TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

Similar documents
FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

The Black-Scholes Equation

TEACHING NOTE 98-01: CLOSED-FORM AMERICAN CALL OPTION PRICING: ROLL-GESKE-WHALEY

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

The Black-Scholes Model

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Completeness and Hedging. Tomas Björk

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends.

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

Extensions to the Black Scholes Model

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Homework Assignments

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher)

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

Valuing Put Options with Put-Call Parity S + P C = [X/(1+r f ) t ] + [D P /(1+r f ) t ] CFA Examination DERIVATIVES OPTIONS Page 1 of 6

Hedging. MATH 472 Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan

Financial Derivatives Section 5

2 f. f t S 2. Delta measures the sensitivityof the portfolio value to changes in the price of the underlying

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

Option Pricing. Simple Arbitrage Relations. Payoffs to Call and Put Options. Black-Scholes Model. Put-Call Parity. Implied Volatility

Lecture 9: Practicalities in Using Black-Scholes. Sunday, September 23, 12

American options and early exercise

Asset-or-nothing digitals

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Chapter 14. Exotic Options: I. Question Question Question Question The geometric averages for stocks will always be lower.

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Chapter 14 Exotic Options: I

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 2 Solutions

MATH 425 EXERCISES G. BERKOLAIKO

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Math 181 Lecture 15 Hedging and the Greeks (Chap. 14, Hull)

Chapter 9 - Mechanics of Options Markets

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

European call option with inflation-linked strike

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

Notes for Lecture 5 (February 28)

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

ON AN IMPLEMENTATION OF BLACK SCHOLES MODEL FOR ESTIMATION OF CALL- AND PUT-OPTION VIA PROGRAMMING ENVIRONMENT MATHEMATICA

The Black-Scholes Model

THE BLACK-SCHOLES FORMULA AND THE GREEK PARAMETERS FOR A NONLINEAR BLACK-SCHOLES EQUATION

Greek Maxima 1 by Michael B. Miller

Deriving and Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

The Black-Scholes Model

PAijpam.eu ANALYTIC SOLUTION OF A NONLINEAR BLACK-SCHOLES EQUATION

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

The Black-Scholes Model

Chapter 17. Options and Corporate Finance. Key Concepts and Skills

CHAPTER 10 OPTION PRICING - II. Derivatives and Risk Management By Rajiv Srivastava. Copyright Oxford University Press

HIGHER ORDER BINARY OPTIONS AND MULTIPLE-EXPIRY EXOTICS

OPTIONS & GREEKS. Study notes. An option results in the right (but not the obligation) to buy or sell an asset, at a predetermined

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee

Option Pricing in Continuous-Time: The Black Scholes Merton Theory and Its Extensions

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

Derivation and Comparative Statics of the Black-Scholes Call and Put Option Pricing Formulas

Simulation Analysis of Option Buying

Barrier options. In options only come into being if S t reaches B for some 0 t T, at which point they become an ordinary option.

1 Interest Based Instruments

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATHEMATICAL METHODS IN PRICING RAINBOW OPTIONS. Blakeley Barton McShane. A Thesis in Mathematics

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

[AN INTRODUCTION TO THE BLACK-SCHOLES PDE MODEL]

MFE/3F Questions Answer Key

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

- 1 - **** d(lns) = (µ (1/2)σ 2 )dt + σdw t

Lecture 18. More on option pricing. Lecture 18 1 / 21

MFE/3F Questions Answer Key

Option pricing. School of Business C-thesis in Economics, 10p Course code: EN0270 Supervisor: Johan Lindén

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 8 Option Pricing in Continuous Time

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice

Financial Risk Management

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

The Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Homework Set 6 Solutions

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Transcription:

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING Version date: June 3, 017 C:\CLASSES\TEACHING NOTES\TN98-04.WPD The exchange option, first developed by Margrabe (1978), has proven to be an extremely powerful generalization of the Black-Scholes model. The intuitive insights in the derivation of the exchange option model are very useful in other applications in option pricing. Let us consider a European option in which at expiration, the holder can exchange one unit of asset and receive one unit of asset 1. Let c(s1,s) denote the price of this call option. Its payoff at expiration is ct(s1,s) = Max(0,S1 - S). In this option, asset plays the role of the exercise price, but asset is stochastic. Alternatively, one can view this option as a put in which asset can be exchanged for asset 1 if asset has lower value. In that context, option 1 plays the role of the exercise price. Let this option price be denoted as p(s,s1) and payoff at expiration be pt(s,s1) = Max(0,S1 - S). We first establish some boundary conditions on the price of this option. Establishing a Lower Bound and Put-Call Parity We begin by constructing a lower bound, which will also show the relationship between the exchange option price and the spread between the prices of the two underlying assets. At time t, construct portfolio A by purchasing one exchange option. Then construct portfolio B by purchasing one unit of asset 1 and selling short one unit of asset. The payoffs are shown below. D. M. Chance, TN98-04 1

Value at Expiration Instrument Current Value S1T ST S1T > ST Portfolio A Exchange option c(s1,s) 0 S1T - ST Portfolio B Long asset 1 S1t S1T S1T Short asset -St -ST -ST Total S1t - St S1T - ST S1T - ST It is clear that portfolio A dominates portfolio B so the value of A at time t must be no less than the value of B at time t. Since the exchange call cannot be worth less than zero, we can say that its minimum value is given as c( S, S ) Max( S, S ). 1 1 Note that if the exchange call were an American option, early exercise would generate only S1 - S so it would never be more valuable to exercise it early. Thus, the American exchange call would be worth the same as the European exchange call. Now we develop a type of put-call parity. Let Portfolio A consist of the same exchange call and a short put to exchange asset for asset 1. Let Portfolio B be the same as above, a long position in asset 1 and a short position in asset. D. M. Chance, TN98-04

Value at Expiration Instrument Current Value S1T ST S1T > ST Portfolio A Long exch. call to swap asset for asset 1 Short exch. put to swap asset 1 for asset c(s1,s) 0 S1T - ST p(s1,s) -(ST - S1T) 0 Total c(s1,s) - p(s1,s) S1T - ST S1T - ST Portfolio B Long asset 1 S1 S1T S1T Short asset -S -ST -ST Total S1 - S S1T - ST S1T - ST Here portfolios A and B produce equivalent payoffs; thus, their initial values must be the same. Consequently, c( S1, S ) - p( S1, S ) = S1 S. The same statement also holds for American exchange options. Note the similarity between put-call parity for exchange options and put-call parity for ordinary options. 1 If we replaced S with Xe -rt) in 1 Note that put-call parity can also be written as c(s1,s) - c(s,s1) = S1 - S. D. M. Chance, TN98-04 3

the above formula, we would have put-call parity for ordinary options. As we shall soon see, there is a most intuitive reason for this substitution. Pricing the Exchange Option Before beginning our derivation of the exchange option pricing model, let us review the mathematical principle of homogeneity, which plays an important role. Consider an unspecified mathematical function f(x1,x,...,xn). The function is said to be homogeneous of degree λ with respect to every variable x if f(ax1,ax,...,axn) = a λ f(x1,x,...,xn) for constant a. For example, consider the function g(x,y,z) = x + 3yz - z, which is homogeneous of degree two with respect to every variable. (Note that a x + 3ayaz - a z = a g(x,y,z).) A function is homogeneous of degree zero with respect to every variable if its value is not altered when multiplying each term by some constant, a. A function can be homogeneous with respect to a limited number of variables. For example, suppose f(ax1,x,..., xn) = a λ f(x1,x,..., xn). Then f(x1,x,..., xn) is said to be homogeneous of degree λ with respect to x1. A function that is homogeneous of degree one is said to be linearly homogeneous. Suppose f(x1,x,..., xn) is linearly homogeneous with respect to x1 and x. This means that f(ax1,ax, x3,...,xn) = a 1 f(x1,x,..., xn). Euler=s Theorem permits us to state that f(x1,x,..., xn) = x1 f( )/ x1 + x f( )/ x. This result will prove useful in deriving the exchange option pricing model. Now let us propose that there are two assets, i = 1,, each following its own lognormal diffusion, ds i = i dt + idzi i S and the correlation between the two Weiner processes driving the asset prices is ρ1. Let c(s1,s) be the value today of the exchange option, which gives the right to tender asset for asset 1 at expiration, T. As noted above, the payoff of this option is ct(s1,s) = Max(0,S1 - S). We consider today time 0 so the time to maturity is T. It is easy to see that this terminal payoff is linearly homogeneous with respect to the two asset values. Since the value of the option today is a simple D. M. Chance, TN98-04 4

discounted expectation of its payoff at expiration, its current value must also be linearly homogeneous. Using Euler s Theorem, we can express the value of the option as c( S1, S) c( S1, S) c( S1, S) - S1- S= 0. S1 S This statement has a natural interpretation: a portfolio consisting of the purchase of one unit of the exchange call and short positions in c/ S1 units of asset 1 and c/ S units of asset would require no initial investment. To avoid profitable arbitrage, such a portfolio must generate an instantaneous return of zero. Now we apply the multivariate version of Itô s Lemma to the value of the call: c( S1, S) c( S1, S) c( S1, S) dc( S1, S ) = d S1+ d S+ dt S1 S t 1 c( S, S ) c( S, S ) c( S, S ) + + + S S S S 1 1 1 1S 1 1 1S 1S S 1 1 Thus, with c(s1,s) - ( c(s1,s)/ S1)S1 - ( c(s1,s)/ S)S = dc - ( c(s1,s)/ S1)dS1 - ( c(s1,s)/ S)dS = 0, substituting Itô s Lemma for dc, we obtain the partial differential equation, ( 1, ) c S S 1 c( S1, S) ( 1, ) ( 1, ) c S S c S S + 1S 1 + 1 1S 1S + S t S 1 S 1 S S = 0 The solution is Taking the discounted expectation is a linear operation, which preserves the linear homogeneity. D. M. Chance, TN98-04 5

c( S, S ) = S N( d ) - S N( d _ 1 1 1 where ln( S1/ S) + ( / ) T 1 1 d =, d = d - T T = + -. 1 1 1 Note that σ is the volatility of a new variable, the proportional change in the log of the ratio S1/S. It is obtained as follows: S 1 Var ln Var ln S1 ln S S Var S Var S S ln ln covlns,ln 1 1. 1 1 1 We can check our solution by taking the partial derivatives and inserting them into the PDE to see if we obtain the above formula, but a simpler and more intuitive check is possible. Since c is linearly homogeneous with respect to the prices of assets 1 and, we can say that ac = c(as1,as) where a is a constant. Define a as 1/S, which gives us (1/S)c(S1,S) = c(s,1) or c(s1,s) = Sc(S,1) where S = S1/S. In effect we have created a new somewhat artificial asset, the ratio of the value of asset 1 to the value of asset. In other words, the exchange call can be expressed as S units of an asset that allows the exchange of one dollar for the value of S1 over S. The latter is an ordinary European call on S with an exercise price of 1. We can, therefore, differentiate the exchange option price by differentiating its equivalent value, Sc(S,1). We need second partials with respect to S1, S, the cross partial of S1 and S, and the first derivative with respect to t. Hence, the model can be expressed as c( S 1, S ) = Sc( S,1) S ( SN( d ) N( d )) 1 where S S / S 1 This is an ordinary Black-Scholes-Merton option on the artificial asset S with strike of 1. The d1 and d variables in this variation are the same as in the first version as shown above. D. M. Chance, TN98-04 6

Now we need to verify the solution to the PDE. First, let us examine the first derivatives with respect to S1 and S, commonly refer to as the option concept of delta. We will make use of the artificial asset S to simplify this process, thereby enabling us to use many of the results from the Black-Scholes-Merton model. To solve the PDE, we need certain partial derivatives. The first partial derivatives with respect to the underlying prices are: c( S1, S) c( S,1) c( S,1) S c( S,1) = ( S c(s, 1 )) S S S 1 S S S S S 1 1 1 c(s, 1) S c(s, 1) S Sc(S, 1) S c(s, 1) S c(s, 1) S S S S S c(s, 1) c(s, 1) S S The second partial derivatives with respect to the asset prices are: c( S 1, S ) c( S 1, S ) c(s, 1) c(s, 1 ) S c( S,1) 1 = S 1 S 1 S 1 S 1 S S S S1 S S c( S 1, S ) c( S 1, S ) c(s, 1) c(s, 1) c(s, 1) = c(s, 1) S S S S S S S S S S c(s, 1) c(s, 1) S c(s, 1) c(s, 1) S S S S S S S S S S S S S S S S c(s, 1) S c(s, 1 ) S c( S,1) S c(s, 1) S c(s, 1) S S S S S S ct( S 1, S ) c( S 1, S ) c( S,1) c(s, 1) S c(s, 1) S = S 1S S S1 S S S S S S We also need the first partial derivative with respect to time: D. M. Chance, TN98-04 7

The PDE above was c( S, S ) (,1) (,1) 1 S c S S cs t t t ( 1, ) c S S 1 c( S1, S) ( 1, ) ( 1, ) c S S c S S + 1S 1 + 1 1S 1S + S t S 1 S 1 S S = 0 Making the appropriate substitutions, we obtain the PDE, (,1) 1 c S c( S,1) 1 c( S,1) S c( S,1) S S 1 1 1 1 1 0 S S S S t S S S S S S c( S,1) 1 c( S,1) c(s, 1) c(s, 1) S 1 SS 1 1 1SS1 SS 1 0 t S S S S c( S1, S) 1 1 c( S1, S) c(s 1,S ) S c(s 1,S ) S S 1 SS 1 1 1SS1 SS1 0 t S S1 S1S S S S c( S1, S) 1 c( S1, S) c(s 1,S ) c(s 1,S ) 1 S1 1 1S1S S 0 t S1 S1S S1S And this is the PDE as obtained above. The first two lines in the equation above show that this partial differential equation is the same as the Black-Scholes-Merton partial differential equation when the interest rate, r, is set to zero, the underlying asset price is S, and the volatility is σ. Consequently, we can say that the exchange option is equivalent to S units of an ordinary European call when the underlying asset is S, the strike is one, the interest rate is zero, and the volatility is σ = σ1 + σ -ρ1σ1σ. The last two lines above verify that this PDE is the same as the one we previously obtained. This result is useful in better understanding not only the exchange option, but also the ordinary European option. The latter can be viewed as an exchange option where the asset exchanged is cash. The exchange option implies a zero interest rate because it can be replicated by D. M. Chance, TN98-04 8

holding asset 1 and shorting asset. The shorting of asset would not have an expected return of r, as it would if it were risk-free. Rather the holder of asset would demand its expected return, α, as compensation. Consequently, the short seller of asset, who is trying to replicate the exchange option, would not have an expected return of -r but rather of -α. In any ordinary European call, the second term in the pricing equation is the present value of the exercise price. In the exchange option, the second term is also the present value of the exercise price. The current price of asset is its present value. Interestingly, in the same issue of The Journal of Finance directly preceding the Margrabe article, there is an article by Stanley Fischer (1978), in which he modeled bonds indexed to inflation. He showed that to price such a bond one needs the formula for an option where the exercise price is stochastic. Such an option is equivalent to an exchange option, and naturally Fisher derives the same formula as Margrabe. The traditional option Greeks are provided in the appendix. References Fischer, S. Call Option Pricing When the Exercise Price is Uncertain and the Valuation of Index Bonds. The Journal of Finance 33 (1978), 169-176. Fu, Q. On the Valuation of an Option to Exchange One Interest Rate for Another. Journal of Banking and Finance 0 (1996), 645-654. Margrabe, W. The Value of an Option to Exchange One Asset for Another. The Journal of Finance 33 (1978), 177-186. Rubinstein, M. One for Another. Risk 4 (July-August, 1991). Appendix: Exchange Option Greeks We obtain the first and second derivatives in symbolic form. The deltas with respect to the two asset prices were obtained previously but not carried out in detail. They are D. M. Chance, TN98-04 9

c( S1, S) c( S,1) c( S,1) S 1 = ( S c(s, 1 )) S S S N( d ) N( d ) S 1 S S S S S The gammas were obtained as 1 1 1 1 1 c(s, 1) S c(s, 1) S Sc(S, 1) S c(s, 1) S c(s, 1) S S S S S c(s, 1) c(s, 1) S c(s, 1 ) SN( d1) S SN( d ) N( d ) SN( d ) N( d ) 1 1 d1 / d1 / c( S1, S) c( S,1) 1 e 1 e = S 1 S S S T S S` T d1 / c( S1, S) c(s, 1) S e = ` S S S S T Therefore, applying what we know from Black-Scholes-Merton, we find that the second derivatives above become the following exchange option gammas: c(, ) c( S,1) 1 S1 S = S 1 S S c(, ) c(s, 1) S S1 S = S S S The partial derivative with respect to the time to expiration is Hence, the theta is The vegas are d1 / d1 / 1 cs 1 S c( S, S ) (,1) S S e S e T T T T d1 / c( S1, S) S1 e t T D. M. Chance, TN98-04 10

1 / ( 1, ) d c S S S1e T 1 1 1 / ( 1, ) d c S S S 1e T 1 And the partial derivative with respect to the correlation is d1 c( S / 1, S) S1e T 1 The risk-free rate does not appear in the equation. Hence, there is no rho. D. M. Chance, TN98-04 11