Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Similar documents
Consumption and Savings (Continued)

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

Problem set 1 ECON 4330

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Consumption-Savings Decisions and Credit Markets

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

EC 324: Macroeconomics (Advanced)

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 2

Consumption and Savings

Economics 101. Lecture 8 - Intertemporal Choice and Uncertainty

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

ECON385: A note on the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). In this note, we will try to understand the permanent income hypothesis (PIH).

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Macroeconomics and finance

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply

Advanced Macroeconomics Tutorial #2: Solutions

Equilibrium with Production and Labor Supply

III: Labor Supply in Two Periods

Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

Dynamic AD and Dynamic AS

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 3 : The Ramsey Growth Model

Micro-foundations: Consumption. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Slides III - Complete Markets

Topic 2: Consumption

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Lecture 4A The Decentralized Economy I

GRA 6639 Topics in Macroeconomics

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Lecture 12 Ricardian Equivalence Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

Lecture 10: Two-Period Model

Problem 1 / 20 Problem 2 / 30 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6

Advanced (International) Macroeconomics

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing

1 Dynamic programming

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

LECTURE 1 : THE INFINITE HORIZON REPRESENTATIVE AGENT. In the IS-LM model consumption is assumed to be a

14.05 Lecture Notes. Labor Supply

Notes for Econ202A: Consumption

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

Problem set 2. Filip Rozsypal November 23, 2011

004: Macroeconomic Theory

The Real Business Cycle Model

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

14.05: SECTION HANDOUT #4 CONSUMPTION (AND SAVINGS) Fall 2005

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Macroeconomics: Fluctuations and Growth

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

INDIVIDUAL CONSUMPTION and SAVINGS DECISIONS

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

Midterm 2 Review. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics Professor Sims University of Notre Dame, Spring 2018

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

Professor Dr. Holger Strulik Open Economy Macro 1 / 34

GOVERNMENT AND FISCAL POLICY IN JUNE 16, 2010 THE CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL (CONTINUED) ADYNAMIC MODEL OF THE GOVERNMENT

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Money in OLG Models. Econ602, Spring The central question of monetary economics: Why and when is money valued in equilibrium?

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply

Solving The Perfect Foresight CRRA Consumption Model

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. Fiscal Policy. Ramsey Taxation. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Lecture 5: to Consumption & Asset Choice

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Kiyotaki and Moore [1997]

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Economics 244: Macro Modeling Dynamic Fiscal Policy

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

The Representative Household Model

Incentives and economic growth

Chapter 4. Consumption and Saving. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 6a

International Macroeconomics

Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods

1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints

Intermediate Macroeconomics: Consumption

Transcription:

Econ 20200 - Elements of Economics Analysis 3 (Honors Macroeconomics) Lecturer: Chanont (Big) Banternghansa TA: Jonathan J. Adams Spring 2013 Introduction Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings This version: May 4, 2013 The purpose of this section is to study how household allocate resources over time, ie how they make the decision about how much to consume today, vs how much to save/borrow and consume tomorrow. We start with a simple 2-period endowment economy, and move to the infinite horizon problem. A 2-period endowment economy We study a partial equilibrium model, in a 2-period endowment economy: Setup The economy is populated by a representative household that lives for 2 periods: 1 and 2. Endowment: The household is endowed with: y 1 units of good at period 1. y 2 units of good at period 2. Preferences: The household has preferences over consumption at dates 1 and 2, represented by the following utility function: where u > 0, u < 0, 0 < β < 1. U(c 1, c 2 ) = u(c 1 ) + βu(c 2 ) In particular, utility is separable across the two periods and the period utility function (small u) is increasing and concave. β : discount factor. A low β means that the household discounts (cares less) a lot the utility it gets from consuming in the second period, and is impatient. 1

A high β characterizes a patient household because he cares more about future consumption. Perfect Credit Market The household can borrow and/or lend between period 1 and 2, at an interest rate r. The interest rate r is given exogenously (partial equilibrium). The household enters period 1 with no debts or assets. It exits on period 2. We denote the amount of savings between 1 and 2 by s, such that { s > 0 the household saves. s < 0 the househld borrows. Period budget constraints, maximization program, and Euler equation. The period budget constraints are: The maximization program is: The Lagrangian is c 1 + s = y 1 at period 1 c 2 = y 2 + (1 + r)s at period 2 max c1,c 2,s u(c 1 ) + βu(c 2 ) s.t. c 1 + s = y 1 [λ 1 ] c 2 = y 2 + (1 + r)s [λ 2 ] L = u(c 1 ) + βu(c 2 ) + λ 1 (y 1 c 1 s) + λ 2 (y 2 + (1 + r)s c 2 ) The first order conditions are Dividing [c 1 ] by [c 2 ] we get [c 1 ] u (c 1 ) = λ 1 [c 2 ] βu (c 2 ) = λ 2 [s] λ 1 + λ 2 (1 + r) = 0 u (c 1 ) βu (c 2 ) = λ 1 λ 2 Using the FOC on [s] to get the ratio of multipliers, we have: u (c 1 ) βu (c 2 ) = 1 + r 2

This is known as the Euler equation (EE). It gives an expression for the marginal rate of substitution between consumption at period 1 and consumption at period 2. It summarizes the optimal intertemporal choice for the household. The equilibrium allocation (c 1, c 2, s ) is given by the euler equation and the 2 budget constraints: u (c 1 ) βu (c 2 ) = 1 + r c 1 + s = y 1 c 2 = y 2 + (1 + r)s Intertemporal Budget Constraint, Maximization program and Euler Equation Let us start with the two period budget constraints: { c1 + s = y 1 c 2 = y 2 + (1 + r)s Dividing the second budget constraint by(1 + r) and summing we have c 1 + s + c 2 1 + r = y 1 + y 2 (1 + r)s + 1 + r 1 + r c 1 + c 2 1 + r = y 1 + y 2 1 + r This is the intertemporal budget constraint. It states that the present value of all consumption flows should be equal to the present value of all income flows. Future income and consumption flows of period 2 are discounted by (1 + r), the interest rate. Now, the maximization program is The Lagrangian is { maxc1,c 2 u(c 1 ) + βu(c 2 ) s.t. c 1 + c 2 = y 1 + y 2 [λ] L = u(c 1 ) + βu(c 2 ) + λ The first order conditions are ( y 1 + y 2 1 + r c 1 c ) 2 1 + r [c 1 ] u (c 1 ) = λ [c 2 ] βu (c 2 ) = λ 1 3

Dividing [c 1 ] by [c 2 ], we have u (c 1 ) βu (c 2 ) = 1 + r Note that this is the same Euler equation as before. In other words, one can collapse the set of time constraint into one constraint and get the same optimal allocation. The equilibrium allocation is given by Savings are s = y 1 c 1 = c 2 y 2. Graphically: u (c 1 ) βu (c 2 ) c 1 + c 2 = y 1 + y 2 = 1 + r The budget constraint is given by the following equation: c 2 = [(1 + r)y 1 + y 2 ] (1 + r)c 1 For a given utility level ū, the indifference curves are given by the following equation (ū ) c 2 = u 1 u(c1 ) β The equilibrium is the point on the intertemporal budget constraint, where the marginal rate of substitution between period 1 and 2 is equal to the slope of the budget constraint. 4

Net Savers and Net borrowers Net savers: The agent is a net saver if s > 0 or c 1 < y 1. This is more likely if y 1 is large (compared to y 2 ). r is large. β is large. Net Borrowers: The agent is a net borrower if s < 0 or c 1 > y 1. This is more likely if y 1 is low (compared to y 2 ). 5

r is low. β is low. Comparative statics: Increase in y 1 We consider a temporary increase in endowment (y 1 > y 1). This has three effects on the equilibrium allocation: increase in c 1 increase in c 2 increase in s (increase in savings or decrease in borrowings) More precisely, we have a positive income shock, which would translate into an increase in c 1, and/or an increase in c 2. In fact, both have to increase at the same time. Indeed, if only c 1 or c 2 increased, the marginal rate of substitution between period 1 and 2 would be modified and the euler equation u (c 1 ) βu (c 2 ) = (1 + r) would be violated. In other words, the pure income shock translates into an increase in consumption in both periods. Consumption at period 1 and at period 2 are both normal goods. The agent exhibits a preference for consumption smoothing. 6

Comparative statics: Increase in y 2 We consider a temporary increase in endowment (y 2 > y 2). This has three effects on the equilibrium allocation: increase in c 1 increase in c 2 decrease in s (decrease in savings or increase in borrowings) Again we observe consumption smoothing. What matters for consumption today is the permanent income: an increase in future revenues results in higher consumption today. This highlights the importance of expectations in the economy. 7

Comparative statics: Increase in β An increase in β means that agent becomes more patient. This has three effects on the equilibrium allocation: decrease in c 1 increase in c 2 increase in s (increase in savings or decrease in borrowings) The increase in β decreases the marginal rate of substitution for any given (c 1, c 2 ) pair. Hence, for the Euler equation to be satisfied, we need c 1 to decrease (u (c 1 ) to increase) and c 2 to increase (u (c 2 ) to decrease), since the budget constraint is unchanged. 8

Comparative statics: Increase in r An increase in r has two effects. It makes the price of the good at period 2 to fall, in the sense that the technology that transforms goods at period 1 into goods at period 2 becomes more productive substitution. It makes total income (y 1 + y 2 fall in today s price, but rise (y 1(1 + r) + y 2 ) in tomorrow s price income effect. In all, we have a substitution and an income effect that makes the effects on c 1 and c 2 difficult to predict. In fact, it is useful to distinguish between borrowers and lenders. Net savers: c 1 c 2 Substitution Effect Income Effect Total? Lenders (think of an active worker, well endowed in current income y 1, but poorly endowed in future income y 2 (ie retirement)). The lenders face two phenomenon Substitution: c 2 becomes cheaper, so they substitute away from c 1 to c 2. Income: Since net lenders have s > 0, the increase in r increases the value of his future income (because y 1 is more efficiently transferred to period 2), which means there s a positive income effect on both c 1 and c 2. 9

Ambiguous effect on c 1, c 2 increases for sure. Net borrowers: c 1 c 2 Substitution Effect Income Effect Total? Borrowers (think of a poor University of Chicago student, well endowed in future income y 2, but poorly endowed in current income y 1 ). Substitution: c 2 becomes cheaper, so they substitute away from c 1 to c 2. Income: Since net borrowers have s < 0, the increase in r decreases the value of 10

his future income (he needs to pay a higher debt), which means there s a negative income effect on both c 1 and c 2. Ambiguous effect on c 2, c 1 decreases for sure. Zero net-supply of bonds, determination of the interest rate We now consider an economy where it is not possible for the household to save or borrow because bonds/savings instruments come in zero net supply. We have s = 0 c 1 = y 1 c 2 = y 2 In such an economy, the interest rate would be r = u ( c 1 ) βu ( c 2 ) 1 = u (y 1 ) βu (y 2 ) 1 In other words, the interest rate adjusts so it is equal to the marginal rate of substitution between consumption at period and period 2, evaluated at (y 1, y 2 ). In particular, the interest rate in equilibrium is: Decreasing in β: if agents are more patient, they are more willing to save, and we need the interest rate to decrease to bring net savings back to zero. Decreasing in y 1 : if agents have more endowments today, they are willing to smooth consumption and save part of this increase, and we need the interest rate to decrease to bring net savings back to zero. 11

increasing in y 2 : if agents anticipate more endowment tomorrow, they are willing to go into debt to increase consumption today, and we need the interest rate to increase to bring net savings back to zero. In the event of a recession (fall in y 2 ) and assuming the supply of bonds is fixed, the interest rate should fall. This is quite a good prediction: periods where the interest rate is low or negative are often predictive of recessions. The infinite-horizon endowment economy Setup The economy is populated by a representative household that lives forever (from t = 0 to ) Endowments ( The household is endowed with a flow of endowments: {y t } t=0. We ) y assume that t t=0 () converges to Ȳ. t Preferences: The household has preferences over consumption at each date {c t } t=0, represented by the following utility function: where u > 0, u < 0, and 0 < β < 1. U ({y t } t=0 ) = β t u(c t ) Perfect Credit Market The household can borrow and/or lend between each period t and t + 1, at a constant rate r, taken as exogenous. t=0 We denote the amount of savings between t and t + 1 by s t such that s t > 0 means household saves at t and s t < 0 means household borrows at t. The household enters period 0 with no debt or assets, so that using our convention, s 1 = 0. The household s savings, in present value, are asymptotically 0: lim t This is called the transversality condition. s t+1 (1 + r) t+1 = 0 12

Period budget constraints, maximization program, and Euler equation: The budget constraint at period t is c t + s t = y t + (1 + r)s t 1 t The constraint holds at each date t. The maximization program is max ct,st t=0 βt u(c t ) s.t. c t + s t = y t + (1 + r)s t 1 t s 1 = 0 s lim t+1 t () t+1 = 0 Denoting λ t the multiplier in front of the budget constraint at date t, the Lagrangian writes: L = β t u(c t ) + λ t (y t + (1 + r)s t 1 c t s t ) t=0 t=0 The first order conditions are, for each t: [c t ] β t u (c 1 ) = λ 1 [s t ] λ t + λ t+1 (1 + r) = 0 Now, taking the FOC of [c t ] and dividing by the FOC of [c t+1 ], we have: β t u (c t ) β t+1 u (c t+1 ) = λ t λ t+1 Using the FOC of [s t ] for the ratio of multipliers, we get β t u (c t ) β t+1 u (c t+1 ) = 1 + r u (c t ) βu (c t+1 ) = 1 + r Again this is the euler equation, giving an expression for the marginal rate of substitution between consumption at date t and consumption at date t and consumption at date t + 1. 13

The equilibrium allocation {c t, s t } is given by the euler equation, the budget constraints, and the transversality condition: u (c t) βu (c t+1 ) c t + s t s 1 = 0 s lim t+1 t () t+1 = 0 = 1 + r = y t + (1 + r)s t 1 Before getting to the resuts, let us derive the intertemporal budget constraint. Intertemporal budget constraint, maximization program and euler equation: Recipe Divide the budget constraint at date t by (1 + r) t. Sum from date 0 to date t + 1 Let t + 1 tend to infinity, and use the transversality condition. This steps are shown below: Divide by (1 + r) t. Sum date 0 c 0 + s 0 = y 0 + (1 + r)s 1 /(1 + r) 0 date 1 c 1 + s 1 = y 1 + (1 + r)s 0 /(1 + r) 1 date 2 c 2 + s 2 = y 2 + (1 + r)s 1 /(1 + r) 2.. date t 1 c t 1 + s t 1 = y t 1 + (1 + r)s t 2 /(1 + r) t 1 date t c t + s t = y t + (1 + r)s t 1 /(1 + r) t date t + 1 c t+1 + s t+1 = y t+1 + (1 + r)s t /(1 + r) t+1 c 0 () 0 + c 1 () 1 + c 2 () 2 +... + + s 0 () 0 + s 1 () 1 + s 2 = y 0 () 0 + y 1 () 1 + y 2 () 2 +... + +... + () 2 + ()s 1 + ()s 0 + ()s 1 () 0 () 1 () 2 ( t+1 ) c i (1 + r) i i=0 + c t 1 + () t 1 s t 1 + () t 1 y t 1 + () t 1 s t+1 (1 + r) t+1 = ct () + c t t+1 () t+1 +... + ()s t 2 () t 1 ( t+1 i=0 st () + s t t+1 () t+1 yt () t + y t+1 () t+1 y i (1 + r) i + ()s t 1 () t ) + (1 + r)s 1 + ()st () t+1 14

Let t + 1 Using lim t s t+1 () t+1 i=0 = 0, we get c i (1 + r) i = y i (1 + r) i = ȳ i=0 This is the intertemporal budget constraint (IBC). It states that the present value of all consumption flows should be equal to the present value of all income flows. Now we can replace the sequence of period budget constraint by the IBC and write the maximization program: max {ct} s.t. t=0 βt u(c t ) t=0 c t () t = ȳ The Lagrangian is L = ( ) β t c t u(c t ) + λ ȳ (1 + r) t t=0 t=0 The first order condition c t is: Dividing by [c t ] by [c t+1 ] we get β t u 1 (c t ) = λ (1 + r) t β t u (c t ) β t+1 u (c t+1 ) = λ/(1 + r)t λ/(1 + r) t+1 u (c t ) βu = (1 + r) t (c t+1 ) The equilibrium allocation is given by {c t } t=0 such that u (c t ) βu (c t+1 ) = (1 + r) t t=0 c t () t = ȳ Permanent Income Note that the solution to the system of equations described above does not depend on the particular sequence of endowments. {y t } t=0, but only on the present value of all the endowment flows ȳ, known as the permanent income. 15

Patience and interest-rate If the agent is patient, β > 1, then the euler equation implies u (c t ) = β(1 + r)u (c t+1 ) u (c t ) > u (c t+1 ) c t < c t+1 A patient household will reduce consumption in earlier dates, save and take advantage of interest payments to increase its consumption in later periods, so that {c t } is increasing in t. If the agent is impatient, β < 1, then the euler equation implies u (c t ) = β(1 + r)u (c t+1 ) u (c t ) < u (c t+1 ) c t > c t+1 An impatient household will increase consumption in earlier dates, go into debt (or save less) and reduce consumption in later periods, so that {c t } is decreasing in t. If β = 1 then u (c t ) = β(1 + r)u (c t+1 ) u (c t ) = u (c t+1 ) c t = c t+1 = c Consumption is constant over time. Th household s impatience exactly cancels with the incentive to invest. In fact, we can solve for c. Using the IBC, we have c t t=0 () t c t=0 () c 1 1 1 c r = ȳ = ȳ = ȳ = ȳ c = r ȳ 16

CRRA (constant relative risk aversion) utility Definition We consider the following utility function c σ 1 σ u(c) = σ 1 for σ > 0, σ 1 σ ln c for σ = 1 σ: intertemporal elasticity of substitution. : coefficient of relative risk aversion. 1 σ We have u (c) = c σ 1 σ 1 = c 1 σ > 0 u (c) = 1 σ c 1 σ 1 = 1 σ c 1 σ σ < 0 The name of the utility function comes from the fact that the coefficient of relative aversion (CRRA) is constant. CRRA = u (c)c u (c) CRRA = Euler equation The euler equation is 1 σ c 1/σ 1 c c 1/σ CRRA = 1 σ u (c t) u (c t+1 ) = β(1 + r) 1 c σ t 1 c σ t+1 c t c t+1 c t+1 c t = β(1 + r) = [β(1 + r)] σ = [β(1 + r)] σ If σ 0 c t+1 = [β(1 + r)] σ 1 β(1 + r) c t When the intertemporal elasticity of substitution is low, consumption flows at different dates are poorly substitutable, and the household will tend to smooth consumption perfctly, no matter what the interest rate and the discount factor are. 17

If σ is large c t+1 c t = [β(1 + r)] σ { σ if β > 1 0 if β < 1 When the intertemporal elasticity of substitution is high: If the household is patient (β > 1 later periods. If the household is impatient (β < 1 the very short run and go into debt. ), it will postpone its consumption to ), it will consume all its endowment in When σ is high, the household is less willing to smooth consumption. Discussion about the permanent income hypothesis and borrowing constrants Our model predicts that consumption only depends on the present value of income flows ȳ and not the particular shape of endowment flows {y t }. There is definitely some empirical counterparts to this prediction: At the aggregate level, consumption is smoother than income/gdp at the individual level, there are life-cycle patterns. 18