Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics. The mean-absolute deviation portfolio selection problem with interval-valued returns

Similar documents
Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance

Applications of Linear Programming

Log-Robust Portfolio Management

The Optimization Process: An example of portfolio optimization

Online Appendix: Extensions

SCHOOL OF BUSINESS, ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT. BF360 Operations Research

Quantitative Risk Management

CSCI 1951-G Optimization Methods in Finance Part 00: Course Logistics Introduction to Finance Optimization Problems

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

Multistage risk-averse asset allocation with transaction costs

Essays on Some Combinatorial Optimization Problems with Interval Data

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

Stochastic Programming and Financial Analysis IE447. Midterm Review. Dr. Ted Ralphs

Solving real-life portfolio problem using stochastic programming and Monte-Carlo techniques

Markowitz portfolio theory

Predicting bank performance with financial forecasts: A case of Taiwan commercial banks

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 5: Mean-variance portfolio theory

FINANCIAL OPERATIONS RESEARCH: Mean Absolute Deviation And Portfolio Indexing

A Broader View of the Mean-Variance Optimization Framework

Research Article Portfolio Optimization of Equity Mutual Funds Malaysian Case Study

Chapter 7: Portfolio Theory

Optimal Portfolio Selection Under the Estimation Risk in Mean Return

Maximum Downside Semi Deviation Stochastic Programming for Portfolio Optimization Problem

Optimization in Finance

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

Chapter 2 Portfolio Management and the Capital Asset Pricing Model

Axioma Research Paper No January, Multi-Portfolio Optimization and Fairness in Allocation of Trades

SciBeta CoreShares South-Africa Multi-Beta Multi-Strategy Six-Factor EW

Comparative Study between Linear and Graphical Methods in Solving Optimization Problems

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Probability and Stochastics for finance-ii Prof. Joydeep Dutta Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Integer Programming Models

Robust Optimization Applied to a Currency Portfolio

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Efficient Portfolio and Introduction to Capital Market Line Benninga Chapter 9

Mean Variance Portfolio Theory

An Asset Allocation Puzzle: Comment

(IIEC 2018) TEHRAN, IRAN. Robust portfolio optimization based on minimax regret approach in Tehran stock exchange market

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Third-degree stochastic dominance and DEA efficiency relations and numerical comparison

Budget Setting Strategies for the Company s Divisions

Mathematics in Finance

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 12 Jul 2012

Value-at-Risk Based Portfolio Management in Electric Power Sector

CSCI 1951-G Optimization Methods in Finance Part 07: Portfolio Optimization

Introduction to Operations Research

Techniques for Calculating the Efficient Frontier

An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model

Select Efficient Portfolio through Goal Programming Model

ON SOME ASPECTS OF PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT. Mengrong Kang A THESIS

Richardson Extrapolation Techniques for the Pricing of American-style Options

Tel: Fax: Web:

Game Theory Tutorial 3 Answers

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Minimum Downside Volatility Indices

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

Portfolio Management and Optimal Execution via Convex Optimization

Supply Chain Outsourcing Under Exchange Rate Risk and Competition

Modern Portfolio Theory -Markowitz Model

Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 109 ( 2014 ) Yigit Bora Senyigit *, Yusuf Ag

Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region*

Correlation Ambiguity

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w

Allocation of shared costs among decision making units: a DEA approach

56:171 Operations Research Midterm Exam Solutions Fall 1994

Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance

Optimization Methods in Finance

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

Optimal Security Liquidation Algorithms

Characterization of the Optimum

RISK ADJUSTMENT FOR LOSS RESERVING BY A COST OF CAPITAL TECHNIQUE

A Simple Utility Approach to Private Equity Sales

Maximization of utility and portfolio selection models

Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

Influence of Real Interest Rate Volatilities on Long-term Asset Allocation

Optimization Models in Financial Mathematics

Some useful optimization problems in portfolio theory

Risk Optimization of the CNSS' Portfolio Using a Return- Constrained Markowitz Model

Robust portfolio optimization using second-order cone programming

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice

Sample Size for Assessing Agreement between Two Methods of Measurement by Bland Altman Method

Quantitative Portfolio Theory & Performance Analysis

Optimization Financial Time Series by Robust Regression and Hybrid Optimization Methods

Annual risk measures and related statistics

Predicting the Success of a Retirement Plan Based on Early Performance of Investments

Optimal retention for a stop-loss reinsurance with incomplete information

56:171 Operations Research Midterm Exam Solutions October 19, 1994

Market Risk Analysis Volume I

Pricing Volatility Derivatives with General Risk Functions. Alejandro Balbás University Carlos III of Madrid

Lecture IV Portfolio management: Efficient portfolios. Introduction to Finance Mathematics Fall Financial mathematics

Black-Litterman Model

Large-Scale SVM Optimization: Taking a Machine Learning Perspective

A Simple, Adjustably Robust, Dynamic Portfolio Policy under Expected Return Ambiguity

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

56:171 Operations Research Midterm Exam Solutions October 22, 1993

Chapter 8: CAPM. 1. Single Index Model. 2. Adding a Riskless Asset. 3. The Capital Market Line 4. CAPM. 5. The One-Fund Theorem

Transcription:

Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics 235 (2011) 4149 4157 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/cam The mean-absolute deviation portfolio selection problem with interval-valued returns Shiang-Tai Liu Graduate School of Business and Management, Vanung University, Chung-Li, Tao-Yuan 320, Taiwan, ROC a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t Article history: Received 29 April 2009 Received in revised form 28 October 2010 MSC: 90C 49M Keywords: Portfolio selection Risk Absolute deviation function Two-level program In real-world investments, one may care more about the future earnings than the current earnings of the assets. This paper discusses the uncertain portfolio selection problem where the asset returns are represented by interval data. Since the parameters are interval valued, the gain of returns is interval valued as well. According to the concept of the mean-absolute deviation function, we construct a pair of two-level mathematical programming models to calculate the lower and upper bounds of the investment return of the portfolio selection problem. Using the duality theorem and applying the variable transformation technique, the pair of two-level mathematical programs is transformed into a conventional one-level mathematical program. Solving the pair of mathematical programs produces the interval of the portfolio return of the problem. The calculated results conform to an essential idea in finance and economics that the greater the amount of risk that an investor is willing to take on the greater the potential return. 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction Each of the different ways to diversify money between several assets is called a portfolio. In the portfolio selection problem, given a set of available securities or assets, we wish to find the best way of investing a particular amount of money in these assets. Portfolio theory and related topics are among the most investigated fields of research in the economic and financial literature. The well-known mean variance approach of Markowitz [1,2] requires one to minimize the risk of the selected asset portfolio, while guaranteeing a pre-established return rate and the total use of the available capital. As the dimensionality of the portfolio selection problem increases, it becomes more difficult to solve a quadratic programming problem with a dense covariance matrix. Several methods have been proposed to alleviate the computational difficulty by using various approximation schemes [3 5]. The use of the index model enables one to reduce the amount of computation by introducing the notion of factors influencing the stock prices [6,7]. However, these efforts are largely discounted because of the popularity of equilibrium models such as capital asset pricing model (CAPM) which are computationally less demanding [8]. The genetic algorithm (GA), support vector machines (SVMs), and other optimization techniques have also been adopted to solve portfolio selection problems [9 12]. Despite these and later enhancements, the Markowitz model still offers the most general technique. While the limits of a quadratic approximation of the utility function are acknowledged, the development of operational procedures for constructing portfolios has been mainly hampered by computational problems. To improve Markowitz s model both computationally and theoretically, Konno and Yamazaki [8] proposed a portfolio selection model using a mean absolute deviation risk function instead of Markowitz s standard deviation risk function. Their model can tackle the difficulties associated with the classical Markowitz model while maintaining its advantages over equilibrium models. In particular, their model can be formulated as a linear program, so that large-scale portfolio selection problems may be easily solved. Tel.: +886 3 4529320; fax: +886 3 4529326. E-mail address: stliu@vnu.edu.tw. 0377-0427/$ see front matter 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.cam.2011.03.008

4150 S.-T. Liu / Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics 235 (2011) 4149 4157 Conventional portfolio selection models have an assumption that the future condition of a stock market can be accurately predicted by historical data. However, no matter how accurate the past data is, this premise will not exist in financial markets due to the high volatility of market environments. In real-world investments, many investment firms employ hundreds of analysts whose job is to look at company fundamentals and then project future trends, most notably future earnings. Afterward, they issue earning estimates for companies and use these estimates as a basis for issuing reports and recommendations on whether they think the specific stock should be bought, hold, or sold. In other words, to obtain better returns from the portfolio, we need to care more about the future earnings rather than the current or historical earnings of the assets. Since the prospective returns of the assets used for portfolio selection problem are forecasted values, considerable uncertainty is involved. One approach for dealing with uncertainty in parameters is via stochastic programming: the variables are treated as random or stochastic variables. For a given insurer s aspiration level of return on assets and risk level, Li [13] employed the chance constrained programming technique to maximize the insurer s probability of achieving their aspiration level. Ouzsoy and Güevn [14] formulated a short-term portfolio model and proposed a robust optimization technique to establish a balance between risk-seeking and risk-averse behaviors. Nevertheless, these two methods only give a point value for the problem. Another way to represent imprecise parameters in real-world applications is by intervals [15,16]. In this case, the associated portfolio selection problem is an interval portfolio selection problem. When the parameters are imprecise in the portfolio problem, the gain of return of the portfolio will be imprecise as well; that is, they will lie in a range. In contrast to most previous studies, which utilize historical values of returns to derive an optimal investment portfolio for the future, this paper proposes a solution method for the uncertain portfolio selection problem whose imprecise parameters are expressed by intervals. According to the concept of the mean-absolute deviation function [8], we construct a pair of two-level mathematical programming models, based on which the upper bound and lower bound of the return from the portfolio are obtained. In other words, an interval return from the portfolio of the uncertain portfolio selection problem is derived. This result should provide the decision maker with more information for making decisions. In the next section, we discuss the nature of the portfolio selection problem; this is followed by a two-level mathematical programming formulation for finding the bounds of the interval investment reruns. Section 3 describes how to transform the two-level mathematical program into a conventional one-level program. We then use an example to illustrate how to apply the concept of this paper to solve the uncertain portfolio selection problem. Finally, we draw a conclusion from the discussion. 2. The uncertain portfolio selection problem Assume that we have n assets for possible investment and that we are interested in determining the portion of available total fund M 0 that should be invested in each of the assets during the investment periods. Let the decision variables be denoted x j, j = 1,..., n, which represent the dollar amounts of funds invested in asset j. We then have the constraints n and x j 0. Let R j be a random variable representing the rate of return (per period) of the asset j. The expected return (per period) of the investment is given by n r(x 1,..., x n ) = E R j x j = E R j xj. (1) Generally, one would diversify the investment portfolio so that funds are invested in several different assets to minimize the investment risk. Markowitz [1,2] employed the standard deviation of the return as the measure of risk. 2 n n σ (x 1,..., x n ) = E R j x j E R j x j. (2) A rational investor may be interested in obtaining a certain average return from the portfolio at a minimum risk. Markowitz [1,2] formulated the portfolio problem as a quadratic programming problem: Min V = σ ij x i x j (3) i=1 r j x j R 0 0 x j U j, j = 1,..., n, where R 0 is the return in dollars and U j is the upper bound of the investment in asset j.

S.-T. Liu / Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics 235 (2011) 4149 4157 4151 To reduce the computational burden and transaction/management costs and cut-off effects, Konno and Yamazaki [8] introduced the absolute deviation function instead of Markowitz s standard deviation function of the (per period) earning out of the portfolio. n w(x) = E R j x j E R j x j. (4) They proved that the measures of standard deviation and absolute deviation functions are essentially the same if (R 1,..., R n ) are multivariate normally distributed, and proposed an alternative portfolio problem: n Min E R j x j E R j x j (5) E R j xj R 0 Suppose that we have historical data on each asset for the past T years, which give the price fluctuations and dividend payments. We can then estimate the return on investment from each asset from past data. Let r jt denote the realization of random variable R j during period t, i.e., the total return per dollar invested in asset j during year t. Clearly, the values of r jt are not constants; they can fluctuate widely from year to year. In addition, r jt may be positive, negative, or zero. In order to assess the investment potential of asset j per dollar invested, we first denote r j as r j = 1 E R j = T r jt. Then w(x) can be approximated as n E R j x j E R j x j = 1 T (r jt r j )x j. (6) That is, (5) can be reformulated as follows [8]: Min (r jt r j )x j T r j x j R 0 (7) This model can be transformed into the following linear program: Min u t /T u t + (r jt r j )x j 0, t = 1,..., T, (r jt r j )x j 0, t = 1,..., T, (8)

4152 S.-T. Liu / Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics 235 (2011) 4149 4157 r j x j R 0 We presume that we are able to roughly project the return on investment for each asset over the next several years. Since the return on investment in the future is uncertain, we let ˆr jt [R L, jt RU jt ] denote the interval of total return per dollar invested in asset j for future year t, where R L jt and RU jt are the lower bound and upper bound of the return on investment during year t. From (6), we have ˆr j = 1 T ˆr jt. When the returns on investment ˆr jt have interval values, the parameters ˆr j and objective value will also have interval values; that is, they lie in ranges. Under such circumstances, the portfolio selection is formulated as the following linear programming problem with interval parameters: Min u t /T u t + (ˆr jt ˆr j )x j 0, t = 1,..., T, (ˆr jt ˆr j )x j 0, t = 1,..., T, ˆr j x j R 0 In the next section, we shall develop the solution method for the portfolio selection problem with interval-valued returns. 3. Solution method Clearly, different values of ˆr jt and ˆr j produce different objective values (risks). To find the interval of the objective values, it suffices to find the lower and upper bounds of the objective values of (10). Denote R = {(ˆr) R L jt ˆr jt R U jt, RL j ˆr j R U j, j = 1,..., n, t = 1, 2,..., T}. The values of ˆr jt and ˆr j that attain the smallest objective value (risk) can be determined from the following two-level mathematical programming model: V L = Min Min u t /T ˆr R x V = u t + (ˆr jt ˆr j )x j 0, t = 1,..., T, (ˆr jt ˆr j )x j 0, t = 1,..., T, ˆr j x j R 0 0 x j U j, j = 1,..., n, where the inner-level program calculates the objective value for each ˆr jt and ˆr j specified by the outer-level program, while the outer-level program determines the values of ˆr jt and ˆr j that produce the smallest objective value (risk). The objective (9) (10) (11)

S.-T. Liu / Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics 235 (2011) 4149 4157 4153 value V L is the lower bound of the objective values (risks) for (10), and the associated return from the portfolio can be also calculated from the derived optimal solution. By the same token, to find the values of ˆr jt and ˆr j that produce the largest objective value (risk) for (10), a two-level mathematical program is formulated by changing the outer-level program of (11) from Min to Max: V U = Max Min u t /T ˆr R x u t + (ˆr jt ˆr j )x j 0, t = 1,..., T, (ˆr jt ˆr j )x j 0, t = 1,..., T, ˆr j x j R 0 The objective value V U is the lower bound of the objective values (risks) for (10). Similar to (11), the corresponding return from the portfolio can be calculated from the optimal solution obtained. When the interval data ˆr jt and ˆr j degenerate to point data r jt and r j, respectively, the outer-level program of (11) and (12) vanishes, and (11) and (12) reduce to the same conventional linear program described in (8). The pair of two-level mathematical programs in (11) and (12) clearly expresses the bounds of the objective values (risks). To find the lower bound of the objective value (risk) of (10), it suffices to solve the two-level mathematical program (11). Since both the inner-level program and outer-level program of (11) have the same minimization operation, they can be combined into a conventional one-level program with the constraints of the two programs considered at the same time. V L = Min x V = u t + u t /T ˆr jt x j ˆr jt x j + ˆr j x j R 0 ˆr j x j 0, t = 1,..., T, (13a) ˆr j x j 0, t = 1,..., T, (13b) R L jt ˆr jt R U jt, j = 1, 2,..., n, t = 1, 2,..., T (13e) R L j ˆr j R U j, j = 1, 2,..., n In (13a), (13b) and (13d), ˆr jt x j and ˆr j x j are nonlinear terms. In other words, (13) is a nonlinear program, which does not guarantee to have a stationary point. Fortunately, the variable transformation technique can be applied to the nonlinear terms ˆr jt x j and ˆr j x j. One can multiply constraint (13e) and (13f) by x j, j = 1, 2,..., n, and substitute ˆr jt x j by ρ jt and ˆr j x j by η j, respectively. Consequently, we have the flowing linear program: V L = Min x V = u t + u t /T ρ jt η j 0, t = 1,..., T, (12) (13) (13c) (13d) (13f) (14)

4154 S.-T. Liu / Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics 235 (2011) 4149 4157 ρ jt + η j R 0 η j 0, t = 1,..., T, R L jt x j ρ jt R U jt x j, R L j x j η j R U j x j, j = 1, 2,..., n j = 1, 2,..., n, t = 1, 2,..., T The obtained objective value V L is the lower bound of the investment risk, and the corresponding return is R L = n η j. Since V L is the lower bound of the risk of the problem, the value R L is the lower bound of the return from the portfolio. For risk-averse investors, they may consider the lower risk as the objective but also obtain lower returns. Similarly, to find the upper bound of the objective value (risk) of (10), it suffices to solve the two-level mathematical program (12). However, solving (12) is not so straightforward, because the outer-level program and inner-level program have different directions for optimization, namely, one for maximization and another for minimization. The dual problem of the inner-level program of (12) has the following mathematical form: Max M 0 y 2T+1 + R 0 y 2T+2 w,y (ˆr jt ˆr j )y t U j w j (ˆr jt ˆr j )y T+t + y 2T+1 + ˆr j y 2T+2 w j 0, j = 1,..., n, y t + y T+t 1/T, t = 1,..., T, y t, y 2T+2, w j 0, t = 1,..., 2T, j = 1,..., n, y 2T+1 unrestricted in sign. (15) By the duality theorem, if one problem is unbounded, then the other is infeasible. Moreover, if both problems are feasible, then they both have optimal solutions having the same objective value. In other words, (12) can be reformulated as V U = Max ˆr R Max M 0 y 2T+1 + R 0 y 2T+2 w,y (ˆr jt ˆr j )y t U j w j (16) (ˆr jt ˆr j )y T+t + y 2T+1 + ˆr j y 2T+2 w j 0, j = 1,..., n, y t + y T+t 1/T, t = 1,..., T, y t, y 2T+2, w j 0, t = 1,..., 2T, j = 1,..., n, unrestricted in sign. y 2T+1 Now, both the inner-level program and the outer-level program have the same maximization operation, so they can be merged into a one-level program with the constraints at the two levels considered at the same time: V U = Max M 0 y 2T+1 + R 0 y 2T+2 w,y U j w j (17) ˆr jt (y t y T+t ) ˆr j (y t y T+t ) + y 2T+1 + ˆr j y 2T+2 w j 0, j = 1,..., n, (17a) y t + y T+t 1/T, t = 1,..., T, R L jt ˆr jt R U jt, j = 1, 2,..., n, t = 1, 2,..., T (17c) R L j ˆr j R U j, j = 1, 2,..., n y t, y 2T+2, w j 0, t = 1,..., 2T, j = 1,..., n, unrestricted in sign. y 2T+1 (17b) (17d)

S.-T. Liu / Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics 235 (2011) 4149 4157 4155 The variable transformation technique can also be applied to the nonlinear terms ˆr jt y t, ˆr jt y T+t, ˆr j y t, ˆr jt y T+t, and ˆr j y 2T+2 contained in (17a). We can multiply constraint (17c) by y t and y T+t, t = 1,..., T, respectively, and substitute ˆr jt y t by ξ jt and ˆr jty T+t by ξ jt, individually. Likewise, constraint (17d) can be multiplied, respectively, by y t and y T+t, t = 1,..., T, and then we substitute ˆr t y t by ψ jt and ˆr jy T+t by ψ jt, respectively. By the same token, we can also multiply this constraint by y 2T+2 and replace ˆr j y 2T+2 with δ j. Via the dual formulation and variable transformation, the two-level mathematical program (12) is transformed into the following one-level linear program: V U = Max M 0 y 2T+1 + R 0 y 2T+2 ξ,ψ,δ,w,y ξ jt y=1 ξ jt ψ U j w j (18) jt + y t + y T+t 1/T, t = 1,..., T, R L jt y t ξ jt RU jt y t, j = 1, 2,..., n, t = 1, 2,..., T R L jt y T+t ξ jt RU jt y T+t, R L j y t ψ jt RU j y t, R L j y T+t ψ jt RU j y T+t, R L j y 2T+2 δ j R U j y 2T+2, ψ jt + y 2T+1 + δ j w j 0, j = 1,..., n, j = 1, 2,..., n, t = 1, 2,..., T j = 1, 2,..., n, t = 1, 2,..., T j = 1, 2,..., n, t = 1, 2,..., T j = 1, 2,..., n y t, y 2T+2, w j, δ j 0, t = 1,..., 2T, j = 1,..., n, unrestricted in sign. y 2T+1 By solving (18), we derive the objective value V U, which is the upper bound of the investment risk, and r j = ξ jt /y t = ξ jt /y T+t. From the dual prices of the optimal solution, we can find the primal solutions x j. The associated return from the portfolio is calculated as R U = n r j x j. An essential idea in finance and economics is that the greater the amount of risk that an investor is willing to take on the greater the potential return. Since we obtain the upper bound of the risk V U, the value R U is also the upper bound of the return from the portfolio. For risk lovers, they may consider obtaining higher returns by taking a higher risk as the objective. Together with R L derived from (14), R L and R U constitute the interval of the returns from the portfolio described in (10). 4. An example In this section, we utilize an example to illustrate the idea of solving a portfolio selection problem with interval-valued returns. Table 1 lists the actual returns from years 2007 to 2009 and the predicted returns of years 2010 and 2011 for three stocks, namely, A, B, and C. Besides, the upper bound of the investment amount in each stock is set to no more than 45% of the total available fund to dissipate the risk. Since the security returns of 2010 and 2011 are forecasted data, they are represented as interval values. The expected returns of the three stocks are calculated as shown in the last row of Table 1. Given a total allocation budget of 100 units and annual return of 15%, conceptually, the lower bound V L and upper bound V U of the portfolio selection problem are formulated as follows: V L = Min(u 1 + u 2 + u 3 + u 4 + u 5 )/5 u 1 + 1.219x 1 + 1.151x 2 + 1.213x 3 (1.193, 1.223)x 1 (1.192, 1.215)x 2 (1.185, 1.211)x 3 0 u 2 + 1.149x 1 + 1.231x 2 + 1.163x 3 (1.193, 1.223)x 1 (1.192, 1.215)x 2 (1.185, 1.211)x 3 0 u 3 + 1.202x 1 + 1.211x 2 + 1.112x 3 (1.193, 1.223)x 1 (1.192, 1.215)x 2 (1.185, 1.211)x 3 0 u 4 + (1.232, 1.313)x 1 + (1.214, 1.261)x 2 + (1.188, 1.262)x 3 (1.193, 1.223)x 1 (1.192, 1.215)x 2 (1.185, 1.211)x 3 0, u 5 + (1.161, 1.232)x 1 + (1.152, 1.222)x 2 + (1.248, 1.304)x 3 (1.193, 1.223)x 1 (1.192, 1.215)x 2 (1.185, 1.211)x 3 0, u 1 1.219x 1 1.151x 2 1.213x 3 + (1.193, 1.223)x 1 + (1.192, 1.215)x 2 + (1.185, 1.211)x 3 0 u 2 1.149x 1 1.231x 2 1.163x 3 + (1.193, 1.223)x 1 + (1.192, 1.215)x 2 + (1.185, 1.211)x 3 0 u 3 1.202x 1 1.211x 2 1.112x 3 + (1.193, 1.223)x 1 + (1.192, 1.215)x 2 + (1.185, 1.211)x 3 0 u 4 (1.232, 1.313)x 1 (1.214, 1.261)x 2 (1.188, 1.262)x 3 + (1.193, 1.223)x 1 + (1.192, 1.215)x 2 + (1.185, 1.211)x 3 0,

4156 S.-T. Liu / Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics 235 (2011) 4149 4157 Table 1 Returns and expected returns of three selected stocks. Year A B C 2007 1.219 1.151 1.213 2008 1.149 1.231 1.163 2009 1.202 1.211 1.112 2010 (1.232, 1.313) (1.214, 1.261) (1.188, 1.262) 2011 (1.161, 1.232) (1.152, 1.222) (1.248, 1.304) Expected return (1.193, 1.223) (1.192, 1.215) (1.185, 1.211) u 5 + (1.161, 1.232)x 1 + (1.152, 1.222)x 2 + (1.248, 1.304)x 3 (1.193, 1.223)x 1 + (1.192, 1.215)x 2 + (1.185, 1.211)x 3 0, x 1 + x 1 + x 3 = 100, (1.193, 1.223)x 1 + (1.192, 1.215)x 2 + (1.185, 1.211)x 3 115, 0 x 1, x 2, x 3 45. V U = Max 100y 11 + 115y 12 45w 1 45w 2 45w 3 [1.219(y 1 y 6 ) + 1.149(y 2 y 7 ) + 1.202(y 3 y 8 ) + (1.232, 1.313)(y 4 y 9 ) + (1.161, 1.232)(y 5 y 10 )] [(1.193, 1.223)(y 1 y 6 ) + (1.193, 1.223)(y 2 y 7 ) +(1.193, 1.223)(y 3 y 8 ) + (1.193, 1.223)(y 4 y 9 ) + (1.193, 1.223)(y 5 y 10 )] + y 11 + (1.193, 1.223)y 12 w 1 0, [1.151(y 1 y 6 ) + 1.231(y 2 y 7 ) + 1.211(y 3 y 8 ) + (1.214, 1.261)(y 4 y 9 ) + (1.152, 1.222)(y 5 y 10 )] [(1.192, 1.215)(y 1 y 6 ) + (1.192, 1.215)(y 2 y 7 ) + (1.192, 1.215)(y 3 y 8 ) + (1.192, 1.215)(y 4 y 9 ) + (1.192, 1.215)(y 5 y 10 )] + y 11 + (1.192, 1.215)y 12 w 2 0, [1.213(y 1 y 6 ) + 1.163(y 2 y 7 ) + 1.112(y 3 y 8 ) + (1.188, 1.262)(y 4 y 9 ) + (1.248, 1.304)(y 5 y 10 )] [(1.185, 1.211)(y 1 y 6 ) + (1.185, 1.211)(y 2 y 7 ) + (1.185, 1.211)(y 3 y 8 ) + (1.185, 1.211)(y 4 y 9 ) + (1.185, 1.211)(y 5 y 10 )] + y 11 + (1.185, 1.211)y 12 w 3 0, y 1 + y 6 1/5, y 2 + y 7 1/5, y 3 + y 8 1/5, y 4 + y 9 1/5, y 5 + y 10 1/5, y t, y 12, w j 0, t = 1,..., 10, j = 1,..., 3, y 11 unrestricted in sign. Based on (14), the lower bound of the objective value (risk) V L is solved as 0.636, which occurs at x 1 = 38.20, x 2 = 45, x 3 = 16.80, ˆr 1 = 1.193, ˆr 2 = 1.192, and ˆr 3 = 1.185. The associated return from the portfolio is R L = 119.12. Similarly, according to (18), the upper bound of the objective value (risk) V U is solved as 4.465. From the dual prices of the optimal solution, we find that the primal solution is x 1 = 39.76, x 2 = 45, x 3 = 15.24, ˆr 1 = 1.223, ˆr 2 = 1.215, and ˆr 3 = 1.211. The corresponding return from the portfolio is calculated as R U = 121.76. The values of R L and R U indicate that the return from the portfolio of this problem is imprecise and lies in the range [119.12, 121.76]. Clearly, the higher risk derives a higher return in this example, and the result conforms to a fundamental idea in finance. 5. Conclusion Financial investments are especially important for individual and business financial managers because of low interest rates. Conventional portfolio optimization models have an assumption that the future condition of a stock market can be accurately predicted by historical data. However, no matter how accurate the past data is, this premise will not exist in financial markets due to changing environments. In contrast to previous studies, which utilize historical values of returns to derive an optimal investment portfolio for the future, this paper develops a solution method for the uncertain portfolio selection problem whose investment returns are represented as intervals. The idea is to find the upper bound and lower bound of the return from the portfolio by employing the two-level mathematical programming technique and meanabsolute deviation risk function. Using the duality theorem and applying the variable transformation technique, the twolevel mathematical programs are transformed into a pair of one-level conventional linear programs so that the return from the portfolio can be easily calculated. The derived results are also in ranges. We utilize an example to illustrate the idea proposed in this paper and show that the return of the portfolio problem is indeed in a range. The calculated results conform to an essential idea in finance and economics that the greater the amount of

S.-T. Liu / Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics 235 (2011) 4149 4157 4157 risk that an investor is willing to take on the greater the potential return. The ability to calculate the bounds of the investment return developed in this paper might help initiate wider applications in portfolio selection problems. Acknowledgements This research was supported by the National Science Council of the Republic of China under Contract No. NSC96-2410-H- 238-004-MY2. The author is indebted to Editor M.J. Goovaerts and the referees for their helpful comments, which improved the presentation of the paper. References [1] H. Markowitz, Portfolio selection, Journal of Finance 7 (1952) 77 91. [2] H. Markowitz, Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investment, John Wiley & Sons, New York, 1959. [3] W.F. Sharpe, A linear programming algorithm for a mutual fund portfolio selection, Management Science 13 (1967) 499 510. [4] W.F. Sharpe, A linear programming approximation for the general portfolio selection problem, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 6 (1971) 1263 1275. [5] B. Stone, A linear programming formulation of the general portfolio selection model, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 8 (1973) 621 636. [6] A. Perold, Large scale portfolio selections, Management Science 30 (1984) 1143 1160. [7] W.F. Sharpe, Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk, Journal of Finance 19 (1964) 425 442. [8] H. Konno, H. Yamazaki, Mean-absolute deviation portfolio optimization model and its applications to Tokyo stock market, Management Science 37 (1991) 519 531. [9] H. Ince, T.B. Trafalis, Kernel methods for short-term portfolio management, Expert Systems with Applications 30 (2006) 535 542. [10] Z. Landsman, Minimization of the root of a quadratic functional under a system of affine equality constraints with application to portfolio management, Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics 220 (2008) 739 748. [11] K.J. Oh, T.Y. Kim, S. Min, Using genetic algorithm to support portfolio optimization for index fund management, Expert Systems with Applications 28 (2005) 371 379. [12] J. Xu, J. Li, A class of stochastic optimization problems with one quadratic and several linear objective functions and extended portfolio selection model, Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics 146 (2002) 99 113. [13] S. Li, An insurance and investment portfolio model using chance constrained programming, Omega 23 (1995) 577 585. [14] C.B. Oğuzsoy, S. Güevn, Robust portfolio planning in the presence of market anomalies, Omega 35 (2007) 1 6. [15] W.W. Cooper, K.S. Park, G. Yu, An illustrative application of IDEA (Imprecise Data Envelopment Analysis) to a Korean mobile telecommunication company, Operations Research 49 (2001) 807 820. [16] C. Kao, S.T. Liu, Predicting bank performance with financial forecasts: a case of Taiwan commercial banks, Journal of Banking and Finance 28 (2004) 2353 2368.