Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

Similar documents
Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Brownian Motion and Ito s Lemma

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

Risk Neutral Measures

Lévy models in finance

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Monte Carlo Simulations

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

The stochastic calculus

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

The discounted portfolio value of a selffinancing strategy in discrete time was given by. δ tj 1 (s tj s tj 1 ) (9.1) j=1

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Hedging under Arbitrage

Continuous time; continuous variable stochastic process. We assume that stock prices follow Markov processes. That is, the future movements in a

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Risk Neutral Valuation

1 Interest Based Instruments

Lecture 3. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria web: July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

QI SHANG: General Equilibrium Analysis of Portfolio Benchmarking

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Objective Binomial Model What is and what is not mortgage insurance in Mexico? 3 times model (Black and Scholes) Correlated brownian motion Other

Stochastic Volatility

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

S t d with probability (1 p), where

Replication strategies of derivatives under proportional transaction costs - An extension to the Boyle and Vorst model.

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as:

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

Stochastic Calculus - An Introduction

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

The Black-Scholes Model

1 The continuous time limit

Completeness and Hedging. Tomas Björk

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Option Pricing Models for European Options

4 Risk-neutral pricing

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

Binomial Model for Forward and Futures Options

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model

The Black-Scholes Model

Logarithmic derivatives of densities for jump processes

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Derivative Securities Section 9 Fall 2004 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences.

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

1. 2 marks each True/False: briefly explain (no formal proofs/derivations are required for full mark).

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 8 Option Pricing in Continuous Time

1 Geometric Brownian motion

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Risk-Neutral Valuation

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Interest rate models in continuous time

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems

A Simple Approach to CAPM and Option Pricing. Riccardo Cesari and Carlo D Adda (University of Bologna)

- 1 - **** d(lns) = (µ (1/2)σ 2 )dt + σdw t

The Term Structure of Interest Rates under Regime Shifts and Jumps

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

Stochastic Processes and Brownian Motion

BLACK SCHOLES THE MARTINGALE APPROACH

Computing Greeks with Multilevel Monte Carlo Methods using Importance Sampling

Financial Risk Management

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Probability in Options Pricing

Futures Options. The underlying of a futures option is a futures contract.

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

(1) Consider a European call option and a European put option on a nondividend-paying stock. You are given:

Importance Sampling for Option Pricing. Steven R. Dunbar. Put Options. Monte Carlo Method. Importance. Sampling. Examples.

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics

Transcription:

Change of Measure Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem Radon-Nikodym derivative: Taking again our intuition from the discrete world, we know that, in the context of option pricing, we need to price the claim using the risk-neutral measure. If there are no interest rates, this measure Q is constructed through the requirement that the stock process S t needs to be a Q-martingale. This will also work in the continuous world, however, we will need a continuous model of the stock process in the first place. For the Black-Scholes model, we start from S t = S e σwt+µt with a P-Brownian motion W t. In order to define a measure Q, such that S t becomes a Q-martingale, we need to know how a Brownian motion changes when the measure changes. Or, in other words, we would like to express the change of measure in terms of Brownian motions. To prepare the change of measure in the continuous world, we go back only for a moment to the discrete world. Consider the same tree with two different measures P and Q. p 9 p 3 p 1 1 p 3 8 p 5 1 p 3 1 5 p 2 1 p 1 1 p 5 2 7 p 1 p 2 1 p Figure 1: Binomial tree with measure P In the following, we basically only need the rule that we have to multiply probabilities on branches in order to compute the probability to get to a 1

q 9 q 3 q 1 1 q 3 8 q 5 1 q 3 1 5 q 2 1 q 1 1 q 5 2 7 q 1 q 2 1 q Figure 2: Binomial tree with measure Q certain node. For instance, using the measure P, the probability π 9 to get to the node numbered node 9 is π 9 = p 1 p 3 p Under the measure Q, the probability to reach node 9 is in general different. Let s denote it by π 9. Obviously, we have π 9 = q 1 q 3 q In this way, we can express probabilities for all nodes. For node 8, we find π 8 = p 1 p 3 1 p, π 8 = q 1 q 3 1 q After these preparations, we are ready to think about the question under which circumstances it is possible to express the measure Q in terms of the measure P and vice versa. The trivial answer is to write simply for the probability to reach node 9 π 9 = π 9 π 9 π 9, in order to go from measure P to the measure Q and, on the other hand, π 9 = π 9 π 9 π 9. 2

in order to go from measure Q to the measure P. First, we notice that the likelihood ratio corresponds to a stochastic process. This process is called Radon-Nikodym derivative and denoted by /dp or dp/. Clearly, for the Radon-Nikodym derivative to be well-defined, we need to assume that nodes of the tree that are accessible under the measure Q are also accessible under the measure P. In other words: we need to avoid dividing by zero when forming the likelihood ratios. The formal definition is given by the equivalence of the two measures: The two measures are equivalent if for each set A the statement QA > is equivalent to PA >. For the binomial tree, this reduces to the statement that, nodes that are accessible under one measure are also accessible under the other measure. By accessible we mean simply that there is a non-zero probability to reach a node. For equivalent measures, we can easily express the expectation value with respect to one measure through the expectation value taken with respect to the other measure. Consider a discrete random variable X, we find E P X = i x i π i = i x i π i π i π i = E Q X dp For a normally distributed random variable, we can use this formula to characterize the change of measure. This is due to the following basic fact: Theorem. Characterization of Gaussian variables The following two statements are equivalent: 1. A random variable X has a normal distribution Nµ, σ 2 under a measure P 1 2. For all real θ, we have E P e θx = e θµ+θ2 σ 2 /2 Let s look at a simple, but very instructive example: In order to define a suitable Radon-Nikodym derivative, a simple choice is to have /dp >. Let W t be a P-Brownian motion hence normally distributed with zero mean and a variance t, a possible choice would be dp = e γwt γ2 t/2 >. Can we figure out what happens to W t under the measure Q? If we are lucky, W has still a normal distribution under the new measure but maybe 3

with a different mean and/or variance. In this case, we should be able to use the above theorem. Let s try to compute E Q e θwt = E P dp eθwt = E P e γwt γ2t/2 e θwt = e γ2t/2 E P e θ γwt = e γ2t/2 e θ γ2 t/2 = e γθt+θ2 t/2 Applying the above theorem again, we see that W has, under the measure Q, again a normal distribution with mean γt and variance t. In summary, we have shown that, for a P Brownian motion W t, we can construct an equivalent measure Q such that, under the new measure Q, the Brownian motion W t has a mean γt and a drift t. In particular W t = W t + γt is actually a Q-Brownian motion, since the term γt is used to compensate for the negative drift. This is a special case of the following theorem: Theorem. Cameron-Martin-Girsanov theorem For a P-Brownian motion W t and a previsible process γ t, satisfying the condition 1 T E P exp γt 2 dt < 2 there exists a measure Q equivalent to P such that W t = W t + t γ s ds is a Q-Brownian motion. The measures are related by the Radon-Nikodym derivative given by t dp = exp γ s dw s 1 t γs 2 ds. 2 In the context of derivative pricing, we can use the Cameron-Martin-Girsanov theorem in order to construct a martingale measure. Consider for example a stochastic process X t = µt + σw t with a P-Brownian motion W t. Now, we can write µ X t = σ σ t + W t = σγt + W t = σ W t since the Cameron-Martin-Girsanov theorem guarantees the existence of an equivalent measure Q and the corresponding Q-Brownian motion W t. Clearly, X t is not a P-martingale, but it is obviously a Q-martingale.

Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula using the Girsanov theorem: We can now derive again the Black-Scholes formula using the Cameron-Martin- Girsanov theorem. The main step consists in considering the Black-Scholes model with a stock and bond process given by S t = S e µt+σwt, B t = B e rt and forming the discounted stock process Z t = B 1 t S t = S e µ rt+σwt. For a European claim X with maturity T, the initial price is given by V = e rt E Q X, and Z t is a Q-martingale. Clearly, we want to use the Cameron- Martin-Girsanov theorem to construct Q. Therefore, we use first Ito s lemma to find dz t : dz t = Z t µ r + σ 2 /2 dt + σdw t = σzt γ dt + dw t, 2 where we set γ = µ r + σ 2 /2. Applying now the Cameron-Martin- Girsanov theorem, we can construct the measure Q such that Z t becomes a Q-martingale and W t = γt + W t is a Q-Brownian motion. Clearly, we have then W t = W t γt and we can use this in order to express the stock process S t in terms of Wt : S t = S e µt+σwt = S e µt+σ W t µ rt σ 2 t/2 = S e σ W t+r σ 2 /2t 3 For a European call, we have X = S T K +, and thus the price of such a call is computed as V = e rt E Q X = E Q S e σ W t σ 2 t/2 Ke rt + which is exactly the Black-Scholes formula. 5