Lecture 3: New Trade Theory

Similar documents
Economic Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade

Lecture 3: International trade under imperfect competition

Monopolistic competition models

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

International Trade. Lecture 3: the Krugman model of trade. Thomas Chaney. Sciences Po. Thomas Chaney (Sciences Po) International Trade 1 / 24

Lecture 12: New Economic Geography

Discussion Papers In Economics And Business

International Trade Gravity Model

The Effects of Regional Free Trade Agreements on Industrial Structure: An Extension of Krugman s Economic Geography Model (1991)

International Trade: Lecture 4

International Trade: Lecture 3

The Composition of Knowledge and Long-Run Growth

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

Monopolistic competition: the Dixit-Stiglitz-Spence model

New Trade Theory I. Part A: Simple monopolistic competition model. Robert Stehrer. The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies - wiiw

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

NOT FOR PUBLICATION. Theory Appendix for The China Syndrome. Small Open Economy Model

A Thesis. Presented to the Faculty of the Graduate School. of Cornell University. in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade.

Bilateral Trade in Textiles and Apparel in the U.S. under the Caribbean Basin Initiative: Gravity Model Approach

The heterogeneous effects of trade facilitation: theory and evidence

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

International Trade Lecture 1: Trade Facts and the Gravity Equation

The Dixit-Stiglitz-Krugman Trade Model: A Geometric Note

Firms in International Trade. Lecture 2: The Melitz Model

International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003)

Gravity, Trade Integration and Heterogeneity across Industries

Neue Erkenntnisse der Außenwirtschaftstheorie von Ricardo bis Melitz

Theory Appendix for: Buyer-Seller Relationships in International Trade: Evidence from U.S. State Exports and Business-Class Travel

Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices

Labor Market Rigidities, Trade and Unemployment

Melitz Model: Heterogenous Firm Model of Trade

Trade and Labor Market: Felbermayr, Prat, Schmerer (2011)

Economics 689 Texas A&M University

International Trade Lecture 1: Trade Facts and the Gravity Equation

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Simulations of the macroeconomic effects of various

} Number of floors, presence of a garden, number of bedrooms, number of bathrooms, square footage of the house, type of house, age, materials, etc.

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory Ariel Zetlin-Jones and Ali Shourideh

The Gravity Model of Trade

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

International Economics B 9. Monopolistic competition and international trade: Firm Heterogeneity

(b) per capita consumption grows at the rate of 2%.

International Trade Lecture 23: Trade Policy Theory (I)

Volume 30, Issue 4. A decomposition of the home-market effect

Graduate Public Finance

Heterogeneous Firms. Notes for Graduate Trade Course. J. Peter Neary. University of Oxford. January 30, 2013

Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev

Geography and Path Dependence

Introduction Intuitive Gravity Structural Gravity Discrete Choice Gravity. The Gravity Model. James E. Anderson. Boston College and NBER.

Modelling International Trade

Gravity, Distance, and International Trade

The Impact of the Tax Cut and Jobs Act on the Spatial Distribution of High Productivity Households and Economic Welfare

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

International Economics: Lecture 10 & 11

Technology, Geography and Trade J. Eaton and S. Kortum. Topics in international Trade

Foreign Direct Investment I

C) a decrease in the wage and an increase in the return to capital in the receiving country.

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

ECO2704 Lecture Notes: Melitz Model

Global Production with Export Platforms

Impact of Tariff under Hecksher-Ohlin Comparative Advantage Setting and Firm Heterogeneity

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters

Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Welfare Consequences of Globalization

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Institutional Distance and Foreign Direct Investment

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets

Global Sourcing. Pol Antràs and Elhanan Helpman

Université Paris I Panthéon-Sorbonne Cours de Commerce International L3 Exercise booklet

Duty drawbacks, Competitiveness and Growth: The Case of China. Elena Ianchovichina Economic Policy Unit, PREM Network World Bank

Gravity in the Weightless Economy

International Trade Lecture 5: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition

Advanced Macro and Money (WS09/10) Problem Set 4

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

A Theory on the Role of Wholesalers in International Trade Based on Economies of Scope

Dynamic Market Making and Asset Pricing

ECO 445/545: International Trade. Jack Rossbach Spring 2016

Lecture 2: The neo-classical model of international trade

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

A Structural Model of Continuous Workout Mortgages (Preliminary Do not cite)

Location, Productivity, and Trade

Final Exam Solutions

Suggested Solutions to Assignment 7 (OPTIONAL)

Testing the predictions of the Solow model: What do the data say?

Optimal Redistribution in an Open Economy

Realization Utility. Nicholas Barberis Yale University. Wei Xiong Princeton University

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

The new Kenesian model

The Location of Domestic and Foreign Production Affiliates by French Multinational Firms

FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION

Public Affairs 856 Trade, Competition, and Governance in a Global Economy Lecture 7-9 2/8-15/2016

Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment

Generalized Multi-Factor Commodity Spot Price Modeling through Dynamic Cournot Resource Extraction Models

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot

Transcription:

Lecture 3: New Trade Theory Isabelle Méjean isabelle.mejean@polytechnique.edu http://mejean.isabelle.googlepages.com/ Master Economics and Public Policy, International Macroeconomics October 30 th, 2008

New Trade Models Dixit-Stiglitz model of monopolistic competition makes it possible to integrate both increasing returns to scale (IRS) and imperfect competition in a highly tractable general-equilibrium setting IRS generates agglomeration of activities in a homogeneous space IRS is incompatible with perfect competition Need for imperfect competition General equilibrium accounts for interactions between product and labor markets

Monopolistic competition Chamberlian (1933) Four assumptions: Firms sell products of the same nature but that are imperfect substitutes Varieties of a differentiated good Every firm produces a single variety under IRS and chooses its price The number of firms is sufficiently large for each of them to be negligible with respect to the whole group Free entry and exit drives profits to zero Each firm has some monopoly power but each producer is constrained in its price choice The resource constraint imposes a limit on the number of varieties

Scale economies, Product differentiation and the Pattern of Trade ()

Motivation Introduction Standard models explain trade as a way to increase aggregate surplus through specialization according to comparative advantage Unable to explain intra-industry trade No role for demand in driving international trade New Trade Theory explains international trade on differentiated varieties Ingredients: Increasing returns to scale, imperfect competition and international trade costs

Hypotheses Introduction Two regions of size L and L, Same technology (no comparative advantages) Two sectors: Agriculture (homogeneous product, perfect competition, no trade costs) and Manufacturing (differentiated good, IRS, monopolistic competition, costly trade) U = C µ M C 1 µ A, 0 < µ < 1 Dixit-Stiglitz preferences over varieties of the differentiated good Composite good! σ NX σ 1 C M = c σ 1 σ i, σ > 1 i=1 Note that the limiting case σ = 1 boils down to a Cobb-Douglas subutility function, while σ implies that varieties are perfect substitutes Agricultural technology: Y A = L A Manufacturing technology: l i = α + βx i (Increasing returns to scale) Free entry

Closed economy Introduction Market-clearing conditions: x i = Lc i L A = LC A N L = (α + βx i ) + L A i=1 Sectoral consumptions: { maxca,c M C µ M C 1 µ s.t. A P A C A + P M C M PC P M C M = µpc = µw P A C A = (1 µ)pc = (1 µ)w P = P1 µ A P µ M (1 µ) 1 µ µ µ

Closed economy (2) Optimal consumption on each variety: 8 < PN σ 1 : maxc i C M = i=1 c σ i P s.t. N i=1 p i c i P M C M pi σ c i = P M " NX P M = i=1 pi C M = P # 1 σ 1 p 1 σ i σ σ 1 σ µpc P M = pi σ µe Large country in terms of aggregate demand consume more of each variety The demand for a variety that is relatively expensive is lower than the demand for cheaper varieties but consumption is still positive (consequence of the preference for diversity) A higher number of varieties reduces the demand for each variety (market-crowding effect) work through the price index Remark: The same demand function can be obtained from a population of heterogeneous consumers buying a single variety P P M

Closed economy (3) Optimal price in agriculture: P A = w = 1 Optimal prices in manufacturing: { πi = p i c i L w(α + βlc i ) ( ) σ s.t. c i = pi P M w P M Mill-pricing: p i = σ σ 1 β

Closed economy (4) Free entry: π i = p i x i (α + βx i ) = 0 x i = α (σ 1) β There is a unique level of sales that allows the typical firm to just break even, ie to earn a level of operating profit sufficient to cover fixed costs. Regardless of the total number of firms, they all have the same size Full-employment: L = NX i=1 N = µl ασ Larger markets benefit from higher diversity (α + βx i ) + L A As long as the fixed cost is strictly positive, the number of firms and varieties is finite.

Costly trade Introduction Trade increases the diversity of varieties available for consumption: U = NX i=1 c σ 1 σ i + XN i =1! µσ c σ 1 σ 1 σ i C 1 µ A, σ > 1 Positive welfare effect Note that this assumes that the varieties produced in the domestic and foreign markets enter symmetrically in the composite good (same elasticity of substitution) Trade is perfectly free in the homogeneous good sector Law of one price P A = P A Equal wages: w = w Iceberg trade costs τ in the manufacturing sector

Costly trade (2) Introduction Mill-pricing and full pass-through: Optimal prices: max pi,p i [p i Lc i + p i L c i β(lc i + τl c i ) α] s.t. c i = ( pi c i = ) σ w P M P ( ) M p σ i w PM PM p i = p i = σ σ 1 β σ σ 1 βτ = τp i At the same mill price, the consumption of an imported variety is lower by a factor of τ σ than the consumption of a domestic variety because the delivered price is higher explains why firms seek to set up close to their consumers

Costly trade (3) Introduction Price indices: P M P M [ N/N + τ 1 σ = N/N τ 1 σ + 1 ] 1 1 σ The relative price of manufacturing goods is a decreasing function of the relative number of firms located in the market. Individual production: x i = c i L + τci L ( ) σ ( ) σ pi wl τpi w L = + τ P M P M Production is the sum of local demands, weighted by a spatial discount factor φ = τ 1 σ P M P M

Costly trade (4) Introduction Spatial equilibrium equalizing profits: p i c i L + τp i c i L w(α + βc i L + τβc i L ) = p i c i L + τp i c i L w (α + βc i L + τβc i L) with s n = N N+N and s L = L L+L Home Market Effect: s n = s L τ 1 σ (1 s L ) 1 τ 1 σ ds n = 1 + τ 1 σ ds L 1 τ 1 σ > 1 An increase in the relative size of the domestic market more than proportionally increases the relative share of firms located here.

Costly trade (5) Introduction Note that when wages are endogenous as in Krugman (1980) (no agricultural sector or sector-specific labor), the relative wage is sensitive to the relative size of countries Home Market Effect on wages: Large countries have relatively higher wages The size differential is offset by a wage differential which explains that, in general, agglomeration is not total. Consequence of the HME: In a world of IRS, countries will tend to export those kinds of products for which they have relatively large domestic demand. Benefit of market integration as a way to increase the market potential

Introduction Newton s theory of gravitation: Two bodies are attracted to each other in proportion of their mass and in inverse proportion to the square of the distance separating them In economics, countries or regions are bodies subject to push and pull forces the intensity of which depends on their sizes and the distances between them Economic activity aggregates firms and households in a limited number of human settlements Application to migrations (Ravenstein, 1885), international trade (Tinbergen, 1962), capital flows (Portes and Rey, 2005), FDI (Di Maurao, 2000), knowledge flows, etc.

The empirical gravity model Describe bilateral trade flows between two countries r and s: X rs = G Y r α Ys β drs δ with G, α, β and δ parameters to be estimated, Y s and Y r the countries mass approximated by their GDP, d rs distance between countries, proxy for trade costs Log-linearizing this equation gives a testable equation: ln X rs = ln G + α ln Y r + β ln Y s δ ln d rs + ε rs with ε rs a residual term that controls for measurement errors

The empirical gravity model (2) Highly popular model because of the quality of its empirical fit Disdier and Head (2008) conduct a meta-analysis over 78 articles estimating a gravity equation Results The (negative) impact of distance on bilateral trade flows tended to decrease slightly between 1870 and 1950 but started to increase again after 1950 Impact of distance more pronounced in developing countries (inferior quality of their transportation infrastructure?) The mean distance elasticity is 0.89 Doubling distance typically divides trade flows by a factor close to two. Strong heterogeneity across sectors (distance matters more for construction materials than for other goods, surprisingly, distance still matters for services) Distance proxies transport costs but also informational costs, time costs (impact of time difference)

The empirical gravity model (3) Figure: France s exports/imports in 2000 France s exports in 2000 500 1000 2000 5000 10000 20000 Distance in KM (log scale) Exports/ Partner GDP (%,log scale) 0.01 0.1 1 10 Slope= 0.65 EU Euro Francophone Colony other France s imports in 2000 500 1000 2000 5000 10000 20000 Distance in KM (log scale) Imports/Partner GDP (%,log scale) 0.01 0.1 1 10 Slope= 0.86 EU Euro Francophone Colony other

Microfoundations Introduction New Trade models provide the gravity equation with some theoretical microfoundations. They also underline some limits to the standard gravity estimation. Estimated equation derived from a standard multi-country new trade model with: R countries/regions (i = 1...R) Manufacturing sector producing under IRS (CT i (q) = w i a i (q + F )), differentiated varieties that are imperfect substitutes (σ > 1) Bilateral iceberg trade costs τ ij 1 Preferences: U j = " R X i=1 Zni x ij (z) σ 1 σ dz # σ σ 1 = " R X i=1 # σ σ 1 n i x σ 1 σ ij

Microfoundations (2) Optimal demand for each variety: with: ( ) σ pij (z) E j x ij (z) = [ R P j = p ij (z) 1 σ dz n i i=1 P j ] 1 1 σ = P j [ R i=1 n i p 1 σ ij ] 1 1 σ Optimal prices: Mill-pricing p ij (z) = σ σ 1 w ia i τ ij p i τ ij

Microfoundations (3) Profitability condition: R p i j=1 τ ijx ij (z) w i a i F σ R ( ) σ σ τ 1 σ ij P σ 1 j E j σ 1 w ia i (σ 1)F j=1 maximum value of w i as a function of the sum of distance weighted market capacities, called market access of country i by Redding & Venables. Equilibrium number of firms: Y i = n i p i ȳ with ȳ = (σ 1)F Y i n i = p i (σ 1)F

Microfoundations (4) Real bilateral trade flows: n i x ij = n i ( τij p i P j ) σ E j P j = Real nominal (CIF) trade flows: n i p ij x ij = n i p 1 σ i τ 1 σ ij E j P σ 1 j = Y i (σ 1)F p σ 1 i Y i (σ 1)F p σ i τ σ ij E j P σ 1 j τ 1 σ ij E j P σ 1 j with: P j = [ R i=1 n i (p i τ ij ) 1 σ ] 1 1 σ

Microfoundations (5) Gravity-like prediction with E j and Y i proportional to GDPs ( α = β = 1) and τ ij correlated with distance (δ = σ 1) Limit: the new trade model yields a gravity equation that involves price terms Instead of GDPs one should introduce the importer s market capacity and the exporter s supply capacity the term P σ 1 j captures general-equilibrium effects associated with third-country interactions: An increase in country j s access to suppliers reduces its price index, which increases real aggregate demand

Empirical implementation ln Trade ij = ln ( n i p 1 σ ) ( ) i + ln τ 1 σ ij + ln E j P σ 1 j with Trade ij value of the bilateral trade flow, (n i p 1 σ i ) country i s supplier capacity, τ 1 σ ij trade frictions (called freeness of trade by Baldwin et al.), (E j P σ 1 j ) country j s market capacity. Measuring trade costs: ln τ ij = δ ln d ij βcont ij λlang ij γtradeag ij +... Natural barriers (distance, mountains, access to the sea, etc.) Institutional barriers (Trade policy measures, environmental/phytosanitary measures, exchange rate costs, etc.) Information costs and cultural differences (language, historical links, etc.)

Empirical implementation The first generation of estimates neglects price effects and uses GDPs to proxy market capacity and supplier access: ln Trade ij = ln GDP i + (1 σ) ln τ ij + ln GDP j Another strategy consists in estimating a fixed-effect model: ln Trade ij = FE i + (1 σ) ln τ ij + FE j n ˆ i p 1 σ i = exp(fe i ) E ˆ j P σ 1 j = exp(fe j ) When internal trade flows are available, one can get rid of market capacities: with p i p j ln Trade ij Trade jj obtained from relative wages. = ln Y i Y j + (1 σ) ln τ ij τ jj σ ln p i p j

Old fashion Introduction (1) (2) (3) (4) ln gdp, origin 0.780 a 0.783 a 0.775 a (587.29) (588.86) (571.04) ln gdp, dest 0.672 a 0.673 a 0.667 a (534.03) (534.31) (515.73) ln distance -1.061 a -1.064 a -0.977 a - 0.920 a (-304.58) (-304.92) (-260.56) (-234.47) ln gdp cap, origin 0.764 a (413.58) ln gdp cap, dest 0.626 a (340.79) ln pop, dest 0.713 a (441.59) ln pop, origin 0.803 a (469.75) Contiguity 0.552 a 0.526 a (31.64) (30.20) Common language 0.367 a 0.343 a (46.29) (43.05) Colonial relationship 1.661 a 1.699 a (91.04) (93.24) Regional trade agreement 0.880 a (46.40) Currency Unions 0.619 a (16.20) Gatt/WTO members -0.015 a (-2.59) Constant -3.911 a -3.561 a -4.789 a -5.166 a (-118.95) (-103.57) (-133.58) (-140.82) Observations 529,387 526,753 529,387 529,387 R 2 0.524 0.526 0.536 0.539 t statistics in parentheses c p<0.1, b p<0.05, a p<0.01

Fixed effects Introduction Figure: Impact of distance on trade, 1870-2001 (source: Combes et al., 2007) 5.1. The Gravity Model 111 1.5 Inverse of distance coefficient 1.0 0.5 0.0 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 Figure 5.1. The impact of distance on trade, 1870 2001. The importance of geography in the determination of international trade flows has increased over time. Following our discussion above, distance is the most obvious candidate to take into account. Two additional variables are introduced: cont rs and

Fixed effects (2) Introduction Figure: Impact of colonial links on trade, 1960-2001 (source: Head and Mayer, 2007) FE estimation of colonial link coefficient colonial linkage coefficient 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.8 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000

Fixed effects (3) Introduction Figure: Impact of common language on trade, 1960-2001 (source: Head and Mayer, 2007) FE estimation of common language coefficient common language coefficient.3.4.5.6.7 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 Increases over time More complex products?

Limits Introduction Endogeneity concerns: i) an unobservable shock to a country s trade flows must have an impact on its income the variables related to the sizes of the countries are likely to be correlated with the error term ii) relative prices are simultaneously determined with relative trade flows iii) endogeneity in trade agreements: countries choose to sign a trade agreement because they expect trade benefits Problem of zero trade flows that are not compatible with the New trade model ( New new trade models) Tobit or Poisson econometric models