United States: What Has Changed Since the Early 198 s?, American Economic Review, 9(), 16-176. We also verified that our main results are robust to estimating a stochastic rather than a deterministic trend, using a VAR where Z t = ( G t, (Y t h t ), h t, c t Y t, i t Y t, Y t h t w t, π t, r t ). 6

[] Mertens, K. and M. O. Ravn (9) Empirical evidence on the aggregate effects of anticipated and unanticipated US tax policy shocks, National Bank of Belgium Research Series 911-13. [6] Romer, C.D. and D.H. Romer (7), The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: Estimates Based on a New Measure of Fiscal Shocks, NBER Working Paper, 136. [7] Stock, J. H. and M.W. Watson (), Has the Business Cycle Changed and Why?, in: M. Gertler and K. Rogoff (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual. [8] Stock, J. H. and M.W. Watson (3), Has the Business Cycle Changed? Evidence and Explanations, FRB Kansas City Symposium, Jackson Hole. 7

Sub-sample I (19:3-198:1) Table 3: Sub-sample Robustness Analysis. Business Cycle component Medium Cycle component ( π 16 π 3 ) ( π 1 π 16 ) Percentage contribution of ϵ g,t 7.1 6. Percentage contribution of ϵ r,t 1..9 Sub-sample II (198:-6:) Percentage contribution of ϵ g,t 1.1 1.3 Percentage contribution of ϵ r,t 1.. Note: The top panel shows the contribution of government spending shock and monetary shocks in explaining GDP at the business and medium cycle frequencies for the first sub-sample (19:3-198:1), and the bottom panel shows the contribution of both shocks in explaining GDP for the second sub-sample (198:-6:). 8

A. Including net taxes in the VAR Table : Robustness Analyses. Business Cycle component Medium Cycle component ( π 16 π 3 ) ( π 1 π 16 ) Percentage contribution of ε g,t.1 3.9 Percentage contribution of ε r,t 1.1 13.8 B. Additional monetary variables in the VAR (i) Monetary policy shock identified as a shock to the FFR Percentage contribution of ε g,t.9 9. Percentage contribution of ε r,t 9.3 7.3 (ii) Monetary policy shock identified as a shock to Non-borrowed reserves Percentage contribution of ε g,t.9 9. Percentage contribution of ε nbr,t 3..9 Note: Panel A (top) reports the contribution of the government spending shock to output fluctuations at business and medium cycle frequencies when net taxes are added to the baseline VAR. Panel B (bottom) reports the contribution of the government spending shock to output fluctuations at business and medium cycle frequencies when additional monetary variables (nonborrowed reserves, total reserves and money supply) are added to the baseline VAR. The monetary policy shock is identified either as a shock to the federal funds rate Panel B(i) or as a shock to nonborrowed reserves Panel B(ii). 9

Govt. spending x 1 3 Output x 1 3 Hours.1.1. 8 6 3 1 3 1 x 1 3 Consumption x 1 Inflation x 1 3 Investment 1 1 x 1 3 Federal funds rate x 1 3 Real wage Figure 1: Impulse Responses to the Government Spending Shock identified in eq.(1). The shaded regions are 9% confidence bands obtained by Monte Carlo simulations. 6 x 1 3 Govt. spending x 1 3 Consumption x 1 Inflation 1 6 x 1 3 Output..1.1 6 Investment x 1 3 Federal funds rate 8 x 1 3 Hours 3 1 x 1 3 Real wage Figure : Impulse Responses to the Monetary Policy Shock identified in eq.(1). The shaded regions are 9% confidence bands obtained by Monte Carlo simulations. 1